Loss of Rail Competition As an Issue in the Proposed Sale of Conrail to Norfolk Southern: Valid Concern Or Political Bogeyman Mark D
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
Cleveland State University EngagedScholarship@CSU Cleveland State Law Review Law Journals 1986 Loss of Rail Competition as an Issue in the Proposed Sale of Conrail to Norfolk Southern: Valid Concern or Political Bogeyman Mark D. Perreault Nancy S. Fleischman Follow this and additional works at: https://engagedscholarship.csuohio.edu/clevstlrev Part of the Business Organizations Law Commons, and the Transportation Law Commons How does access to this work benefit oy u? Let us know! Recommended Citation Mark D. Perreault & Nancy S. Fleischman, Loss of Rail Competition as an Issue in the Proposed Sale of Conrail to Norfolk Southern: Valid Concern or Political Bogeyman, 34 Clev. St. L. Rev. 413 (1985-1986) This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Law Journals at EngagedScholarship@CSU. It has been accepted for inclusion in Cleveland State Law Review by an authorized editor of EngagedScholarship@CSU. For more information, please contact [email protected]. LOSS OF RAIL COMPETITION AS AN ISSUE IN THE PROPOSED SALE OF CONRAIL TO NORFOLK SOUTHERN: VALID CONCERN OR POLITICAL BOGEYMAN? MARK D. PERREAULT* NANCY S. FLEISCHMAN** 1. INTRODUCTION ......... ..................................... 414 II. PRESERVATION OF RAIL-RAIL COMPETITION AS A CONSIDERATION IN RAIL CONSOLIDATIONS ............................... 414 A . Prior to 1920 ................................. 414 B . 1920 - 1940 .................................. 418 C. 1940 - 1980 .................................. 421 D . 1980 - Present ................................ 425 Ill. PRESERVATION OF RAIL-RAIL COMPETITION AS A CONSIDERATION IN THE FORMATION OF CONRAIL AND SUBSEQUENT DETERMINATION TO SELL CONRAIL ........ ........................................ 428 A. 1970's Congressional Response to the Penn Central and Other Railroad Bankruptcies ..................... 428 B. Foundation of Initial CongressionalPolicy ........... 429 C. Implementing the Policy ......................... 432 D. The Decision to Sell Conrail...................... 433 IV. THE DEPARTMENT OF TRANSPORATION'S DECISION TO SELL CONRAIL TO NORFOLK SOUTHERN AND SUBSEQUENT EVENTS ............... 433 A. The Bidding Process and Selection of Norfolk Southern. 433 B. Department of Justice Evaluation of Norfolk Southern- Conrail Consolidation........................... 435 V. A VIEWPOINT ON RAIL-RAIL COMPETITION AND THE NORFOLK SOUTHERN-CONRAIL AFFILIATION ..... ........................ 436 A. DOJ Underestimated the Pervasiveness of Intermodal Competition in Conrail'sMarkets .................. 436 B. DOJ Placed Emphasis Unprecedented in Recent His- tory on PreservingRail-Rail Competition in the Divesti- tures ........................................ 437 C. DOJ's Attention to Rail-Rail Competition Goes Far Be- yond What is Required Under TransportationLaw or the National TransportationPolicy ................... 439 * Assistant General Solicitor, Norfolk Southern Corporation. ** General Attorney, Norfolk Southern Corporation. Published by EngagedScholarship@CSU, 1986 1 CLEVELAND STATE LA W REVIEW [Vol. 34:413 I. INTRODUCTION The Department of Transportation's (DOT) plan to return Consoli- dated Rail Corporation (Conrail) to the private sector by selling the federal government's controlling interest to Norfolk Southern Corpora- tion (Norfolk Southern) has, not surprisingly, been the subject of a spirited debate in the transportation and political community since its announcement in February, 1985. Detractors have voiced concerns about loss of jobs, quality of service, rates, adequacy of the price, tax benefits, effects on other railroads, ports, communities, and even minority ven- dors.1 Perhaps the most virulent yet poorly understood criticism has been that Norfolk Southern's acquisition of Conrail would adversely affect competition. Critics have said that the sale proposal "runs directly contrary to [antitrust] policy goals" and would have a serious, adverse effect on competition. 2 The proposal is a "flagrant violation of antitrust laws and would create an unconscionable monopoly."3 [T]he proposed sale of Conrail to the Norfolk Southern violates every principle of good transportation policy and destroys the competitive framework which is the key to the future health of our railroad system .... [The proposal] would not survive any rational scrutiny under antitrust concepts that have governed 4 every railroad merger in this country. The purpose of this article is to examine the legal standards histori- cally and currently applied to considering the competitive impacts of rail consolidations in conjunction with the goals of the legislation relating to Conrail. With that perspective, a viewpoint will be offered as to whether the competitive effects of the proposed sale have been addressed in a manner consistent with those standards and goals. II. PRESERVATION OF RAIL-RAIL COMPETITION AS A CONSIDERATION IN RAIL CONSOLIDATIONS A. Prior to 1920 Prior to the enactment in 1890 of the Sherman Antitrust Act, there were no federal limitations on mergers or other consolidations of compet- See Wall Street Journal, Aug. 8, 1985, at 22, col. 1. 2 Sale of Conrail:Hearings on S261-31.9 Before the Committee on Commerce, Science, and Transportation, 99th Cong. 1st Sess. 323 (1985) (statement of Bruce B_ Wilson, Vice-Pres., Law, Consolidated Rail. Corp.). Youngstown Vindicator, Oct. 16, 1985, at 12, col. 1, (statement of Ill. Atty. Gen. Neil F. Hartigan). ' Sale of Conrail:Hearings on S261-31.9 Before the Committee on Commerce, Science, and Transportation,219-20 (1985) (statement of Hays T. Watkins, Bd. Chairman and Chief Exec. Officer of CSX Corp.). https://engagedscholarship.csuohio.edu/clevstlrev/vol34/iss3/6 2 1986] LOSS OF RAIL COMPETITION ing railroads.5 A Jay Gould or Daniel Drew, if he worried about laws at all, could limit his concern to state corporate law and any state regulatory law which might apply to the particular transaction involved. While the enactment of the Interstate Commerce Act (Act) preceded the Sherman Act by three years, its original provisions did not address consolidations other than "pooling" between different carriers. 6 The Act was primarily directed, from the shippers' point of view, to eliminating rebates, and, from the carriers' point of view, to achieving some modicum of rate stability in an industry then afflicted with a tremendous increase in capacity without a corresponding increase in business.7 The railroads had not reached the stage in their development where consolidation was viewed as the solution of choice for their problems. Rather, the railroads had looked primarily to rate agreements and, prior to 1887, the outright allocation of revenues and traffic among competing carriers, the "pool," for relief.8 Several years after the passage of the Act, however, a major rail consolidation movement took root. Problems such as the railroads' inability to stabilize rates at profitable levels or to slow reckless expan- sion of lines through provisions of the Act, rate agreements or legalized pools, as well as problems in the economy (e.g., the Depression of 1893), prompted calls for consolidation of the various lines.9 This movement collided with the new national policy of enhancing economic efficiency by protecting and promoting competition, which was promulgated in the Sherman Act. The first major rail unification challenged under the Sherman Act was the attempt by the J.P. Morgan-James J. Hill-controlled Northern Securities Company to acquire the stock of the Great Northern Railway (GN) and Northern Pacific Railway (NP). This second attempt to amal- gamate these competing rail lines failed when the Supreme Court affirmed a lower court decree declaring the consolidation a "combination in restraint of interstate and international commerce" and therefore ' Cf. G. KOLKO, RAILROADS AND REGULATION 1877-1916 14 (1965). 6 Interstate Commerce Act of Feb. 4, 1887, ch. 104, 24 Stat. 379. Pooling, much to the chagrin of the railroads, was prohibited by the Act. Id. at § 5 (codified as amended at 49 U.S.C. § 11342). 7 G. KOLKO, supra note 5, at 7-44. 8 Id. at 17-19. v Aldace Walker in 1890 and Collis P, Huntington in 1891 urged rail managers to consolidate in the interest of ending anarchy. Id. at 64. Following the Depression of 1893 and the reorganization of many railroads, J.P. Morgan took the lead in acquiring control of, although not necessarily consolidating, a large number of carriers, including the Erie, Reading, Jersey Central, Lehigh Valley, Delaware & Hudson, Northern Pacific, Southern, and New Haven. Id. at 65-66. These developments did not achieve the desired result as rates declined drastically during the 1890's, from 94o per ton mile to 73v per ton mile. Id. at 66. Published by EngagedScholarship@CSU, 1986 3 CLEVELAND STATE LAW REVIEW [Vol. 34:413 prohibited by Section 1 of the Sherman Act.1 The compeIc ive analysis by the Court was primitive by today's standards; the Court simply found that GN and NP were "competing and substantially parallel lines from the Great Lakes and the Mississippi River to the Pacific Ocean and Puget Sound"i" and that [ilf such combination be not destroyed, all tk advantages that would naturally come to the public under the op-ration of the general laws of competition, or between the Great Northern and Northern Pacific Railway companies, will be lost, and the entire commerce of the immense territory in the northern part of the United States between the Great Lakes and the Pacific at Puget Sound will be at the mercy of a single holding corporation. .12