Returns to Scale, Market Power, and the Nature of Price Rigidity in New Keynesian Models with Self-Fulfilling Expectations

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Returns to Scale, Market Power, and the Nature of Price Rigidity in New Keynesian Models with Self-Fulfilling Expectations KEVIN X.D. HUANG QINGLAI MENG Returns to Scale, Market Power, and the Nature of Price Rigidity in New Keynesian Models with Self-Fulfilling Expectations Increasing returns to scale and firms’ market power are two potential sources of sunspot expectations in neoclassical models. We show that in New Keyne- sian models, returns to scale and market power can have fundamentally dif- ferent implications for broad macroeconomic issues, including self-fulfilling expectations, depending on the nature of price rigidity. Our findings sug- gest that the design of stabilization monetary policy can depend on precise knowledge about the economy’s real and nominal features. Therefore, a clear understanding of the specific economic environment and its relevance to monetary policymaking for ensuring macroeconomic stability can be an integrated part of monetary policy practice. JEL codes: E12, E31, E52 Keywords: returns to scale, market power, price rigidity, self-fulfilling expectations. THE SOURCES OF SUNSPOT EXPECTATIONS unrelated to economic fundamentals have long been studied in macroeconomics. In neoclassical models, two real features pertaining to production technology and market structure, namely, increasing returns to scale and firms’ market power, have been found as potential factors for real indeterminacy of equilibrium and sunspot-driven business cycles.1 In New Keynesian models, the focus has been on implications of nominal features We are grateful to Jang-Ting Guo, seminar participants at the University of California at Riverside, and two anonymous referees of this journal for helpful comments and suggestions. KEVIN X.D. HUANG is a Professor in the Department of Economics at Vanderbilt University (E-mail: [email protected]). QINGLAI MENG is an Associate Professor in the Department of Economics at Oregon State University (E-mail: [email protected]). Received August 25, 2011; and accepted in revised form February 10, 2012. 1. For the former, see Benhabib and Farmer (1994, 1996), Farmer and Guo (1994), Wen (1998), and Benhabib and Wen (2004), among others. For the latter, see the survey by Schmitt-Grohe´ (1997). Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 46, No. 2–3 (March–April 2014) C 2014 The Ohio State University 294 : MONEY, CREDIT AND BANKING pertaining to price rigidity and monetary policy for multiple equilibria and sunspot- driven fluctuations. We study the interactions of these real and nominal features. The general thesis of this paper is that these real features can have fundamentally different implications for macroeconomic dynamics in New Keynesian models, depending on the nature of nominal price rigidity. To help demonstrate this point, we make use of two canonical sticky price models, the Rotemberg (1982) model of costly price adjustment and the Calvo (1983) model of partial price adjustment, which are commonly viewed as iden- tical up to a linear approximation. We find that although the linearized equilibrium systems of the two models are alike in their reduced forms, as similarly demonstrated by Benhabib, Schmitt-Grohe, and Uribe (2000, 2001), among others, structural fun- damentals pertaining to the underlying production technology and market structure affect the elasticity of nominal price inflation with respect to real marginal cost in fundamentally different ways across the two types of stickiness. This gives rise to a different linkage from the structural fundamentals to the slope of the reduced-form Phillips curve, depending on whether price rigidity is modeled one way or another. We analyze in some depth the differences in this connection across the two models and their causes, which can have broad implications for inflation and other aggregate dynamics. While these differences hold in the general context of model specifications and can be relevant for a wide range of macroeconomic issues, we focus our attention in this paper on one important issue, that is, their implications for self-fulfilling expectations and sunspot-induced macroeconomic instability. To this end, we make use of these two models with a flexible forward-inflation targeting policy, under which the mon- etary authority sets nominal interest rate in response to variations in expected future inflation and current output. This makes it particularly convenient for one to digest our discrete-time analysis in the light of the local indeterminacy analysis of Benhabib, Schmitt-Grohe, and Uribe (2000, 2001) that is conducted in continuous time, where the monetary authority sets a nominal interest rate as a function of the instantaneous rate of inflation, since, as is now well known, the instantaneous rate of inflation in a continuous-time setting is the right derivative of the logged price level and, thus, the discrete-time counterpart of a continuous-time policy rule that sets the interest rate in response to the instantaneous rate of inflation is characterized by forward-looking policy that responds to expected future inflation.2 Further, as is also well known, forward-inflation targeting is prone to real indeterminacy of equilibrium, and, thus, the contrasts between the different implications of those real features of the economy for sunspot expectations under the two types of nominal rigidities are quantitatively strik- ing with forward-looking policy. But, most importantly, forward-inflation targeting is justified on the ground of both policy effectiveness and central bank accountability 2. See, for example, Obstfeld and Rogoff (1995, p. 522, footnote 10) for an enlightening discussion of this point. KEVIN X.D. HUANG AND QINGLAI MENG : 295 and credibility.3 On the other hand, a flexible targeting rule, which allows the nominal interest rate to respond not only to expected future inflation, but also to other endoge- nous variables, such as current output, is crucial for avoiding policy-induced macroe- conomic instability.4 This is why such a flexible inflation-forecast targeting procedure has been advocated by many researchers5 and has become a dominant framework for monetary policymaking at central banks around the world.6 This is to say that the kind of monetary policy considered in this paper is of paramount practical interest. We show that both the degree of returns to scale in production (including not only increasing but also constant and decreasing returns to scale) and firms’ market power can have exact opposite implications for macroeconomic stability in the Rotemberg model than in the Calvo model. Here, we summarize our results briefly. First, in the Calvo model, increasing returns to scale is a potential source of sunspot expectations,7 as in the real models, whereas decreasing returns to scale or fixed factors is potentially a stabilizing factor for the economy. In the Rotemberg model, by contrast, it is decreasing returns to scale or fixed factors that is a potential source of self-fulfilling expectations, whereas increasing returns to scale may actually be a stabilizing factor for the economy. Second, in the Calvo model, firms’ market power is a potential source of sunspot-driven fluctuations, as in the real models, provided that production technology exhibits decreasing returns to scale or fixed factors, while such market power may actually be a stabilizing factor if production technology exhibits increasing returns to scale. In the Rotemberg model, by contrast, market power of firms is a stabilizing factor for the economy regardless of the degree of returns to scale in production technology. We show these contrasts analytically for the case with labor as the only productive input and numerically for the case with endogenous capital accumulation. We show that these contrasts continue to hold in the presence of policy inertia in the form of interest rate smoothing, which is considered an 3. See, among others, Svensson (1997), Bernanke and Woodford (1997), Batini and Haldane (1999), Levin, Wieland, and Williams (2003), Orphanides and Williams (2003), and Bernanke and Woodford (2004). 4. See, among others, Clarida, Gal´ı, and Gertler (1998, 1999), Christiano and Gust (1999), Rotemberg and Woodford (1999), Woodford (1999, 2003), Levin, Wieland, and Williams (2003), Kurozumi and Zandweghe (2008), and Huang, Meng, and Xue (2009). 5. See, among others, Svensson (1997, 1999), Svensson and Woodford (2004), and Goodhart (2001). 6. This policy practice started in the industrial and middle-income countries in the late 1980s (see, e.g., Leiderman and Svensson 1995, Bernanke and Mishkin 1997, Bernanke et al. 1999), and spread to the transition and emerging-market economies in the late 1990s (see, e.g., Schaechter, Stone, and Zelmer 2000, Jonas and Mishkin 2004, Roger and Stone 2005), with more moving toward this direction. Indeed, while the U.S. Federal Reserve, the European Central Bank, and the Bank of Japan are usually viewed as having followed some implicit inflation-forecast targeting procedures, estimated forward-looking interest rate feedback rules explain well the behavior of interest rates in the U.S., Germany, and Japan (see, e.g., Chinn and Dooley 1997, Clarida and Gertler 1997, Clarida, Gal´ı, and Gertler 1998, Orphanides 2000, Orphanides and Williams 2003, Carare and Stone 2006). 7. Xiao (2008) and Huang and Meng (2009) also use the Calvo model to analyze the implications of increasing returns to scale for macroeconomic stability under alternative interest rate policy rules, and Weder (2006) conducts a similar analysis in a monetary model with flexible prices. In a monetary model with a constant returns to scale technology and labor as the only productive input, Weder (2008) shows how the Calvo price setting may reduce the scope of indeterminate equilibria under a constant money supply rule. 296 : MONEY, CREDIT AND BANKING important ingredient in monetary policy practice (see, e.g., Sack 1998, Kozicki 1999, Clarida, Gal´ı, and Gertler 2000, Orphanides 2000, Levin, Wieland, and Williams 2003, Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans 2005, Levin et al. 2005). These results obtained in the canonical models may convey broad implications. Understanding these implications may be important for the monetary policy practices of central banks that aim to preempt sunspot expectations and fluctuations unrelated to economic fundamentals.
Recommended publications
  • Internal Increasing Returns to Scale and Economic Growth
    NBER TECHNICAL WORKING PAPER SERIES INTERNAL INCREASING RETURNS TO SCALE AND ECONOMIC GROWTH John A. List Haiwen Zhou Technical Working Paper 336 http://www.nber.org/papers/t0336 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 March 2007 The views expressed herein are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. © 2007 by John A. List and Haiwen Zhou. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Internal Increasing Returns to Scale and Economic Growth John A. List and Haiwen Zhou NBER Technical Working Paper No. 336 March 2007 JEL No. E10,E22,O41 ABSTRACT This study develops a model of endogenous growth based on increasing returns due to firms? technology choices. Particular attention is paid to the implications of these choices, combined with the substitution of capital for labor, on economic growth in a general equilibrium model in which the R&D sector produces machines to be used for the sector producing final goods. We show that incorporating oligopolistic competition in the sector producing finals goods into a general equilibrium model with endogenous technology choice is tractable, and we explore the equilibrium path analytically. The model illustrates a novel manner in which sustained per capita growth of consumption can be achieved?through continuous adoption of new technologies featuring the substitution between capital and labor. Further insights of the model are that during the growth process, the size of firms producing final goods increases over time, the real interest rate is constant, and the real wage rate increases over time.
    [Show full text]
  • The Historical Role of the Production Function in Economics and Business
    American Journal of Business Education – April 2011 Volume 4, Number 4 The Historical Role Of The Production Function In Economics And Business David Gordon, University of Saint Francis, USA Richard Vaughan. University of Saint Francis, USA ABSTRACT The production function explains a basic technological relationship between scarce resources, or inputs, and output. This paper offers a brief overview of the historical significance and operational role of the production function in business and economics. The origin and development of this function over time is initially explored. Several various production functions that have played an important historical role in economics are explained. These consist of some well known functions, such as the Cobb-Douglas, Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES), and Generalized and Leontief production functions. This paper also covers some relatively newer production functions, such as the Arrow, Chenery, Minhas, and Solow (ACMS) functions, the transcendental logarithmic (translog), and other flexible forms of the production function. Several important characteristics of the production function are also explained in this paper. These would include, but are not limited to, items such as the returns to scale of the function, the separability of the function, the homogeneity of the function, the homotheticity of the function, the output elasticity of factors (inputs), and the degree of input substitutability that each function exhibits. Also explored are some of the duality issues that potentially exist between certain production and cost functions. The information contained in this paper could act as a pedagogical aide in any microeconomics-based course or in a production management class. It could also play a role in certain marketing courses, especially at the graduate level.
    [Show full text]
  • Increasing Returns to Scale, Dynamics of Industrial Structure and Size Distribution of Firms†
    Increasing Returns to Scale, Dynamics of Industrial Structure and Size Distribution of Firms† Ying Fan, Menghui Li, Zengru Di∗ Department of Systems Science, School of Management, Beijing Normal University, Beijing 100875, China _______________________________________________________________________ Abstract A model is presented of the market dynamics to emphasis the effects of increasing returns to scale, including the description of the born and death of the adaptive producers. The evolution of market structure and its behavior with the technological shocks are discussed. Its dynamics is in good agreement with some empirical “stylized facts” of industrial evolution. Together with the diversities of demand and adaptive growth strategies of firms, the generalized model has reproduced the power-law distribution of firm size. Three factors mainly determine the competitive dynamics and the skewed size distributions of firms: 1. Self-reinforcing mechanism; 2. Adaptive firm grows strategies; 3. Demand diversities or widespread heterogeneity in the technological capabilities of different firms. JEL classification: L11, C61 Key words: Increasing returns, Industry dynamics, Size distribution of firms _______________________________________________________________________ Ⅰ. INTRODUCTION In the past decades, the evolutionary perspective has contributed lot to the economics (Arthur, Durlauf, and Lane, 1997; Dosi, Nelson, 1994; Aruka, 2001). The economy is studied as an evolving complex system with many features in complexity such as nonlinear interactions and emergent properties. In reality, the economic system consists † The paper has been presented in the 1st Sino-German workshop on the evolutionary economics, March, 2004, Beijing, China. The authors thank all the participants for their helpful comments and suggestions. The work is supported by the NSFC under the grant No. 70371072 and grant No.
    [Show full text]
  • Returns to Scale and Size in Agricultural Economics
    Returns to Scale and Size in Agricultural Economics John W. McClelland, Michael E. Wetzstein, and Wesley N. Musser Differences between the concepts of returns to size and returns to scale are systematically reexamined in this paper. Specifically, the relationship between returns to scale and size are examined through the use of the envelope theorem. A major conclusion of the paper is that the level of abstraction in applying a cost function derived from a homothetic technology within a relevant range of the expansion path may not be severe when compared to the theoretical, estimative, and computational advantages of these technologies. Key words: elasticity of scale, envelope theorem, returns to size. Agricultural economists investigating long-run scale, Euler's theorem, and the form of pro- relationships among levels of inputs, outputs, duction functions. However, the direct link be- and costs generally use concepts of returns to tween returns to size and scale is not devel- scale and size. Econometric studies which uti- oped. Hanoch investigates the elasticity of scale lize production or profit functions commonly and size in terms of variation with output and are concerned with returns to scale (de Janvry; illustrates that only at the cost-minimizing in- Lau and Yotopoulos), while synthetic studies put combinations are the two concepts equiv- of relationships between output and cost uti- alent. Hanoch further provides a proposition lize returns to size (Hall and LaVeen; Rich- stating that Frisch's "Regular Ulta-Passum ardson and Condra). However, as noted by Law" is neither necessary nor sufficient for a Bassett, the word scale is sometimes also used production technology to be associated with to mean size (of a plant).
    [Show full text]
  • Price Dispersion and Increasing Returns to Scaleଝ
    Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 73 (2010) 406–417 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jebo Price dispersion and increasing returns to scaleଝ David M. Levy a, Michael D. Makowsky b,∗ a Department of Economics, George Mason University, United States b Department of Economics, Towson University, United States article info abstract Article history: We present a model in which price dispersion allows the market to remain competitive Received 28 April 2008 in the long run amidst increasing returns to scale. The model hinges upon turnover in the Received in revised form 7 October 2009 productive technology-leading firm, price dispersion resultant of Stigler’s logic of rational Accepted 9 October 2009 search, and limited excludability of knowledge. Price dispersion, traditionally viewed as Available online 23 October 2009 an efficiency loss derivative of imperfect information in the market protects competition from being destroyed by innovation and increasing returns to scale. Bankruptcy occurs in JEL classification: a form similar to the gambler’s ruin. The model requires no entry or replacement of failed C63 L11 firms. The number of active firms in a market reaches a stationary state increasing with, O33 and contingent on, search costs. D83 © 2009 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. Keywords: Increasing returns to scale Price dispersion Search “Professor Chamberlin was right in concluding that perfect competition is a poor instrument in analyzing selling costs. His results might have been more informative, however, if he had chosen to drop the assumption that the economy was stationary, rather than the assumption that the economy was competitive.” – George J.
    [Show full text]
  • The Conflict Between General Equilibrium and the Marshallian
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive The Conflict Between General Equilibrium and the Marshallian Cross Saglam, Ismail and Zaman, Asad September 2010 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/40275/ MPRA Paper No. 40275, posted 26 Jul 2012 13:32 UTC The Conflict Between General Equilibrium and the Marshallian Cross By Ismail Saglam1 and Asad Zaman2 Abstract. There is a conflict in the mechanism for price determination used in a Marshallian partial equilibrium supply and demand framework and the Walrasian general equilibrium framework. It is generally thought that partial equilibrium is a simplified approximation to the complexities of the general model. The goal of this paper is to show that there is a strong conflict between the two models – intuitions and heuristics suggested by partial equilibrium are contradicted by extensions to the general equilibrium case. We review the literature on the conflict and also provide a very simple model where partial equilibrium analysis fails completely. Several intuitively plausible remedies fail to restore partial equilibrium results. We show that Marshallian analysis can be made to work only under rather stringent conditions requiring joint production with low fixed costs and decreasing returns resulting in identical production proportions by all producers. 1Corresponding author. [email protected], Department of Economics, TOBB University of Economics and Technology. [email protected], International Institute of Islamic Economics, International Islamic University. 1 Introduction Today most economic analysis as well as the majority of elementary textbooks explain price determinations via the partial equilibrium method, which gained its distinction with the publication of the first edition of Principles of Economics in 1890 by Alfred Marshall.
    [Show full text]
  • Resource Limitations, the Demand for Education and Economic Growth--A Macroeconomic View
    DOCUMENT RESUME ED 053 282 VT 010 927 AUTHOR Stam, Jerome M. TITLE Resource Limitations, the Demand for Education and Economic Growth--A Macroeconomic View. INSTITUTION Michigan State Univ., East Lansing. Dept. of Agricultural Economics. SPONS AGENCY Economic Research Service (DOA), Washington, D.C. REPORT NO AER-147 PUB DATE Aug 69 NOTE 32p. EDRS PRICE EDRS Price MF-$0.65 HC-$3.29 DESCRIPTORS *Economic Development, *Economic Factors, *Human Resources, *Input Output Analysis, *Models ABSTRACT To develop a theoretical framework for explaining the observed change in demand for human skill and knowledge that occurs with economic growth, a macroeconomic analysis was made of economic variables which are influenced by political, social, and cultural factors. In the three-dimensional framework, total output (Y) of all final goods and services produced in the economy during one specified time period is treated as a function of three inputs, capital (K), labor (L), and natural resources (R). Because the framework contains only four variables, an entire economy can be theoretically analyzed. Thus, to demonstrate how the need for human skill and knowledge is generated, an analysis of economic development reveals that as more complex forms of non-human capital are required, more human capital is also require .The demand for human skill and knowledge is largely a function of factor disproportions among the basic inputs, K, Le and R which generate certain basic forces. (SB) '' yenrrn rICo 141 LC uJ Agricultural Economics Report REPORT NO. 147 AUGUST 1969 RESOURCE LIMITATIONS, THE DEMAND FOR EDUCATION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH-A MACROECONOMIC VIEW U.S. DEPARTMENT OF HEALTH, EOUCATION & WELFARE OFFICE OF EOUCATION THIS DOCUMENT HAS BEEN REPRODUCED EXACTLY AS RECEIVED FROM THE PERSON OR ORGANIZATION ORIGI iATING IT.
    [Show full text]
  • Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution
    Review of Consumer Choice 1 1. Consumer’s problem • Which factors determine consumer’s choice? 2. Single consumer’s demand function 3. What happens when some variables change? • Income changes • Price changes • Why is this important? 4. Example of an economic model: • Difference between exogenous and endogenous variables. • Role of the assumptions New topic: Producer’s Choice 2 Key question: Price What factors influence supply? Supply 700 Eu • 400 Eu • 0 600 1500 Quantity Firm’s decisions 3 Each firm has to decide 1. To operate or not? 2. Which product(s) to produce? 3. Which materials and in which combinations to use? 4. How many units to produce? Production Function 4 Resources, such as labor and capital equipment, that firms use to manufacture goods and services are called inputs or factors of production. The amount of goods and services produced by the firm is the firm’s output. The production function gives the maximum amount of output the firm can produce for any given quantity of inputs. Production Function 5 The production function gives the maximum amount of output the firm can produce for any given quantity of inputs. Example: One input 1 Q f (L) L2 Q = f(L) D 7 • 4 • C Labor 16 49 Example 6 Suppose that a firm produces only with labor and the production function is 푄 = 퐹 퐿 = 퐿 That is, L units of labor produce 퐿 units of output. If the firm has to pay a wage of w=$10 for each unit of labor and can sell each unit of output for the price p=$10, how many units will the firm produce? Production Function 7 Ipad 2: • The tablet itself is assembled in China (and by the end of 2011 also in Brazil) by Taiwan-based Foxconn.
    [Show full text]
  • Economics 101A (Lecture 15)
    Economics 101A (Lecture 15) Stefano DellaVigna March 9, 2017 Outline 1. Cost Minimization: Example 2. Cost Curves and Supply Function 1 Cost Minimization: Example Continue example above: = ( )= • Cost minimization: • min + = What is the return to scale for this example? • Increase of all inputs: (z) with scalar, 1 • How much does input increase? • — Decreasing returns to scale: for all z and 1 (z) (z) — Constant returns to scale: for all z and 1 (z)= (z) — Increasing returns to scale: for all z and 1 (z) (z) Returns to scale depend on + 1: ( )= • ≶ () () = + = + ( ) Solutions: • — Optimal amount of labor: 1 + −+ ∗ ( )= µ¶ à ! — Optimal amount of capital: 1 + −+ ∗ ( )= = µ¶ à ! 1 + + = µ¶ à ! Check various comparative statics: • — ∗ 0 (technological progress and unem- ployment) — ∗ 0 (more workers needed to produce more output) — ∗ 0∗ 0 (substitute away from more expensive inputs) Parallel comparative statics for • ∗ Cost function • ( )=∗ ( )+∗ ( )= 1 + + − + = ⎡ ³ ´ ⎤ µ¶ + ⎢ + ⎥ ⎢ ⎥ ⎣ ³ ´ ⎦ Define := −+ + + • ³ ´ ³ ´ Cost-minimizing output choice: • 1 + max − µ¶ First order condition: • 1 (+) 1 −+ =0 − + µ¶ Second order condition: • 1 2(+) 1 1 ( + ) −+ − 2 − + + µ¶ When is the second order condition satisfied? • Solution: • — + =1(CRS): S.o.c.equalto0 ∗ Solution depends on ∗ For produce ∗ ∗ →∞ For = produce any [0 ) ∗ ∗ ∈ ∞ For produce =0 ∗ ∗ — + 1 (IRS): S.o.c. positive ∗ Solution of f.o.c. is a minimum! ∗ Solution is ∗ ∗ →∞ Keep increasing production since higher pro- ∗ duction is associated with higher returns — + 1 (DRS): s.o.c. negative. OK! ∗ Solution of f.o.c. is an interior optimum ∗ This is the only "well-behaved" case under per- ∗ fect competition Here can define a supply function ∗ 2CostCurves Nicholson, Ch. 10, pp. 341-349; Ch.
    [Show full text]
  • Growth and Ideas
    Growth and Ideas Prof. Lutz Hendricks Econ520 February 19, 2021 1 / 29 Questions 1. How does TFP growth come about? 2. What types of policies could manipulate long-run growth? The dominant view today: Innovation (the production of new "ideas") is what drives TFP growth. 2 / 29 Objectives In this section you will learn: 1. how ideas differ from ordinary goods (non-rivalry) 2. how non-rivalry generates scale effects 3. how scale effects make sustained growth possible 3 / 29 Ideas We take the view that productivity growth is due to new "ideas". Ideas are broadly defined to include: I Designs for new products: the microchip, the steam engine,... I New ways of organizing production: Walmart, the assembly line. Key assumption: Ideas are produced like other goods. I By profit maximizing firms. I The profit of innovation is the rent of owning a patent. The stock of knowledge is a form of capital. 4 / 29 Non-rivalry How then do ideas differ from physical capital? I they are produced by investing goods I they are accumulated over time There is just one difference: non-rivalry 5 / 29 Non-rivalry Most goods are rival I only a limited number of people can use a good at the same time I examples: cars, computers, ... Ideas can be used by many at the same time. I software, music I product designs (blueprints) I production methods (just-in-time production, assembly line). 6 / 29 Why Does Non-rivalry Matter? We know: capital accumulation cannot sustain growth. We will show: Accumulation of non-rival “knowledge capital” can sustain growth.
    [Show full text]
  • 202ARE Lecture Notes
    ARE 202: Welfare: Tools and Applications Spring 2018 Thibault FALLY Lecture Notes 05 – Production and Industry Equilibrium ARE202 - Lec 05 - Production 1 / 38 Production side Topics for a brief intro: Returns to scale : crucial in applied micro, growth, development, trade Producer surplus and profits as measure of welfare in partial eq. Industry equilibrium with free entry : yields zero profits in long term, and other implications for aggregate production function, etc. Beyond firms: I want to talk about equilibrium on factor markets and return to factors Putting firms and factors together: “Production Possibility Frontier” Imperfect competition: monopoly pricing and monopolistic competition ARE202 - Lec 05 - Production 2 / 38 Plan A- Tools 1) Returns to scale 2) Producer surplus and duality in supply side 3) Industry equilibrium with free entry 4) Equilibrium on factor markets 5) Monopolistic competition B- Illustration Costinot and Donaldson (2016): Illustrate how to recover PPF and equilibrium prices in Agriculture from output and sales data across US counties, and how to infer gains from economic integration and productivity improvements (1880-1997) ARE202 - Lec 05 - Production 3 / 38 Returns to scale Consider production function Y = f (L1, L2, ... ) with inputs Lf Constant returns to scale (CRS): f (λL1, λ L2, ... ) = λF (L1, L2, ... ) for any λ > 0 CRS, increasing or decreasing returns to scale? f (L) = aL − b? ρ ρ 1 f (L, K) = [ aLL + aK K ] ρ ? f (L, K) = aL αK β? 2 log f (L, K) = aL log L + aK log K + aKL (log K − log L) ? (see also translog production functions) IRS often modeled with a fixed cost (see IRS example above) In these examples: elasticity of substitution between K and L? ARE202 - Lec 05 - Production 4 / 38 Returns to scale CRS often assumed in macro or trade (see later slides with free entry) Note: Any DRS industry can be re-interpreted as CRS: Just add a specific factor (hypothetical or not).
    [Show full text]
  • Increasing Returns and Unemployment Theory
    Increasingreturns and unemploymenttheory Increasingreturns and the foundationsof unemploymenttheory: an explanation MARTIN L. WEITZMAN I would like to express my gratitudeto the contributorsfor their stimu- lating comments and to the editor for kindly providing me with an opportunityto reply. There is much in the comments with which I agree, and from which I have learned. I certainlywish I had expressed myself more clearly on certain points in the article. I hope that my remarks here will help to clarify some of these points. At first I thoughtI would replyto each commentby addressing,more or less systematically and exhaustively,the specific issues they were raising. Now I am not so sure that is the best approach.The issues are too disparate, and some of them, if I may be excused for expressing myself so directly,seem to me beside the point. Instead,I thinkit would be more fruitfulif I tried to restatemy general thesis, in words, taking into accountas best I can the criticisms that seem to me most relevant. My immediatepoint of departureis the "Keynesian message." By that term I have in mind not anotherrendition of what Keynes meant in The General Theory. (I am not particularlyqualified, in any event, to give such a rendition.) I have in mind more the spirit of that which constitutes what might be called the Keynesian outlook or economic philosophy. Now this "spirit" is hardlyan objective entity, and need- less to say it is my interpretationof it which is here recorded.Neverthe- less, and allowing for normalhuman differences in perception,I would hope there might be rough agreementon those features I am about to highlight.
    [Show full text]