Quantifying Worldwide Demand Elasticities As a Policy Tool

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Quantifying Worldwide Demand Elasticities As a Policy Tool Quantifying Worldwide Demand Elasticities as a Policy Tool Tarek Atalla, Simona Bigerna and Carlo Andrea Bollino August 2016 KS-1644-DP038A Quantifying Worldwide Demand Elasticities as a Policy Tool 1 About KAPSARC The King Abdullah Petroleum Studies and Research Center (KAPSARC) is a non-profit global institution dedicated to independent research into energy economics, policy, technology, and the environment across all types of energy. KAPSARC’s mandate is to advance the understanding of energy challenges and opportunities facing the world today and tomorrow, through unbiased, independent, and high-caliber research for the benefit of society. KAPSARC is located in Riyadh, Saudi Arabia. Legal Notice © Copyright 2016 King Abdullah Petroleum Studies and Research Center (KAPSARC). No portion of this document may be reproduced or utilized without the proper attribution to KAPSARC. Quantifying Worldwide Demand Elasticities as a Policy Tool 2 Key Points his paper provides a comprehensive worldwide database of estimated elasticities for electricity and natural gas for households as a function of income, price, capital stocks and weather conditions. TEmerging economies show lower price elasticities than advanced economies as a result of limited physical capital availability and lock in effect pertaining to energy consumption. Hot weather has a higher impact on energy demand in emerging economies than in advanced ones, as a result of higher efficiency and diversified technologically-advanced equipment. We find that the energy demand elasticity to capital stock is positive implying that the rebound effect prevails over the substitution effect when it comes to the deployment of capital stock technologies. For most countries, including former Soviet Union economies, natural gas is considered as an essential good while electricity is perceived, economically, as a luxury where its income elasticity is above unity. Quantifying Worldwide Demand Elasticities as a Policy Tool 3 Summary nderstanding how energy demand responds Our econometric estimation provides new refined to prices changes is crucial for policymakers quantitative evidence on the impact of changes in around the world. Elasticity is a quantitative prices and income on energy demand. Specifically, Umeasure of this response. This subject has been we found that the aggregate energy elasticity to widely analyzed in empirical studies, but the quality price has a world average of 0.19 and the electricity of the results varies, leading to limited comparability elasticity to price is between -0.10 and -0.20 for most across countries. countries, meaning that both energy and electricity have limited price elasticity. The study found that In this paper, we provide a new and more accurate emerging economies have a lower energy demand approach to estimate aggregate energy demand price elasticities than advanced ones. In addition, the elasticity for 117 countries. The model that we have intra-fuel analysis shows that natural gas is generally developed provides a coherent and integrated perceived as more of an essential good than empirical tool for policymakers to quantify how electricity, especially in less developed economies. energy demand responds to policies. The model This is partly due to the fact that natural gas is mostly allows simultaneous variations of prices, income and used for essential needs such as heating and cooking. capital stock or productive capacity, while including We found that the demand elasticity for cooling climate conditions as an uncontrollable factor. needs is triple that of heating, which means more final energy is used for cooling than heating on a per Our approach is unique in accurately estimating capita level. Yet people in richer countries are rooted demand response to prices by explicitly modeling a in their comfortable lifestyle when it comes to their utility-maximizing rational behavior for consumers heating needs, resulting in positive gas elasticity in each of the countries studied. This implies a to heating degree days. This is aligned with the better estimation of the energy demand function general observation that countries with natural gas as it is computed using a structural model based endowments prefer to maximize its usage. These on a simultaneous system of equations, thus findings have welfare-improving policy implications, avoiding potential econometric bias in the resulting because appropriate policy strategies can help parameters. decision-makers to promote production efficiency and consumer welfare. Quantifying Worldwide Demand Elasticities as a Policy Tool 4 Policy Insight ur work quantifies how consumer energy to the demand elasticity, meaning that an increase demand responds to changes in key in tax may result in lower consumption and hence variables, such as income, prices, lower-than-expected revenue. Very elastic behavior Ocapital stock availability and climate conditions. could have the contrarian effect of reducing The calculated response factors are known as government income. Quantifying distortions due to demand elasticities. Policymakers can use demand taxation can be a difficult task, hence the application elasticities in many ways, including in designing of our elasticities can help in the development of efficient price policies and in setting fuel subsidy better calibrated policies. and taxation levels. Another sensitive issue for policymakers is funding Public authorities alter the prices of goods in a limitations and the associated efficiency-equity number of ways. In some cases, they administer trade-off. Many pricing policies have a role in prices for an entire class of products or subject them improving the living conditions of poor households, to uniform taxes or subsidies. Tobacco and energy but usually impose a societal cost in terms of are typical of this first type of price control. In such market inefficiency. The reverse is also true; cases, the demand elasticity is useful for assessing when implementing policies to promote economic how consumption might change with prices: for efficiency, the poorest in the society often get hurt. example, increasing tobacco excise duties or raising gasoline prices. At one level, the policy maker needs instruments to measure inefficiencies in the market caused by tax In other instances, they focus on the price of only distortions or imperfections, such as externalities one particular good and leave the prices of others and non-competitive market behaviors. In this within that class to market forces. Bread and respect, demand elasticities are useful to construct pharmaceuticals may provide examples of this the minimum distortion pricing policy (the so-called second type of price control. Here, only the basic Ramsey pricing), a cornerstone of the efficiency- type of bread would be subject to a price cap to ensure that poor households could afford a basic equity trade-off. On another level, the same policy need. In the case of pharmaceuticals, a basic class maker needs to assess the economic impact of of active ingredient might be the target for policy equitable intervention, like price subsidy to the poor action. All other types of bread and pharmaceuticals and elderly. The maximum equitable solution is the would have free prices, so overall demand would other cornerstone of the efficiency-equity trade-off. be the sum of the quantity consumed under the administered price plus the quantity consumed Our model of estimated demand elasticities under the free market pricing regime. can provide a quantitative assessment of policy interventions on energy prices, income and capital Policy goals can also revolve around raising formation in the household sector. In addition, revenues through price taxation. In this case, the our model can quantify the effect on energy policy maker must know the associated demand consumption of specific climate conditions across elasticity to make accurate budget forecasts. The the world, allowing cross-country comparison net of quantity consumed changes with price according the differences in natural climate conditions. Quantifying Worldwide Demand Elasticities as a Policy Tool 5 Background Review ost previous studies are based on the are modelled as the sum of residential electricity single demand estimation, assuming a and gas consumption. The model assumes that all partial equilibrium viewpoint and neglecting consumers in the market are cost minimizers, but Mthe simultaneity of consumer decision processes still demand a diverse basket of goods. We further (Hodge and Dahl, 2012; Labandeira, 2012). This implement a multistage optimization process, approach is at variance with observed behavior, which uses the minimum number of parameter especially considering the complex relationships requirements while remaining flexible in modeling among consumer goods and services, as complex demand behavior and acknowledging that households optimize their consumption under a both capital and climate conditions affect demand constrained budget. choices. Previously published works used weather conditions This research improves on existing literature in three or capital stock as a regressor, or explanatory ways. First, we improve upon the single equation variable, in the estimation of a single energy approach in the energy and electricity market (e.g. demand function, typically as a production input Bernstein and Griffin, 2006 among others), taking at all aggregation levels. Their primary interest into account work on consumers’ energy demand, was usually the causal
Recommended publications
  • ECON501- Short Questions
    Graduate Microeconomics Short Study Questions Areas: 1. Consumer Demand Theory 2. Theory of the firm and Production 3. Competitive Markets Lecturer: Glenn P. Jenkins Indicate whether the following statements are true, false or uncertain and briefly explain why. Your grade will depend on your explanation. 1. If two goods are gross substitutes then the absolute value of the uncompensated cross price elasticity of demand must always be less than the absolute value of compensated cross price elasticity between these two goods. 2. The shares of income that individuals spend on every good will always be changing as the person’s income grows, unless the person’s income elasticity of demand for each goods is equal to one. 3. A fall in the price of automobiles will decrease the consumer surplus of the workers in the factory that produces the automobiles. 4. The cross-price elasticity of demand for automobiles with respect to the price of gasoline is equal to the cross- price elasticity of demand for gasoline with respect to the price of automobiles. 5. The sum of the uncompensated own and cross price elasticities of demand for any one good must be equal to the negative of the income elasticity of demand for the good. 6. An inferior good will always be inferior throughout the full range of incomes experienced by consumers. 7. If the MRSxy < Px/Py then the consumer would maximize utility if she would consume less of good X. 8. A consumer’s utility function containing two goods X and Y yields a set of indifference curves that are straight lines.
    [Show full text]
  • Giffen Behaviour and Asymmetric Substitutability*
    Tjalling C. Koopmans Research Institute Tjalling C. Koopmans Research Institute Utrecht School of Economics Utrecht University Janskerkhof 12 3512 BL Utrecht The Netherlands telephone +31 30 253 9800 fax +31 30 253 7373 website www.koopmansinstitute.uu.nl The Tjalling C. Koopmans Institute is the research institute and research school of Utrecht School of Economics. It was founded in 2003, and named after Professor Tjalling C. Koopmans, Dutch-born Nobel Prize laureate in economics of 1975. In the discussion papers series the Koopmans Institute publishes results of ongoing research for early dissemination of research results, and to enhance discussion with colleagues. Please send any comments and suggestions on the Koopmans institute, or this series to [email protected] ontwerp voorblad: WRIK Utrecht How to reach the authors Please direct all correspondence to the first author. Kris De Jaegher Utrecht University Utrecht School of Economics Janskerkhof 12 3512 BL Utrecht The Netherlands. E-mail: [email protected] This paper can be downloaded at: http:// www.uu.nl/rebo/economie/discussionpapers Utrecht School of Economics Tjalling C. Koopmans Research Institute Discussion Paper Series 10-16 Giffen Behaviour and Asymmetric * Substitutability Kris De Jaeghera aUtrecht School of Economics Utrecht University September 2010 Abstract Let a consumer consume two goods, and let good 1 be a Giffen good. Then a well- known necessary condition for such behaviour is that good 1 is an inferior good. This paper shows that an additional necessary for such behaviour is that good 1 is a gross substitute for good 2, and that good 2 is a gross complement to good 1 (strong asymmetric gross substitutability).
    [Show full text]
  • By Marcus Berliant, Shin-Kun Peng, and Ping Wang
    WELFARE ANALYSIS OF THE NUMBER AND LOCATIONS OF LOCAL PUBLIC FACILITIES by Marcus Berliant, Shin-kun Peng, and Ping Wang Working Paper No. 00-W35 August 2000 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS VANDERBILT UNIVERSITY NASHVILLE, TN 37235 www.vanderbilt.edu/econ Welfare Analysis of the Number and Locations of Local Public Facilities Marcus Berliant Washington University, St. Louis, MO, USA Shin-kun Peng Academia Sinica, Taipei, Taiwan, ROC Ping Wang Vanderbilt University, Nashville, TN, USA This Version: August 2000 Abstract We develop a discrete or finite household model with congestable local public goods where the level of provision, the number of facilities and their locations are all endogenously determined in a purely normative context. We prove the existence of an equal-treatment identical-provision second best optimum, where all households are required to reach the same utility level, the provision of local public good is required to be the same at all facilities, and all facilities must serve the same number of consumers. Such an optimal public facility configuration need not be geographically centralized even if there is only a single public facility site. Moreover, the optimal public facility configuration could be either concentrated (single site) or dispersed (multiple sites), depending crucially on the degree of congestability and the household valuation of local public goods as well as the unit transportation cost. JEL Classification Numbers: D61, H41, R13 Keywords: Congestable Local Public Goods, Optimal Public Facility Configurations Acknowledgments: We are grateful for valuable comments and suggestions from Hideo Konishi, Tomoya Mori, David Wildasin, and participants at the North American Meetings of the Regional Science Association International in Montreal.
    [Show full text]
  • Network Externalities and Public Goods in Payment Systems
    NETWORK EXTERNALITIES AND PUBLIC GOODS IN PAYMENT SYSTEMS John A, Weinberg Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond P.O. Box 27622, Richmond VA 23261, 804-697-8205 November 1996 ABSTRACT: As a network, a payment system is likely to exhibit network externalities and perhaps some public good characteristics. Such properties may be more pronounced in an electronic payment system, because of its greater reliance on communication infrastructures with high fixed and low variable costs, for instance. This paper presents the basic economics of network externalities and reviews some basic principles regarding public goods. It then asks what these phenomena imply about the role of the Federal Reserve in emerging payment systems. The general conclusion is that there is reason to be skeptical that network externalities and public goods will be significant sources of market failure in electronic payment systems. These phenomena, by themselves, give rise to no particular, essential central bank role in these markets. The views expressed herein are the authors and do not represent the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System. In a large modern economy, there is a vast and constant movement of funds in the conduct of commerce and finance. In dollar value, the bulk of this movement is not in cash but in the form of instructions for the crediting and debiting of accounts held with public or private financial institutions. In using a non-cash payment instrument, a business or consumer relies on the process through which the payment is ultimately made final. That is, parties to a transaction rely on the network that connects the point of the transaction (in space and time) to the parties' accounts with financial institutions.
    [Show full text]
  • Consumer Theory
    Consumer Theory The study about scarcity o Microeconomics is the study of choices & behaviour of individual decision- making units o How we can allocate the world limited resources o How can we allocate the world’s limited resources most efficiently? o How do we allocate our limited resources?.. Our limited time (hours in the week); . Our limited budgets; . Our limited supply of oil, gas, iron, etc. Consumer choice: budget constraint: o Budget constraint identifies what he can afford to buy . There are two goods X฀ and Y฀; . Good X฀ can be purchased at price PX and Y at price PY; . The consumer has an income of M. A consumption bundle (x,y) ฀ tells us that the consumer gets฀x units of good X฀ and y฀ units of good Y ฀. Bundle (x,y) is feasible if, and only if Px+Py≤M . ฀M or m฀ stands for income; . x฀ stands for the amount of good X฀; . y stands for the amount of good Y (and similarly for other goods); . PX or px stands for the price of good X฀and PY or py stands for the price of good Y (and similarly for other goods and prices). o We will call budget line or budget constraint the set of consumption bundles that cost exactly available income. o If we assume that the consumer will spend all of his income, and rearrange, we get the budget constraint: . y=(M/Py)-(Px/Py)x o “Relative” prices are illustrated by the slope of the budget line. Factors that affect the budget constraint position: The slope and position of the budget constraint are a function of two factors: income and relative prices: o Changes in income shift the budget constraint by changing the intercept; o Changes in the price of one good pivots the budget line by changing the slope.
    [Show full text]
  • Economics 352: Intermediate Microeconomics
    EC 352: Intermediate Microeconomics, Lecture 6 Economics 352: Intermediate Microeconomics Notes and Sample Questions Chapter 6: Demand Relationships Among Goods This chapter will use the consumer theory we have established to study demand relationships across goods. Substitutes and Complements We will start with the concepts of pairs of goods being substitutes or complements. To review, substitutes are two goods that can replace one another, such as butter and margarine. To be more precise, when the price of one rises, demand for the other increases. Examples include: butter and margarine Budweiser beer and Miller beer beef and chicken caffeine and sleep electric light and candle light old cars and new cars bicycles and cars Complements are goods that are typically used together. To be more precise, when the price of one falls, demand for the other rises. Examples include: electricity and computers computer hardware and computer software roads and automobiles left shoes and right shoes beer and salty snacks It is worth noting that when the price of salty snacks falls, demand for beer rises. This is why taverns will very often give patrons salty snacks for free. Substitutes and complements can be illustrated in the standard consumer diagram. Consider the change in the quantity of x demanded when the price of y falls. If the quantity of x demanded rises, the two goods are complements, of the quantity of x demanded falls, the two goods are substitutes: EC 352: Intermediate Microeconomics, Lecture 6 Two graphs showing the effect of a decrease in the price of good y on the quantity of good x that a consumer demands under the assumption that the two goods are complements and under the assumption that they are substitutes.
    [Show full text]
  • Explaining Hypothetical Bias Variations Using Income Elasticity of Demand
    School of Economic Sciences Working Paper Series WP 2013‐15 Explaining Hypothetical Bias Variations Using Income Elasticity of Demand By Tongzhe Li and Felix Munoz‐Garcia November 2013 Explaining Hypothetical Bias Variations Using Income Elasticity of Demand Tongzhe Liy Félix Muñoz-Garcíaz School of Economic Sciences School of Economic Sciences Washington State University Washington State University Pullman, WA 99164 Pullman, WA 99164 November 21, 2013 Abstract Experimental methods have been widely used to elicit consumer preferences. However, the estimates are challenged because the existing literature indicates that individuals overstate their economic valuation in hypothetical settings, thus giving rise to the so-called “hypothetical bias.” Although many studies seek to experimentally test which factors emphasize or ameliorate the hypothetical bias, no studies analyze its theoretical foundations. In this paper, we provide a theoretical model to demonstrate the underlying causes of hypothetical bias. Our results also help to explain experimental regularities, such as that hypothetical bias increases in a commodity’s income elasticity of demand, and that the hypothetical bias for public goods is larger than for private goods. Keywords: Experiments; Hypothetical Bias; Income Elasticity; Private and Public Goods; Willingness to Pay. JEL classification: C9, D01, D10 We would like to especially thank Ana Espínola-Arredondo, Miaoru Liu, Jill McCluskey, Ron Mittelhammer and Robert Rosenman for their insightful comments and suggestions. yAddress: 213 Hulbert Hall, Washington State University, Pullman, WA 99164. E-mail: [email protected]. zAddress: 103G Hulbert Hall, Washington State University. Pullman, WA 99164-6210. E-mail: [email protected]. Phone: (509) 335 8402. Fax: (509) 335 1173. 1 1 Introduction Field and laboratory experiments in the last decades have sought to elicit consumers’willingness to pay for various goods, both private and public in nature, including environmental services and other nonmarket goods.
    [Show full text]
  • Budget Constraint, Preferences and Utility
    Budget Constraint, Preferences and Utility Varian: Intermediate Microeconomics, 8e, Chapters 2, 3 and 4 () 1 / 53 Consumer Theory Consumers choose the best bundles of goods they can afford. • This is virtually the entire theory in a nutshell. • But this theory has many surprising consequences. Two parts to consumer theory • \can afford" { budget constraint • \best" { according to consumers' preferences () 2 / 53 Consumer Theory (cont´d) What do we want to do with the theory? • Test it. See if it is adequate to describe consumer behavior. • Predict how behavior changes as economic environment changes. • Use observed behavior to estimate underlying values. These values can be used for • cost-benefit analysis, • predicting impact of some policy. () 3 / 53 Budget Constraint The first part of the lecture explains • what is the budget constraint and the budget line, • how changes in income and prices affect the budget line, • how taxes, subsidies and rationing affect the budget line. () 4 / 53 Consumption Bundle For goods 1 and 2, the consumption bundle (x1; x2) shows how much of each good is consumed. Suppose that we can observe • the prices of the two goods (p1; p2) • and the amount of money the consumer has to spend m (income). The budget constraint can be written as p1x1 + p2x2 ≤ m. The affordable consumption bundles are bundles that don't cost more than income. The set of affordable consumption bundles is budget set of the consumer. () 5 / 53 Two Goods Theory works with more than two goods, but can't draw pictures. We often think of good 2 (say) as a composite good, representing money to spend on other goods.
    [Show full text]
  • Topic 3: Consumer Theory Rational Consumer Choice
    DARTMOUTH COLLEGE, DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 1 Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 1, Fall ‘02 Topic 3: Consumer Theory Economics 1, Fall 2002 Andreas Bentz Based Primarily on Frank Chapters 3 - 5 Rational Consumer Choice X “A rational individual always chooses to do what she most prefers to do, given the options that are open to her.” X Two questions: – How do we describe the options open to a consumer? » Individuals operate under constraints. – How do we describe preferences? » We use indifference curves to represent preferences. 2 © Andreas Bentz page 1 DARTMOUTH COLLEGE, DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 1 Two Goods are Enough X In what follows, we will only study the choice between two goods. – This allows us to draw (two-dimensional) diagrams. – (And: Two goods are often enough: for instance, if we are interested in your choice about how much pizza to consume, we could make the two goods “pizza” and “money spent on everything else.”) 3 Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 1, Fall ‘02 Constraints Open Opportunities © Andreas Bentz page 2 DARTMOUTH COLLEGE, DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 1 Constraints X Typically, we operate under many constraints: – time constraint: » How do you allocate time to the following activities: eating, sleeping, going to class, homework? – budget constraint: » How do you allocate your income to different consumption goods? X We will be interested in budget constraints: how do you allocate your expenditure? – (We will later discuss the problem of how to allocate your time between leisure and work.) 5 Bundles of Goods X Definition: A bundle of goods is a particular combination of quantities of (two or more) goods.
    [Show full text]
  • Optimal Provision of Public Goods: a Synthesis∗
    Optimal Provision of Public Goods: A Synthesis∗ Claus Thustrup Kreiner University of Copenhagen, EPRU, and CESifo Nicolaj Verdelin University of Copenhagen and EPRU Preliminary Draft: October 2008 Abstract There currently exist two competing approaches in the literature on the optimal provision of public goods. The standard approach highlights the importance of distortionary taxa- tion and distributional concerns. The new approach neutralizes distributional concerns by adjusting the non-linear income tax, and finds that this reinvigorates the simple Samuelson rule when preferences are separable in goods and leisure. We provide a synthesis by demon- strating that both approaches derive from the same basic formula. We further develop the new approach by deriving a general, intuitive formula for the optimal level of a public good without imposing any separability assumptions on preferences. This formula shows that distortionary taxation may have a role to play as in the standard approach. However, the main determinants of optimal provision are completely different and the traditional formula with its emphasis on MCF only obtains in a very special case. (JEL: H41, H23, H11) ∗We are grateful to Kenneth Small for discussions leading up to this paper. We also wish to thank Henrik Jacobsen Kleven for detailed comments on a previous draft. 1Introduction Cost-benefit analysis is an important tool in everyday government decision making on public projects. When carried out in practice, the dominating view seems to be that the costs of a tax-funded project should be adjusted according to the marginal cost of funds (MCF), as a close reflection of the deadweight loss that will materialize if the project is added to the budget.1 Today, the theoretical foundation for such a practice is less clear.
    [Show full text]
  • The Welfare Cost of Uncertainty in Policy Outcomes
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE WELFARE COST OF UNCERTAINTY IN POLICY OUTCOMES Edward Schlee V. Kerry Smith Working Paper 22864 http://www.nber.org/papers/w22864 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 November 2016 The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer-reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2016 by Edward Schlee and V. Kerry Smith. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. The Welfare Cost of Uncertainty in Policy Outcomes Edward Schlee and V. Kerry Smith NBER Working Paper No. 22864 November 2016 JEL No. H41,Q50,Q51 ABSTRACT This paper proposes a simple index of the welfare significance of uncertainty in the public goods resulting as policy outcomes. Our measure is the ex ante compensation an individual would require to accept an uncertain level of service compared to receiving the expected value of the distribution of possible values for that service. Our compensation measure is a function of the coefficient of relative risk aversion, the variance in the measure of environmental service associated with policy and relevant for the individual, and a set of conventional parameters that describe the properties of nonmarket benefit measures under conditions of certainty. We would expect that the inverse virtual price elasticity of the for the environmental service and the square of the coefficient of relative variation are the primary factors influencing the size of our compensation index.
    [Show full text]
  • Regeneration, Public Goods, and Economic Growth Author(S): Oded Hochman and Eithan Hochman Source: Econometrica, Vol
    Regeneration, Public Goods, and Economic Growth Author(s): Oded Hochman and Eithan Hochman Source: Econometrica, Vol. 48, No. 5 (Jul., 1980), pp. 1233-1250 Published by: The Econometric Society Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1912180 . Accessed: 20/06/2011 16:57 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at . http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=econosoc. Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. The Econometric Society is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Econometrica. http://www.jstor.org Econometrica, Vol. 48, No. 5 (July, 1980) REGENERATION, PUBLIC GOODS, AND ECONOMIC GROWTH BY ODED HOCHMAN AND EITHAN HOCHMAN' In this paper we discuss the (Pareto) optimal provision of a public good (desirable or undesirable) in an intergenerational model of an economy, where regeneration is an endogenous decision variable of the households in the economy.
    [Show full text]