Outlook on the United States JUL 2021

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Outlook on the United States JUL 2021 Outlook on the United States JUL 2021 Summary • As growth accelerates, worry over US inflation has moved to the forefront. Lazard’s equity and fixed income teams alike believe that recent higher inflation levels will not last. • Our equity teams expect inflation on average to be marginally above the Federal Reserve’s 2% target for the next two to three years but do not expect it to rise more or last longer. With the US economy still in recession, our analysts are closely watching job The focus on inflation comes as the tide has turned decisively against growth. COVID-19 in the United States, and it is accompanied by a particular • In its economic impact, the COVID-19 pandemic has been akin to focus on the potential for a full reopening to drive growth. Yet, we a natural disaster, and our fixed income team expects volatility in believe it is worth sounding a note of caution. The United States is inflation, other economic data, and the path to recovery. still in a recession. Some 7.5 million people who had jobs in February • After many credit rating downgrades in the past 16 months, 2020 are no longer working, about the same number as during our bond analysts continue to believe in a bifurcated recovery, which favors an investing approach built on bottom-up security the depths of the global financial crisis. So, while it is important to selection and focused on lending to viable borrowers. consider the various risks to the economy, including inflation, the biggest risk of all is an anemic recovery that could lead to years of disappointing growth akin to the 2010s. In the United States, massive fiscal stimulus combined with a largely US Equity successful vaccination campaign has raised questions for investors Inflation was the talk of the town in the second quarter. Most in three areas. First, at what rate will jobs return and when will the economists expected inflation to rise, but few foresaw a Consumer labor market tighten? Second, how will excess savings and changing Price Inflation (CPI) reading of 5.0% in May, the highest rate in consumption patterns drive the economic recovery? And third, what almost 15 years. Two months of higher-than-expected inflation added path will inflation and interest rates take in the short-to-medium term, fuel to concerns that the United States is on the precipice of a secular and how will this change asset allocations? shift in the inflation paradigm. Almost all economists agree that some proportion of inflation is COVID-19 Update transient; the disagreement among them is how much. Our base In the second quarter, 26% of all US adults received at least one shot case view is that inflation is likely to exceed 2% for the next two to of the COVID-19 vaccine, bringing the total proportion of Americans three years, at least. However, we think this marginally above-target who have received one dose or more to 53.3% and the fully vaccinated inflation is unlikely to accelerate or to last. Even if our base case view is to 45.1%. Along with acquired immunity from those who were correct, however, we believe investors should be concerned about the already infected, this means the US population already has significant potential for higher long-term interest rates and how rising bond yields immunity to COVID-19. Yet, the pace of daily vaccinations has in general could change the environment for savings and investment. declined from over 4 million doses per day in April 2021 to just over 1 million in June 2021, and lingering vaccine hesitancy meant that RD12134 2 the United States missed President Joseph Biden’s target of having (Exhibit 2). A major portion of the jobs lost were low income. Before 70% of adults vaccinated by 4 July. At the current pace, the country the pandemic, median pay for a US worker was $60,000 and the will only vaccinate 70% of adults by the middle of the third quarter. 25th percentile of earnings was $27,000 per year. Since the pandemic By comparison, the European Union (EU) has rapidly accelerated began, jobs that pay more than $60,000 per year have increased vaccinations and likely will surpass the United States in the proportion 2.4%, while jobs that pay less than $27,000 have declined 23.6%. of the population that has been vaccinated as soon as the third quarter Jobs with salaries between $27,000 and $60,000 are down 2.4%. (Exhibit 1). While some of these low wage jobs might be gone for good, the vast majority should return as the service sector fully reopens. Exhibit 1 EU Vaccinations Will Soon Surpass US Efforts Exhibit 2 Population Vaccinated with at Least One Dose “True” US Unemployment Stands at About 8.6%, for Now (% of Total Population) (%) 80 25 Unemployment Rate Adjusted Unemployment Rate 20 60 Absentee Worker Adjustment UK 15 40 US 10 20 EU 5 0 Dec Feb Apr Jun 0 2020 2021 2021 2021 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 2021 As of 20 June 2021 As of May 2021 Source: Our World in Data Official unemployment rate accounts for people who are out of work and looking for a job. In April and May 2020, US Bureau of Labor Statistics classified workers that reported being employed, but not at work as “employed.” Had they been classified as unemployed, the unemployment rate would have been 4.8 ppts higher in April and 3 ppts higher in May; this decreased to <0.5 ppt for August–October; the adjusted Still, the benefits of the US vaccination program have been staggering. unemployment rate treats the fall in labor market participation as unemployed as a proportion of total working age people. Daily cases have decreased from more than 200,000 in January to Source: Department of Labor, Haver Analytics fewer than 15,000 in June; over the same time period, the most important metric, deaths, has decreased from more than 4,000 per day to fewer than 300. Most states have rescinded mask mandates and lifted coronavirus-related regulations, spurring a rapid increase in Despite the overall weakness of the labor market, there are good reasons demand for services such as restaurants, cinemas, and domestic travel. to think the recovery will accelerate sharply in the coming months. First, labor supply should surge in September as children return to Changing patterns of consumption are fueling recoveries across in-person school and unemployment insurance benefits expire. Second, sectors. However, the economic recovery from the pandemic it is easier to lay off workers in a downturn than to hire in a recovery. entails many unknown unknowns. Investors and businesses are Employers incur search costs to find workers, as they have to take time understandably worried about the risks they can see. But, as evidenced to sift through applications while also trying to keep up with surging by jobs data so far, the recovery will not be smooth, and it will not post-COVID demand. The idea that employers could, from the depths have easily predictable effects on the economy or on financial markets. of a recession, hire everyone back who had lost jobs in the space of a few months was always a fantasy that did not account for hiring friction. Reopening: Jobs Indeed, the number of job openings outstripped hiring by almost 400,000 positions in May. While some are keen to chalk this up to The beginning of the second quarter was marked by widespread generous unemployment insurance, which is most likely a factor on the anticipation of gaining 1 million or more new jobs per month. Yet, margins, we believe that the dislocation created by the pandemic, lack job creation fell far short of expectations throughout the quarter even of child care and in-person schooling, and the closing of hundreds of while data was encouraging. With more than 7 million people still thousands of small businesses across the country are more important out of work relative to February 2020 and 3.5 million more people factors in the gap between vacancies and hiring. Finally, it’s reasonable to who dropped out of the labor market altogether, it is premature believe that the recovery will accelerate because jobs are already returning to think about tightening labor markets, in our view. If job gains as vaccinations continue and American consumers flock back to the continue at the pace of May 2021, it would take almost 15 months service sector (Exhibits 3 and 4). for employment in the United States to return to pre-pandemic levels. While headline unemployment has dropped to 5.8%, The United States is in a strange place, then: Consumption has when adding in people that have dropped out of the labor force rebounded to pre-COVID-19 levels, the median American household for economic reasons, the unemployment rate is more like 8.6% has more savings now than at any point in decades, job growth is 3 continuing at a rapid pace, and still, millions of people are looking Exhibit 3 for jobs, and many of those people are the ones who arguably need Labor Distortions Are Another Transitory Inflation Force them the most—low-income workers. What it all adds up to is Non-Farm People Unemployed, Job Openings, and Hires (Thousands) that consumers’ balance sheets are well-positioned to fuel higher 25,000 consumption for the rest of the year (Exhibit 5) even as US fiscal stimulus diminishes, thanks to child tax credits and household savings 20,000 that exceed pre-pandemic run rates by over $2.1 trillion.
Recommended publications
  • Making Sense of Unemployment Data
    PAGE ONE Economics® Making Sense of Unemployment Data Scott A. Wolla, Ph.D., Senior Economic Education Specialist GLOSSARY “Unemployment is like a headache or a high temperature—unpleasant and Cyclical unemployment: Unemployment exhausting but not carrying in itself any explanation of its cause.” associated with recessions in the business —William Henry Beveridge, Causes and Cures of Unemployment cycle. Discouraged worker: Someone who is not working and is not looking for work because of a belief that there are no jobs Job growth has been healthy for five years.1 However, many people still available to him or her. express concern over the health of the overall labor market. For example, Employed: People 16 years and older who Jim Clifton, CEO of Gallup, states that the “official unemployment rate, as have jobs. reported by the U.S. Department of Labor, is extremely misleading.”2 He Frictional unemployment: Unemployment proposes the Gallup Good Jobs rate as a better indicator of the health of the that results when people are new to the labor market. At the heart of Clifton and others’ concern is what the official job market, including recent graduates, or are transitioning from one job to another. unemployment rate actually measures and whether it is a reliable indicator. Labor force: The total number of workers, including both the employed and the The Labor Force: Are You In or Out? unemployed. To measure the unemployment rate, the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics Labor force participation rate: The percent- (BLS) surveys 60,000 households—about 110,000 individuals—which age of the working-age population that is in the labor force.
    [Show full text]
  • Ten Tips for Interpreting Economic Data F Jason Furman Chairman, Council of Economic Advisers
    Ten Tips for Interpreting Economic Data f Jason Furman Chairman, Council of Economic Advisers July 24, 2015 1. Data is Noisy: Look at Data With Less Volatility and Larger Samples Monthly Employment Growth, 2014-Present Thousands of Jobs 1,000 800 Oct-14: +836/-221 600 400 200 0 -200 Mar-15: Establishment Survey -502/+119 -400 Household Survey (Payroll Concept) -600 Jan-14 Apr-14 Jul-14 Oct-14 Jan-15 Apr-15 Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics. • Some commentators—and even some economists—tend to focus too closely on individual monthly or weekly data releases. But economic data are notoriously volatile. In many cases, a longer-term average paints a clearer picture, reducing the influence of less informative short-term fluctuations. • The household employment survey samples only 60,000 households, whereas the establishment employment survey samples 588,000 worksites, representing millions of workers. 1 2. Data is Noisy: Look Over Longer Periods Private Sector Payroll Employment, 2008-Present Monthly Job Gain/Loss, Seasonally Adjusted 600,000 400,000 200,000 0 -200,000 12-month -400,000 moving average -600,000 -800,000 -1,000,000 2008 2010 2012 2014 Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics. • Long-term moving averages can smooth out short-term volatility. Over the past year, our businesses have added 240,000 jobs per month on average, more than the 217,000 per month added over the prior 12 months. The evolving moving average provides a less noisy underlying picture of economic developments. 2 2. Data is Noisy: Look Over Longer Periods Weekly Unemployment Insurance Claims, 2012-2015 Thousands 450 400 Weekly Initial Jobless Claims 350 300 Four-Week Moving Average 7/18 250 2012 2013 2014 2015 Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.
    [Show full text]
  • Deflation: a Business Perspective
    Deflation: a business perspective Prepared by the Corporate Economists Advisory Group Introduction Early in 2003, ICC's Corporate Economists Advisory Group discussed the risk of deflation in some of the world's major economies, and possible consequences for business. The fear was that historically low levels of inflation and faltering economic growth could lead to deflation - a persistent decline in the general level of prices - which in turn could trigger economic depression, with widespread company and bank failures, a collapse in world trade, mass unemployment and years of shrinking economic activity. While the risk of deflation is now remote in most countries - given the increasingly unambiguous signs of global economic recovery - its potential costs are very high and would directly affect companies. This issues paper was developed to help companies better understand the phenomenon of deflation, and to give them practical guidance on possible measures to take if and when the threat of deflation turns into reality on a future occasion. What is deflation? Deflation is defined as a sustained fall in an aggregate measure of prices (such as the consumer price index). By this definition, changes in prices in one economic sector or falling prices over short periods (e.g., one or two quarters) do not qualify as deflation. Dec lining prices can be driven by an increase in supply due to technological innovation and rapid productivity gains. These supply-induced shocks are usually not problematic and can even be accompanied by robust growth, as experienced by China. A fall in prices led by a drop in demand - due to a severe economic cycle, tight economic policies or a demand-side shock - or by persistent excess capacity can be much more harmful, and is more likely to lead to persistent deflation.
    [Show full text]
  • This Is the Heritage Society After All – to 1893, and the Shape of This
    1 IRVING HERITAGE SOCIETY PRESENTATION By Maura Gast, Irving CVB October 2010 For tonight’s program, and because this is the Irving Heritage Society, after all, I thought I’d take a departure from my usual routine (which probably everyone in this room has heard too many times) and talk a little bit about the role the CVB plays in an historical context instead. I’m hopeful that as champions of heritage and history in general, that you’ll indulge me on this path tonight, and that you’ll see it all come back home to Irving by the time I’m done. Because there were really three key factors that led to the convention industry as we know it today and to our profession. And they are factors that, coupled with some amazing similarities to what’s going on in our world today, are worth paying attention to. How We as CVBs Came to Be • The Industrial Revolution – And the creation of manufacturing organizations • The Railroad Revolution • The Panic of 1893 One was the industrial revolution and its associated growth of large manufacturing organizations caused by the many technological innovations of that age. The second was the growth of the railroad, and ultimately the Highway system here in the US. And the third was the Panic of 1893. The Concept of “Associations” 2 The idea of “associations” has historically been an American concept – this idea of like‐minded people wanting to gather together in what came to be known as conventions. And when you think about it, there have been meetings and conventions of some kind taking place since recorded time.
    [Show full text]
  • Macroeconomics Course Outline and Syllabus
    City University of New York (CUNY) CUNY Academic Works Open Educational Resources New York City College of Technology 2018 Macroeconomics Course Outline and Syllabus Sean P. MacDonald CUNY New York City College of Technology How does access to this work benefit ou?y Let us know! More information about this work at: https://academicworks.cuny.edu/ny_oers/8 Discover additional works at: https://academicworks.cuny.edu This work is made publicly available by the City University of New York (CUNY). Contact: [email protected] COURSE OUTLINE FOR ECON 1101 – MACROECONOMICS New York City College of Technology Social Science Department COURSE CODE: 1101 TITLE: Macroeconomics Class Hours: 3, Credits: 3 COURSE DESCRIPTION: Fundamental economic ideas and the operation of the economy on a national scale. Production, distribution and consumption of goods and services, the exchange process, the role of government, the national income and its distribution, GDP, consumption function, savings function, investment spending, the multiplier principle and the influence of government spending on income and output. Analysis of monetary policy, including the banking system and the Federal Reserve System. COURSE PREREQUISITE: CUNY proficiency in reading and writing RECOMMENDED TEXTBOOK and MATERIALS* Krugman and Wells, Eds., Macroeconomics 3rd. ed, Worth Publishers, 2012 Leeds, Michael A., von Allmen, Peter and Schiming, Richard C., Macroeconomics, Pearson Education, Inc., 2006 Supplemental Reading (optional, but informative): Krugman, Paul, End This Depression
    [Show full text]
  • Research & Policy Brief No.47
    Research & Policy Briefs From the World Bank Malaysia Hub No. 47 May 24, 2021 Demand and Supply Dynamics in East Asia during the COVID-19 Recession Ergys Islamaj, Franz Ulrich Ruch, and Eka Vashakmadze The COVID-19 pandemic has devastated lives and damaged economies, requiring strong and decisive policy responses from governments. Developing Public Disclosure Authorized the optimal short-term and long-term policy response to the pandemic requires understanding the demand and supply factors that drive economic growth. The appropriate policy response will depend on the size and duration of demand and supply shocks. This Research & Policy Brief provides a decomposition of demand and supply dynamics at the macroeconomic level for the large developing economies of East Asia. The findings suggest that both demand and supply shocks were important drivers of output fluctuations during the first year of the pandemic. The demand shocks created an environment of deficient demand—reflected in large negative output gaps even after the unprecedented policy response—which is expected to last through 2021. The extant deficient demand is suggestive of continued need to support the economic recovery. Its size should guide policy makers in calibrating responses to ensure that recovery is entrenched, and that short-term supply disruptions do not lead to long-term declines in potential growth. The Pandemic-Induced Shock Low external demand will continue to affect economies reliant on tourism, while sluggish domestic demand will disproportionally affect The pandemic, national lockdowns, and reverberations from the rest economies with large services sectors. Understanding the demand of the world inflicted a massive shock to the East Asia and Pacific and supply factors that drive economic growth is critical for region in 2020 (World Bank 2020a).
    [Show full text]
  • Rebuilding the Public Sector for Economic Recovery and Resilience
    REBUILDING THE PUBLIC SECTOR FOR ECONOMIC RECOVERY AND RESILIENCE Sara Hinkley, Ph.D. March 2021 Executive Summary As the country crests the most devastating wave yet of the COVID-19 pandemic, there is growing optimism that the new administration will act quickly to stem the economic crisis: both by deploying the federal government’s leadership to control the pandemic itself and by using the federal government’s fiscal capacity to mitigate the economic damage caused by the public health crisis. The Biden administration will need to turn around both of these failures quickly in order to prevent further catastrophe for millions of Americans and a sustained recession. But the disaster unfolding now is not just a result of policy failures over the past eleven months; it is the result of decades of disinvestment and austerity, accelerated during the Great Recession, which made us more vulnerable to this crisis. Local, state, and national austerity set the country up for a harsh, prolonged, and profoundly unequal recession. We face a pivotal moment now: we can repeat those mistakes, leaving us more vulnerable to future crises, or we can build back our public sector to make us more economically resilient. groundworkcollaborative.org REBUILDING THE PUBLIC SECTOR FOR ECONOMIC RECOVERY AND RESILIENCE | 1 It is certainly bad luck that the long-predicted1 economic downturn was sparked by a pandemic, but our failure to meet this crisis with an effective public response is the outcome of years of deliberate policy choices. The austerity implemented after the Great Recession decimated both our ability to weather an economic downturn and our ability to handle any crisis requiring a strong public response.
    [Show full text]
  • Pandemic 101:A Roadmap to Help Students Grasp an Economic Shock
    Social Education 85(2) , pp.64–71 ©2021 National Council for the Social Studies Teaching the Economic Effects of the Pandemic Pandemic 101: A Roadmap to Help Students Grasp an Economic Shock Kim Holder and Scott Niederjohn This article focuses on the major national economic indicators and how they changed within the United States real GDP; the over the course of the COVID-19 pandemic. The indicators that we discuss include output from a Ford plant in Canada is not. Gross Domestic Product (GDP), the unemployment rate, interest rates, inflation, and Economists typically measure real GDP other variations of these measures. We will also present data that sheds light on the as a growth rate per quarter: Is GDP get- monetary and fiscal policy responses to the pandemic. Graphs of these statistics are ting bigger or smaller compared to a prior sure to grab teachers’ and students’ attention due to the dramatic shock fueled by the quarter? In fact, a common definition of pandemic. We will explain these economic indicators with additional attention to what a recession is two quarters in a row of they measure and the limitations they may present. Teachers will be introduced to the declining real GDP. Incidentally, it also Federal Reserve Economic Database (FRED), which is a rich source of graphs and measures total U.S. income (and spend- information for teacher instruction and student research. Further classroom-based ing) and that explains why real GDP per resources related to understanding the economic effects of the COVID-19 pandemic capita is a well-established measure used are also presented.
    [Show full text]
  • Working Paper
    WP 2020-12 December 2020 Working Paper Charles H. Dyson School of Applied Economics and Management Cornell University, Ithaca, New York 14853-7801 USA Social Externalities and Economic Analysis Marc Fleurbaey, Ravi Kanbur, and Brody Viney It is the Policy of Cornell University actively to support equality of educational and employment opportunity. No person shall be denied admission to any educational program or activity or be denied employmen t on the basis of any legally prohibited discrimination involving, but not limited to, such factors as race, color, creed, religion, national or ethnic origin, sex, age or handicap. The University is committed to the maintenance of affirmative action prog rams which will assure the continuation of such equality of opportunity. 2 Social Externalities and Economic Analysis Marc Fleurbaey, Ravi Kanbur, Brody Viney ThisThis version: versio Augustn: Aug 6,us 2020t 6, 20201 Abstract This paper considers and assesses the concept of social externalities through human interdependence, in relation to the economic analysis of externalities in the tradition of Pigou and Arrow, including the analysis of the commons. It argues that there are limits to economic analysis. Our proposal is to enlarge the perspective and start thinking about a broader framework in which any pattern of influence of an agent or a group of agents over a third party, which is not mediated by any economic, social, or psychological mechanism guaranteeing the alignment of the marginal net private benefit with marginal net social benefit, can be attached the “externality” label and be scrutinized for the likely negative consequences that result from the divergence .These consequences may be significant given the many interactions between the social and economic realms, and the scope for spillovers and feedback loops to emerge.
    [Show full text]
  • Demand Composition and the Strength of Recoveries†
    Demand Composition and the Strength of Recoveriesy Martin Beraja Christian K. Wolf MIT & NBER MIT & NBER September 17, 2021 Abstract: We argue that recoveries from demand-driven recessions with ex- penditure cuts concentrated in services or non-durables will tend to be weaker than recoveries from recessions more biased towards durables. Intuitively, the smaller the bias towards more durable goods, the less the recovery is buffeted by pent-up demand. We show that, in a standard multi-sector business-cycle model, this prediction holds if and only if, following an aggregate demand shock to all categories of spending (e.g., a monetary shock), expenditure on more durable goods reverts back faster. This testable condition receives ample support in U.S. data. We then use (i) a semi-structural shift-share and (ii) a structural model to quantify this effect of varying demand composition on recovery dynamics, and find it to be large. We also discuss implications for optimal stabilization policy. Keywords: durables, services, demand recessions, pent-up demand, shift-share design, recov- ery dynamics, COVID-19. JEL codes: E32, E52 yEmail: [email protected] and [email protected]. We received helpful comments from George-Marios Angeletos, Gadi Barlevy, Florin Bilbiie, Ricardo Caballero, Lawrence Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum, Fran¸coisGourio, Basile Grassi, Erik Hurst, Greg Kaplan, Andrea Lanteri, Jennifer La'O, Alisdair McKay, Simon Mongey, Ernesto Pasten, Matt Rognlie, Alp Simsek, Ludwig Straub, Silvana Tenreyro, Nicholas Tra- chter, Gianluca Violante, Iv´anWerning, Johannes Wieland (our discussant), Tom Winberry, Nathan Zorzi and seminar participants at various venues, and we thank Isabel Di Tella for outstanding research assistance.
    [Show full text]
  • Methodology for the National Accounts Main Aggregates Database CONTENTS
    Methodology for the National Accounts Main Aggregates Database CONTENTS Page I. INTRODUCTION A. Background ................................................................................................................................................................ 2 B. System of National Accounts ..................................................................................................................................... 2 C. Scope of the database ................................................................................................................................................. 2 D. Collection of data ....................................................................................................................................................... 3 E. Comparability of the national estimates ..................................................................................................................... 3 F. Nomenclature ............................................................................................................................................................. 4 G. Country coverage ....................................................................................................................................................... 5 H. Country groupings ...................................................................................................................................................... 5 I. Revisions ...................................................................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 1 the Demand for Economic Statistics
    Chapter 1 The Demand for Economic Statistics The media publish economic data on a daily basis. But who decides which statistics are useful and which are not? Why is housework not included in the national income, and why are financial data available in real time, while to know the number of people in employment analysts have to wait for weeks? Contrary to popular belief, both the availability and the nature of economic statistics are closely linked to developments in economic theory, the requirements of political decision-makers, and each country’s way of looking at itself. In practice, statistics are based on theoretical and interpretative reference models, and if these change, so does the picture the statistics paint of the economic system. Thus, the data we have today represent the supply and demand sides of statistical information constantly attempting to catch up with each other, with both sides being strongly influenced by the changes taking place in society and political life. This chapter offers a descriptive summary of how the demand for economic statistics has evolved from the end of the Second World War to the present, characterised by the new challenges brought about by globalisation and the rise of the services sector. 1 THE DEMAND FOR ECONOMIC STATISTICS One of the major functions of economic statistics is to develop concepts, definitions, classifications and methods that can be used to produce statistical information that describes the state of and movements in economic phenomena, both in time and space. This information is then used to analyse the behaviour of economic operators, forecast likely movements of the economy as a whole, make economic policy and business decisions, weigh the pros and cons of alternative investments, etc.
    [Show full text]