THE GODLEY-TOBIN LECTURE Robert Rowthorn WP 512 June 2019
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
“KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS– BACK FROM THE DEAD?” THE GODLEY-TOBIN LECTURE Robert Rowthorn WP 512 June 2019 KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS– BACK FROM THE DEAD? THE GODLEY-TOBIN LECTURE Centre for Business Research, University of Cambridge Working Paper no. 512 Robert Rowthorn Faculty of Economics and Kings College University of Cambridge Email: [email protected] June 2019 Abstract This paper surveys some the main developments in macroeconomics since the anti- Keynesian counter-revolution forty years ago. It covers both mainstream and heterodox economics. Amongst the topics discussed are: New Keynesian economics, Modern Monetary Theory (MMT), expansionary fiscal contraction, unconventional monetary policy, the Phillips curve, and hysteresis. The conclusion is that Keynesian economics is alive and well, and that there has been a degree of convergence between heterodox and mainstream economics. JEL Codes: E60, E10, E31, B22. Keywords: Macroeconomics, Keynesian economics, Keynes Acknowledgements: I should like to thank Wendy Carlin, Geoffrey Harcourt, Bill Martin and Thomas Michl for their comments on an earlier draft of this paper. The paper is forthcoming in Review of Keynesian Economics. Further information about the Centre for Business Research can be found at: www.cbr.cam.ac.uk 1. Introduction When Thomas Palley asked me to give this year’s Godley-Tobin Lecture, he suggested that I might present my views about modern developments in macroeconomics. At first, I baulked at the idea of covering such a vast field, but then I decided it would be an interesting challenge. To the extent that there is one, the underlying theme of my lecture is that, since the initial anti-Keynesian counter-revolution forty years ago, Keynesian economics has made something of a come-back. It would be an exaggeration to say that ‘we are all Keynesians now’, but surveys indicate that many leading economists in the USA and the UK have Keynesian sympathies (IGM Forum, 2014), (CFM, 2014). 2. Background Forty years ago macroeconomics was dominated by Keynesians. Many of their views could be traced back to Keynes, although there had also been various innovations by authors such as Alvin Hansen, John Hicks, Abba Lerner and William Phillips. The defining features of Keynesian economics included a rejection of Say’s law – the notion that supply creates its own demand; the paradox of thrift whereby an attempt to save more may result in less total saving because of its negative impact on aggregate income; a clear distinction between saving as abstention from consumption and investment as expenditure on productive capital; the view that saving and investment are brought into equality by variations in aggregate income. Keynesians believed that a capitalist economy is crisis-prone and in the absence of an external stimulus may get stuck in a prolonged depression. They believed that conventional monetary policy is ineffectual in such a situation - ‘like pushing on a string’ – and that fiscal policy (tax cuts, more government expenditure) is a more effective way to promote recovery. This was probably their most important tenet. Some Keynesians believed that persistent unemployment is explained by the (inescapable) downward rigidity of money wages. Others disagreed. Some Keynesians believed in the existence of a stable trade-off between unemployment and inflation (the Phillips curve). Some believed in the importance of dynamic returns to scale (Verdoorn’s law, learning by doing). Like Keynes himself, many stressed the importance of radical uncertainty in economic behaviour as opposed to quantifiable risk which is such a prominent feature of modern DSGE models. By the late 1960s, and especially during the oil crisis of the 1970s, governments were finding it difficult to reconcile full employment with low inflation. This failure 1 led to a backlash against Keynesian economics and ensured a hearing for economists who rejected much of the Keynesian heritage. These were known as the ‘new classical economists’ – not to be confused with neoclassical (Hoover, 1988). The main theoretical innovations of the new classical economics were: the Lucas critique, micro-foundations, time inconsistency and rational expectations. I should like to discuss these topics in depth, but there is no time. 3. The New Keynesians The new classical economics gave rise to what are known as Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) models. These models were developed by Kydland and Prescott (1982) and Prescott (1986) in their work on real business cycles. So- called ‘ad hoc’ behavioural equations describing relations between aggregate variables were replaced by optimisation conditions for consumers and firms. The key tenets of these early DSGE models were perfect competition, market clearing, complete markets and rational expectations. Business cycles were seen as efficient responses to technology shocks. Real business cycle theory gained a following amongst academics but had little influence on central banks and other policy makers. Some of the predictions of the theory were at odds with reality or made implausible assumptions about parameter values (Mankiw, 1989). In the light of these failings real business cycle theory was soon modified. The assumption of perfect competition was replaced by monopoly pricing and provision was made for nominal wage and price ‘rigidities’ (Calvo pricing). The new theory continued to assume complete markets and optimising agents with infinite time horizons and rational expectations. This new theory became known as New Keynesianism, because business cycles were no longer viewed as efficient and markets did not always clear.1 It has become the dominant paradigm in mainstream macro-economics. New Keynesian models have undergone many changes over the years. For example, the influential Smets and Wooters (2003, 2007) model in addition to nominal wage and price ‘rigidities’ also contained real ‘rigidities’ in the form of habit formation in consumption, costs of adjustment in capital accumulation, and variable capacity utilization. Other New Keynesian models include modifications such as the existence of a financial sector, a zero lower bound for the interest rate, and a fraction of ‘hand to mouth’ or credit constrained consumers. In the HANK (heterogeneous agent New Keynesian) model of Kaplan, Moll and Violante (2018), the economy is populated by a continuum of households indexed by their holdings of liquid assets, 2 illiquid assets, and their idiosyncratic labor productivity. In the SAM (search and matching) models, involuntary unemployment arises because of frictions in the operation of the labour market. The effect of these numerous, sometimes ‘ad hoc’ changes is to make the original DSGE models more realistic and allows them to generate Keynesian results. The assumption of sticky wages and prices allows monetary policy to have real effects. The inclusion of credit constrained or hand to mouth consumers may yield Keynesian results for fiscal policy. Stiglitz (2018) has described these various modifications as Ptolemeic epicycles and he regards their proliferation as a sign that the New Keynesian research programme is degenerate. Others see the continuing stream of modifications as evidence of the programme’s vitality. Either way, the effect of these modifications is to generate certain Keynesian results. However, in terms of basic methodology, New Keynesianism remains far removed from either Keynes or traditional Keynesianism. The difference is most striking in their treatment of expectations. Whereas Keynes stressed the importance of radical uncertainty and animal spirits, the New Keynesians assume that decision-making is based on quantifiable, known probabilities, and that agents maximise an infinite stream of expected net benefits. After a transient shock, agents re-optimise and follow a new path that, in the absence of further shocks, will take the economy back to the original equilibrium trajectory. Keynes explicitly rejected this way of thinking as the following quotation indicates: ‘The orthodox theory assumes that we have knowledge of the future of a kind quite different from that which we actually possess. This false rationalization follows the lines of the Benthamite calculus. The hypothesis of a calculable future leads to a wrong interpretation of the principles of behavior which the need for action compels us to adopt, and to an underestimation of the concealed factors of utter doubt, precariousness, hope and fear.’ (Keynes, 1937, p222) 3 The New Keynesians also depart from Keynes is their treatment of consumption and saving. They assume that a significant fraction of households maximize their discounted expected utility, subject to an intertemporal budget constraint. If such a household reduces its consumption in one period, it will simultaneously increase planned consumption in some future period. This relationship between present and future consumption is expressed in an Euler equation. Keynes (2017, p182) rejected this view of saving: ‘An act of individual saving means – so to speak – a decision not to have dinner today. But it does not necessitate a decision to have dinner or buy a pair of boots a week hence or a year hence or to consume any specified thing at any specified date. Thus, it depresses the business of preparing today’s dinner without stimulating the business of making ready for some future act of consumption. It is not a substitution of future consumption- demand for present consumption-demand – it is a net diminution of such demand.’ 4. Other Models