Today Returns to Scale

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Today Returns to Scale 3/31/2016 1 Intermediate Microeconomics W3211 Lecture 14: Introduction Cost Functions and Optimal Output Columbia University, Spring 2016 Mark Dean: [email protected] 2 3 4 The Story So Far…. Today • We have set up the firm’s problem • Describe the relationship between returns to scale and • Converts inputs to outputs in order to maximize profit cost functions • Thought about how to solve the firm’s problem when there is • Solve the second part of the firm’s problem: only one input • E.g. economists who only need labor to produce paper • Choose the output level that maximizes profit given costs • Thought about how to solve the problem when the firm needs • i.e. the profit maximization problem to use more than one input to produce output • Think about comparative statics • Suggested that we can solve this problem by splitting it into two • i.e. what happens when we change the prices of inputs and outputs 1. Construct the cost function for the firm, by finding the lowest cost way of producing each output (the cost minimization problem) 2. Choose the output level that maximizes profit given these costs (the profit maximization problem) • Figured out how to solve the firm’s cost minimization problem 6 Returns to Scale and Cost Functions • In the last lecture we defined returns to scale for production functions • Decreasing returns to scale: doubling the inputs less than doubles the output Returns to Scale and Cost ,,,…,,,… • Constant returns to scale: doubling the inputs exactly doubles Functions the output ,,,…,,,… • Increasing returns to scale: doubling the inputs more than doubles the output ,,,…,,,… 5 1 3/31/2016 7 8 Returns-to-Scale Returns-to-Scale One input, one output One input, one output Output Level Output Level 2f(x’) y = f(x) y = f(x) 2y’ f(2x’) Decreasing Constant returns-to-scale returns-to-scale f(x’) y’ x’ 2x’ x x’ 2x’ x Input Level Input Level 9 10 Returns-to-Scale Returns to Scale and Cost Functions One input, one output Output Level • We showed that, a Cobb Douglas production function ,,,… … Increasing returns-to-scale y = f(x) Will exhibit • Decreasing returns to scale if …1 f(2x’) • Constant returns to scale if …1 • Increasing returns to scale if …1 2f(x’) f(x’) x’ 2x’ x Input Level 11 12 Returns to Scale and Cost Functions Returns to Scale and Cost Functions • Ultimately, what we are interested in is the firm’s costs • What are the marginal costs for a firm with Cobb Douglas production function? • In the worked example, we showed that for technology • Specifically, their marginal costs, which will determine optimal output , • We showed that, in the case of one input, that there was • Costs were given by a relationship between returns to scale and marginal costs , , • Because of the inverse function theorem It turns out (and you should check) that for technology , 1 Costs are given by ,, • E.g., decreasing returns to scale means increasing marginal costs Where A is a constant which depends on and 2 3/31/2016 13 14 Returns to Scale and Cost Functions Returns to Scale and Cost Functions ,, = 1 ,, What does this mean for marginal costs? Is this positive? Take the first derivative with respect to y Only if is greater than 1 ,, i.e. only if <1 = i.e. Only if the production function exhibits decreasing returns to Now take the second derivative scale ,, = 1 Is this positive or negative? i.e. are marginal costs increasing or decreasing? 15 16 Returns to Scale and Cost Functions Returns-to-Scale and Marginal Cost Marginal Cost • So, if there is only one input, or technology is Cobb Douglas decreasing returns to scale • Decreasing returns to scale if and only if marginal costs increase as increases • Constant returns to scale if and only if marginal cost unchanged constant returns to scale as increases • Increasing returns to scale: marginal cost fall as increases increasing returns to scale. y 17 18 Returns to Scale and Cost Functions Returns-to-Scale and Total Costs • What about Average Cost? What does this imply for the shapes of total cost functions? • Say marginal cost is always increasing Lets start by thinking about decreasing returns to scale • The cost of the making the second car is higher than the cost of making the first car And therefore increasing average cost • The average cost of producing two cars is higher than that of producing one car • Following the same logic • Decreasing returns to scale → increasing marginal cost → increasing average cost • Constant returns to scale → constant marginal cost → constant average cost • Increasing returns to scale → decreasing marginal cost → decreasing average cost 3 3/31/2016 19 20 Returns-to-Scale and Total Costs Returns-to-Scale and Total Costs $ $ c(2y’) Slope = c(2y’)/2y’ = AC(2y’). Slope = c(y’)/y’ Slope = c(y’)/y’ = AC(y’). = AC(y’). c(y’) c(y’) y’ y y’ 2y’ y 21 + 22 Returns-to-Scale and Total Costs Returns-to-Scale and Total Costs $ What does this imply for the shapes of total cost functions? c(y) Now increasing returns to scale c(2y’) Slope = c(2y’)/2y’ And therefore decreasing average cost = AC(2y’). Slope = c(y’)/y’ = AC(y’). c(y’) y’ 2y’ y 23 24 Returns-to-Scale and Total Costs Returns-to-Scale and Total Costs Av. cost decreases with y if the firm’s Av. cost decreases with y if the firm’s technology exhibits increasing r.t.s. technology exhibits increasing r.t.s. $ $ c(y) c(2y’) c(2y’) Slope = c(2y’)/2y’ Slope = c(2y’)/2y’ c(y’) = AC(2y’). c(y’) = AC(2y’). Slope = c(y’)/y’ Slope = c(y’)/y’ = AC(y’). = AC(y’). y’ 2y’ y y’ 2y’ y 4 3/31/2016 + 25 26 Returns-to-Scale and Total Costs Returns-to-Scale and Total Costs Av. cost is constant when the firm’s technology exhibits constant r.t.s. What does this imply for the shapes of total cost functions? $ c(2y’) c(y) Finally constant returns to scale =2c(y’) Slope = c(2y’)/2y’ And therefore constant average cost = 2c(y’)/2y’ = c(y’)/y’ c(y’) so AC(y’) = AC(2y’). y’ 2y’ y 28 Profit Maximization Remember that the firm’s original problem was 1. CHOOSE inputs and output - , ,,… 2. IN ORDER TO MAXIMIZE profit - ⋯ Solving The Firm’s Profit 3. SUBJECT TO technological constraints - y ,,,….) Maximization Problem 27 29 30 Profit Maximization Profit Maximization Which we split into two: First the cost minimization problem Let’s think a bit more about the profit maximization problem 1. CHOOSE inputs ,,… Using the Cobb Douglas case as an example. 2. IN ORDER TO MINIMIZE costs ⋯ Remember I claimed that for Cobb Douglas technology , 3. SUBJECT TO achieving output y ,,,….) This allowed us to identify the cost function ,,… The cost function is given by Which we can then use to solve the profit maximization , , problem 1. CHOOSE output And so profits by 2. IN ORDER TO MAXIMIZE profits ,,… 5 3/31/2016 31 32 Profit Maximization Profit Maximization Is this going to work? Depends on whether we have increasing, decreasing or How can we find the profit maximizing output? constant returns to scale Well, we could take derivatives with respect to y If we have decreasing returns to scale (i.e. <1) then marginal And use the first order conditions costs are increasing , 1 Which implies 33 34 Marginal Revenue and Marginal Cost Profit Maximization $ Marginal Cost In this case, setting marginal cost equal to price is optimal Marginal The cost of producing one more unit of output would be higher Revenue than the revenue of doing so This would lower profits We can also see this from the second order conditions y* y 35 36 Profit Maximization Profit Maximization Profits are given by 1 1 , ,… 1 Remember, from calculus, for us to have found a maximum, we need this to be negative First derivative is Which it will be if 1 is positive 1 i.e. <1 Second derivative is i.e. decreasing returns to scale 1 1 1 6 3/31/2016 37 38 Profit Maximization Marginal Revenue and Marginal Cost $ Marginal What about if we have increasing returns to scale? Cost Then marginal costs are decreasing Marginal Revenue y* y 39 40 Profit Maximization Profit Maximization ∗ Imagine we are producing at 1 1 1 What would happen if we produced one more unit of output? If 1 (i.e. increasing returns to scale) then this expression is Now the costs of additional output are below revenue positive ∗ If we wanted to produce at then we would certainly want to Means we have found a profit minimizing level of output produce more So, if the ‘tangency point’ is not the solution, what is? The more we produce, the lower the costs and the higher the profits A corner solution! ∗ is the profit minimizing output Produce infinite output (assuming marginal costs at some point get below price) You can see this from the second order conditions 41 42 Profit Maximization Marginal Revenue and Marginal Cost $ Marginal What about constant returns to scale? Cost 1 Marginal 1 Revenue = So in the constant returns to scale case marginal cost doesn’t depend on output y This leaves us with three possibilities 7 3/31/2016 43 44 Marginal Revenue and Marginal Cost Marginal Revenue and Marginal Cost $ $ Marginal Marginal Cost Cost Marginal Marginal Revenue Revenue y y 45 46 Profit Maximization Profit Maximization Putting this all together 1. Marginal costs above price Lose money on each item produced Diminishing returns to scale: MC increasing Optimal to produce zero Optimal output is an interior solution as long as there is a y such that price equals marginal cost What happens otherwise? 2.
Recommended publications
  • Perfect Competition--A Model of Markets
    Econ Dept, UMR Presents PerfectPerfect CompetitionCompetition----AA ModelModel ofof MarketsMarkets StarringStarring uTheThe PerfectlyPerfectly CompetitiveCompetitive FirmFirm uProfitProfit MaximizingMaximizing DecisionsDecisions \InIn thethe ShortShort RunRun \InIn thethe LongLong RunRun FeaturingFeaturing uAn Overview of Market Structures uThe Assumptions of the Perfectly Competitive Model uThe Marginal Cost = Marginal Revenue Rule uMarginal Cost and Short Run Supply uSocial Surplus PartPart III:III: ProfitProfit MaximizationMaximization inin thethe LongLong RunRun u First, we review profits and losses in the short run u Second, we look at the implications of the freedom of entry and exit assumption u Third, we look at the long run supply curve OutputOutput DecisionsDecisions Question:Question: HowHow cancan wewe useuse whatwhat wewe knowknow aboutabout productionproduction technology,technology, costs,costs, andand competitivecompetitive marketsmarkets toto makemake outputoutput decisionsdecisions inin thethe longlong run?run? Reminders...Reminders... u Firms operate in perfectly competitive output and input markets u In perfectly competitive industries, prices are determined in the market and firms are price takers u The demand curve for the firm’s product is perceived to be perfectly elastic u And, critical for the long run, there is freedom of entry and exit u However, technology is assumed to be fixed The firm maximizes profits, or minimizes losses by producing where MR = MC, or by shutting down Market Firm P P MC S $5 $5 P=MR D
    [Show full text]
  • Perfect Competition
    Perfect Competition 1 Outline • Competition – Short run – Implications for firms – Implication for supply curves • Perfect competition – Long run – Implications for firms – Implication for supply curves • Broader implications – Implications for tax policy. – Implication for R&D 2 Competition vs Perfect Competition • Competition – Each firm takes price as given. • As we saw => Price equals marginal cost • PftPerfect competition – Each firm takes price as given. – PfitProfits are zero – As we will see • P=MC=Min(Average Cost) • Production efficiency is maximized • Supply is flat 3 Competitive industries • One way to think about this is market share • Any industry where the largest firm produces less than 1% of output is going to be competitive • Agriculture? – For sure • Services? – Restaurants? • What about local consumers and local suppliers • manufacturing – Most often not so. 4 Competition • Here only assume that each firm takes price as given. – It want to maximize profits • Two decisions. • ()(1) if it produces how much • П(q) =pq‐C(q) => p‐C’(q)=0 • (2) should it produce at all • П(q*)>0 produce, if П(q*)<0 shut down 5 Competitive equilibrium • Given n, firms each with cost C(q) and D(p) it is a pair (p*,q*) such that • 1. D(p *) =n q* • 2. MC(q*) =p * • 3. П(p *,q*)>0 1. Says demand equals suppl y, 2. firm maximize profits, 3. profits are non negative. If we fix the number of firms. This may not exist. 6 Step 1 Max П p Marginal Cost Average Costs Profits Short Run Average Cost Or Average Variable Cost Costs q 7 Step 1 Max П, p Marginal
    [Show full text]
  • Quantifying the External Costs of Vehicle Use: Evidence from America’S Top Selling Light-Duty Models
    QUANTIFYING THE EXTERNAL COSTS OF VEHICLE USE: EVIDENCE FROM AMERICA’S TOP SELLING LIGHT-DUTY MODELS Jason D. Lemp Graduate Student Researcher The University of Texas at Austin 6.9 E. Cockrell Jr. Hall, Austin, TX 78712-1076 [email protected] Kara M. Kockelman Associate Professor and William J. Murray Jr. Fellow Department of Civil, Architectural and Environmental Engineering The University of Texas at Austin 6.9 E. Cockrell Jr. Hall, Austin, TX 78712-1076 [email protected] The following paper is a pre-print and the final publication can be found in Transportation Research 13D (8):491-504, 2008. Presented at the 87th Annual Meeting of the Transportation Research Board, January 2008 ABSTRACT Vehicle externality costs include emissions of greenhouse and other gases (affecting global warming and human health), crash costs (imposed on crash partners), roadway congestion, and space consumption, among others. These five sources of external costs by vehicle make and model were estimated for the top-selling passenger cars and light-duty trucks in the U.S. Among these external costs, those associated with crashes and congestion are estimated to be the most practically significant. When crash costs are included, the worst offenders (in terms of highest external costs) were found to be pickups. If crash costs are removed from the comparisons, the worst offenders tend to be four pickups and a very large SUV: the Ford F-350 and F-250, Chevrolet Silverado 3500, Dodge Ram 3500, and Hummer H2, respectively. Regardless of how the costs are estimated, they are considerable in magnitude, and nearly on par with vehicle purchase prices.
    [Show full text]
  • Profit Maximization and Cost Minimization ● Average and Marginal Costs
    Theory of the Firm Moshe Ben-Akiva 1.201 / 11.545 / ESD.210 Transportation Systems Analysis: Demand & Economics Fall 2008 Outline ● Basic Concepts ● Production functions ● Profit maximization and cost minimization ● Average and marginal costs 2 Basic Concepts ● Describe behavior of a firm ● Objective: maximize profit max π = R(a ) − C(a ) s.t . a ≥ 0 – R, C, a – revenue, cost, and activities, respectively ● Decisions: amount & price of inputs to buy amount & price of outputs to produce ● Constraints: technology constraints market constraints 3 Production Function ● Technology: method for turning inputs (including raw materials, labor, capital, such as vehicles, drivers, terminals) into outputs (such as trips) ● Production function: description of the technology of the firm. Maximum output produced from given inputs. q = q(X ) – q – vector of outputs – X – vector of inputs (capital, labor, raw material) 4 Using a Production Function ● The production function predicts what resources are needed to provide different levels of output ● Given prices of the inputs, we can find the most efficient (i.e. minimum cost) way to produce a given level of output 5 Isoquant ● For two-input production: Capital (K) q=q(K,L) K’ q3 q2 q1 Labor (L) L’ 6 Production Function: Examples ● Cobb-Douglas : ● Input-Output: = α a b = q x1 x2 q min( ax1 ,bx2 ) x2 x2 Isoquants q2 q2 q1 q1 x1 x1 7 Rate of Technical Substitution (RTS) ● Substitution rates for inputs – Replace a unit of input 1 with RTS units of input 2 keeping the same level of production x2 ∂x ∂q ∂x RTS
    [Show full text]
  • Marginal Social Cost Pricing on a Transportation Network
    December 2007 RFF DP 07-52 Marginal Social Cost Pricing on a Transportation Network A Comparison of Second-Best Policies Elena Safirova, Sébastien Houde, and Winston Harrington 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036 202-328-5000 www.rff.org DISCUSSION PAPER Marginal Social Cost Pricing on a Transportation Network: A Comparison of Second-Best Policies Elena Safirova, Sébastien Houde, and Winston Harrington Abstract In this paper we evaluate and compare long-run economic effects of six road-pricing schemes aimed at internalizing social costs of transportation. In order to conduct this analysis, we employ a spatially disaggregated general equilibrium model of a regional economy that incorporates decisions of residents, firms, and developers, integrated with a spatially-disaggregated strategic transportation planning model that features mode, time period, and route choice. The model is calibrated to the greater Washington, DC metropolitan area. We compare two social cost functions: one restricted to congestion alone and another that accounts for other external effects of transportation. We find that when the ultimate policy goal is a reduction in the complete set of motor vehicle externalities, cordon-like policies and variable-toll policies lose some attractiveness compared to policies based primarily on mileage. We also find that full social cost pricing requires very high toll levels and therefore is bound to be controversial. Key Words: traffic congestion, social cost pricing, land use, welfare analysis, road pricing, general equilibrium, simulation, Washington DC JEL Classification Numbers: Q53, Q54, R13, R41, R48 © 2007 Resources for the Future. All rights reserved. No portion of this paper may be reproduced without permission of the authors.
    [Show full text]
  • Health Economic Evaluation a Shiell, C Donaldson, C Mitton, G Currie
    85 GLOSSARY Health economic evaluation A Shiell, C Donaldson, C Mitton, G Currie ............................................................................................................................. J Epidemiol Community Health 2002;56:85–88 A glossary is presented on terms of health economic analyses the costs and benefits of evaluation. Definitions are suggested for the more improving patterns of resource allocation.”7 common concepts and terms. Health economics: one role of health economics is to .......................................................................... provide a set of analytical techniques to assist decision making, usually in the health care sector, t is well established that economics has an to promote efficiency and equity. Another role, how- important part to play in the evaluation of ever, is simply to provide a way of thinking about Ihealth and health care interventions. Many health and health care resource use; introducing a books and papers have been written describing thought process that recognises scarcity, the need the methods of health economic evaluation.12 to make choices and, thus, that more is not always Despite this, controversies remain about issues better if other things can be done with the same such as the definition, purposes and limitations of resources. Ultimately, health economics is about the different evaluative techniques, whether or maximising social benefits obtained from con- not to discount future health benefits, and the strained health producing resources. usefulness of “league tables” that rank health interventions according to their cost per unit of effectiveness.3–5 ECONOMIC EVALUATION CRITERIA To help steer potential users of economic Technical efficiency: with technical efficiency, an evidence through some of these issues, we seek objective such as the provision of tonsillectomy here to define the more common economic for children in need of this procedure is taken as concepts and terms.
    [Show full text]
  • Internal Increasing Returns to Scale and Economic Growth
    NBER TECHNICAL WORKING PAPER SERIES INTERNAL INCREASING RETURNS TO SCALE AND ECONOMIC GROWTH John A. List Haiwen Zhou Technical Working Paper 336 http://www.nber.org/papers/t0336 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 March 2007 The views expressed herein are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. © 2007 by John A. List and Haiwen Zhou. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Internal Increasing Returns to Scale and Economic Growth John A. List and Haiwen Zhou NBER Technical Working Paper No. 336 March 2007 JEL No. E10,E22,O41 ABSTRACT This study develops a model of endogenous growth based on increasing returns due to firms? technology choices. Particular attention is paid to the implications of these choices, combined with the substitution of capital for labor, on economic growth in a general equilibrium model in which the R&D sector produces machines to be used for the sector producing final goods. We show that incorporating oligopolistic competition in the sector producing finals goods into a general equilibrium model with endogenous technology choice is tractable, and we explore the equilibrium path analytically. The model illustrates a novel manner in which sustained per capita growth of consumption can be achieved?through continuous adoption of new technologies featuring the substitution between capital and labor. Further insights of the model are that during the growth process, the size of firms producing final goods increases over time, the real interest rate is constant, and the real wage rate increases over time.
    [Show full text]
  • The Historical Role of the Production Function in Economics and Business
    American Journal of Business Education – April 2011 Volume 4, Number 4 The Historical Role Of The Production Function In Economics And Business David Gordon, University of Saint Francis, USA Richard Vaughan. University of Saint Francis, USA ABSTRACT The production function explains a basic technological relationship between scarce resources, or inputs, and output. This paper offers a brief overview of the historical significance and operational role of the production function in business and economics. The origin and development of this function over time is initially explored. Several various production functions that have played an important historical role in economics are explained. These consist of some well known functions, such as the Cobb-Douglas, Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES), and Generalized and Leontief production functions. This paper also covers some relatively newer production functions, such as the Arrow, Chenery, Minhas, and Solow (ACMS) functions, the transcendental logarithmic (translog), and other flexible forms of the production function. Several important characteristics of the production function are also explained in this paper. These would include, but are not limited to, items such as the returns to scale of the function, the separability of the function, the homogeneity of the function, the homotheticity of the function, the output elasticity of factors (inputs), and the degree of input substitutability that each function exhibits. Also explored are some of the duality issues that potentially exist between certain production and cost functions. The information contained in this paper could act as a pedagogical aide in any microeconomics-based course or in a production management class. It could also play a role in certain marketing courses, especially at the graduate level.
    [Show full text]
  • Report No. 2020-06 Economies of Scale in Community Banks
    Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Staff Studies Report No. 2020-06 Economies of Scale in Community Banks December 2020 Staff Studies Staff www.fdic.gov/cfr • @FDICgov • #FDICCFR • #FDICResearch Economies of Scale in Community Banks Stefan Jacewitz, Troy Kravitz, and George Shoukry December 2020 Abstract: Using financial and supervisory data from the past 20 years, we show that scale economies in community banks with less than $10 billion in assets emerged during the run-up to the 2008 financial crisis due to declines in interest expenses and provisions for losses on loans and leases at larger banks. The financial crisis temporarily interrupted this trend and costs increased industry-wide, but a generally more cost-efficient industry re-emerged, returning in recent years to pre-crisis trends. We estimate that from 2000 to 2019, the cost-minimizing size of a bank’s loan portfolio rose from approximately $350 million to $3.3 billion. Though descriptive, our results suggest efficiency gains accrue early as a bank grows from $10 million in loans to $3.3 billion, with 90 percent of the potential efficiency gains occurring by $300 million. JEL classification: G21, G28, L00. The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the official positions of the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation or the United States. FDIC Staff Studies can be cited without additional permission. The authors wish to thank Noam Weintraub for research assistance and seminar participants for helpful comments. Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, [email protected], 550 17th St. NW, Washington, DC 20429 Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, [email protected], 550 17th St.
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Evaluation Glossary of Terms
    Economic Evaluation Glossary of Terms A Attributable fraction: indirect health expenditures associated with a given diagnosis through other diseases or conditions (Prevented fraction: indicates the proportion of an outcome averted by the presence of an exposure that decreases the likelihood of the outcome; indicates the number or proportion of an outcome prevented by the “exposure”) Average cost: total resource cost, including all support and overhead costs, divided by the total units of output B Benefit-cost analysis (BCA): (or cost-benefit analysis) a type of economic analysis in which all costs and benefits are converted into monetary (dollar) values and results are expressed as either the net present value or the dollars of benefits per dollars expended Benefit-cost ratio: a mathematical comparison of the benefits divided by the costs of a project or intervention. When the benefit-cost ratio is greater than 1, benefits exceed costs C Comorbidity: presence of one or more serious conditions in addition to the primary disease or disorder Cost analysis: the process of estimating the cost of prevention activities; also called cost identification, programmatic cost analysis, cost outcome analysis, cost minimization analysis, or cost consequence analysis Cost effectiveness analysis (CEA): an economic analysis in which all costs are related to a single, common effect. Results are usually stated as additional cost expended per additional health outcome achieved. Results can be categorized as average cost-effectiveness, marginal cost-effectiveness,
    [Show full text]
  • Increasing Returns to Scale, Dynamics of Industrial Structure and Size Distribution of Firms†
    Increasing Returns to Scale, Dynamics of Industrial Structure and Size Distribution of Firms† Ying Fan, Menghui Li, Zengru Di∗ Department of Systems Science, School of Management, Beijing Normal University, Beijing 100875, China _______________________________________________________________________ Abstract A model is presented of the market dynamics to emphasis the effects of increasing returns to scale, including the description of the born and death of the adaptive producers. The evolution of market structure and its behavior with the technological shocks are discussed. Its dynamics is in good agreement with some empirical “stylized facts” of industrial evolution. Together with the diversities of demand and adaptive growth strategies of firms, the generalized model has reproduced the power-law distribution of firm size. Three factors mainly determine the competitive dynamics and the skewed size distributions of firms: 1. Self-reinforcing mechanism; 2. Adaptive firm grows strategies; 3. Demand diversities or widespread heterogeneity in the technological capabilities of different firms. JEL classification: L11, C61 Key words: Increasing returns, Industry dynamics, Size distribution of firms _______________________________________________________________________ Ⅰ. INTRODUCTION In the past decades, the evolutionary perspective has contributed lot to the economics (Arthur, Durlauf, and Lane, 1997; Dosi, Nelson, 1994; Aruka, 2001). The economy is studied as an evolving complex system with many features in complexity such as nonlinear interactions and emergent properties. In reality, the economic system consists † The paper has been presented in the 1st Sino-German workshop on the evolutionary economics, March, 2004, Beijing, China. The authors thank all the participants for their helpful comments and suggestions. The work is supported by the NSFC under the grant No. 70371072 and grant No.
    [Show full text]
  • Principles of Microeconomics
    PRINCIPLES OF MICROECONOMICS A. Competition The basic motivation to produce in a market economy is the expectation of income, which will generate profits. • The returns to the efforts of a business - the difference between its total revenues and its total costs - are profits. Thus, questions of revenues and costs are key in an analysis of the profit motive. • Other motivations include nonprofit incentives such as social status, the need to feel important, the desire for recognition, and the retaining of one's job. Economists' calculations of profits are different from those used by businesses in their accounting systems. Economic profit = total revenue - total economic cost • Total economic cost includes the value of all inputs used in production. • Normal profit is an economic cost since it occurs when economic profit is zero. It represents the opportunity cost of labor and capital contributed to the production process by the producer. • Accounting profits are computed only on the basis of explicit costs, including labor and capital. Since they do not take "normal profits" into consideration, they overstate true profits. Economic profits reward entrepreneurship. They are a payment to discovering new and better methods of production, taking above-average risks, and producing something that society desires. The ability of each firm to generate profits is limited by the structure of the industry in which the firm is engaged. The firms in a competitive market are price takers. • None has any market power - the ability to control the market price of the product it sells. • A firm's individual supply curve is a very small - and inconsequential - part of market supply.
    [Show full text]