Accumulation Regimes, Endogenous Desired Rate of Capacity Utilization and Income Distribution*

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Accumulation Regimes, Endogenous Desired Rate of Capacity Utilization and Income Distribution* Investigación Económica, vol. LXIII, núm. 248, abril-junio, 2004, pp. 41-70 Accumulation Regimes, Endogenous Desired Rate of Capacity Utilization and Income Distribution* JOSÉ LUIS OREIRO** INTRODUCTION The principle of effective demand in its Kaleckian version has been constantly invoked as the theoretical foundation of what was named in economic literature as “cooperative capitalism”; i.e. the idea that capitalists and workers could both benefit from a redistribution of income toward wages. The main argument is that an increase in the share of wages would produce an increase in aggregate demand —since the propensity to consume for workers is higher than capitalists— and in the degree of capacity utilization. Thus, this change in income distribution would be compatible Received October 2002; accepted October 2003. * Modified version of the paper delivered at 4th Annual Conference of the Association for Heterodox Economics, held at Dublin City University from the 9th to the 10th of July, 2002. ** PHD in Economics at Federal University od Rio de Janeiro and Professor of Economics at Universidade Federal do Paraná, Curitiba, Brazil <[email protected]> <www.joseluisoreiro.ecn.br>. 41 42 JOSÉ LUIS OREIRO with the stability (even an increase) of the profit rate. On the other hand, due to the existence of the accelerator effect, this increase in the degree of capacity utilization would induce firms to increase investment in fixed capital, stimulating growth. Therefore, according to this line of reasoning, the principle of effective demand would be the theoretical foundation of “cooperative capitalism” and also of the wage-led growth regime. However, some authors —for example, Marglin and Bhaduri (1990)— have questioned the hypothesis of wage-led growth at empirical and theoretical levels. According to these authors, the empirical evidence of the European economies in the 1960’s and 1970’s is incompatible with the hypothesis of a positive relationship between the share of wages and the degree of capacity utilization. In fact, as figure 1 illustrates, a great reduction in the profit share can be observed in the economies of the United Kingdom, Germany, France and Italy during this period. This reduction is also followed by a reduction in the degree of capacity utilization. At the theoretical level, the wage-led growth hypothesis does not take in account the effect of profit share on a firm’s investment decisions. More specifically, a reduction in profit share may be a signal for entrepreneurs of a future reduction in the profit obtained by each unit of product that firms will be able to sell with the additional productive capacity resulting from their investment decisions (cf. Marglin, S; Bhaduri, 1990, p. 173). In this case, entrepreneurs may then decide to reduce their investment spending. This reduction of the investment —if strong enough— will produce a reduction in aggregate demand, in the degree of capacity utilization and in the growth rate of capital stock. In other words, an increase in the share of wages will result in a profit squeeze which will reduce economic growth. According to this line of reasoning, the accumulation regime will be a profit-led type. I other words, economic growth will be stimulated by an increase in profits, instead of “being pulled” by increase in wages. Thus, the relationship between income distribution, the degree of capacity utilization and economic growth will be dependent on the macroeconomic structure, i.e. the set of structural relations between the main ACCUMULATION REGIMES AND CAPACITY UTILIZATION 43 macroeconomic variables.1 If investment is very sensitive to changes in the degree of capacity utilization but not as sensitive to changes in the profit share, the accumulation regime will be the wage-led type. If, on the other hand, investment is very sensitive to changes in the share of profits and not so sensitive to changes in the degree of capacity utilization, the accumulation regime will be the profit-led type. FIGURE 1 Profit Rate and Profit Share in Four European Economies (1951-1983) 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 1951 1953 1955 1957 1959 1961 1963 1965 1967 1969 1971 1973 1975 1977 1979 1981 1983 Profit Rate Profit Share Source: Marglin and Bhaduri (1990). 1 Marglin (1990) defines a macroeconomic structure as the set of mechanisms that determine the global level of economic performance (p. 6). This definition, however, is not very precise because it does not specify the set of mechanisms that will determine economic performance nor how economic performance is determined. In the present article, however, we will define the concept of macroeconomic structure as the set of relations between the main macroeconomic variables, and this set will be represented by structural equations between the variables in the model. For example, a macroeconomic structure can be represented by relations of the type I=f (u) or I=f (u, m), where I is the volume of investment, u is the degree of capacity utilization and m is profit share. 44 JOSÉ LUIS OREIRO However, the Kaleckian view and the most recent approach by Marglin and Bhaduri had both ignored an important element of the macroeconomic structure: the relationship between planned investment by firms and planned (desired) degrees of capacity utilization. In fact, these approaches consider investment a function of the effective degree of capacity utilization (cf. Rowthorn, 1981; Dutt, 1984; Taylor, 1985) or consider the desired degree of capacity utilization an exogenous variable of the model (cf. Amadeo, 1986) so that a change in the profit share cannot produce a change in the planned degree of capacity utilization. Thus, the objective of the present article is to introduce the desired degree of capacity utilization as an endogenous variable in the macroeconomic structure of a Post-Keynesian growth model and evaluate the impact of this change in the macroeconomic relationship of income distribution, effective degrees of capacity utilization and economic growth. In order to do that, we will assume —like Skott (1989)— that the planned degree of capacity utilization is a decreasing function of the profit share. The economic basis of this assumption is the idea that excess capacity may be used by established firms as a device to increase the level of “entry barriers” to new competitors in the industry. The desired level of excess capacity is an increasing function of the economic profits obtained by established firms since the bigger the profit, the greater the incentive will be for new firms to enter the market. This change in the macroeconomic structure will produce a short run equilibrium configuration of the economy in which there are two equilibrium levels of productive capacity utilization and two equilibrium growth rates. In other words, in our model economy, multiple equilibrium points exist. In this situation, an increase in the share of wages can produce either an increase or a decrease in the effective level of capacity utilization, depending on its initial value. If capacity utilization is initially high, then an increase in the wage share will generate an increase in the effective degree of capacity utilization and the economy will be in a “stagnationist regime”. However, if capacity utilization is initially low, then an increase in the wage share will produce a reduction in the effective level of capacity utilization and ACCUMULATION REGIMES AND CAPACITY UTILIZATION 45 the economy will be in an “exhilarationist regime”. Therefore, the relationship between income distribution and capacity utilization is non- linear as Bhaduri and Marglin have suggested in their 1990 article. However, for the long run equilibrium configuration of the economy, the endogenous application of the planned degree of productive capacity utilization will produce a change in the causality between income distribution and economic growth. In the Marglin and Bhaduri model, a change in the distribution of wages and profits will produce a change in the profitability of investment on fixed capital and consequently, a change in the growth rate of capital stock. In our model, changes in functional income distribution do not affect the growth rate of capital stock. In the long run, the growth rate of capital stock is completely determined by the autonomous component of the investment function —more precisely, the “animal spirits” of the capitalists— and is independent of changes in the income distribution of wages and profits. The opposite of this, however, does not stand. Changes in the growth rate of capital stock will in fact produce changes in the distribution of income between wages and profits. If the economy is in the upward sloping region of the “no-entry-condition” curve, a reduction in the growth rate of capital stock will produce a reduction in both the profit share and in the long-run level of capacity utilization. Thus, a “profit squeeze” situation can be the result of an autonomous reduction in the propensity of capitalists to invest rather than the result of a class struggle between capitalists and workers. This article is structured in five sections including the introduction. In the second section, we will present some theoretical arguments for the existence of a planned or desired level of excess capacity and examine the relationship between this variable and the investment decisions of the firms as well as the relationship between income distribution, capacity utilization and capital accumulation in the canonical Kalecki-Steindl growth model. In the third section, the basic structure of a Post-Keynesian growth model with an endogenous planned degree of capacity utilization will be presented as well as the short run equilibrium configuration of the economy. The fourth section presents the long run equilibrium configuration and analyses 46 JOSÉ LUIS OREIRO the effect of a reduction in the animal spirits of the capitalists on income distribution and on the long run level of capacity utilization.
Recommended publications
  • Chapter 24 Financial Accelerator
    Chapter 24 Financial Accelerator Starting in 2007, and becoming much more pronounced in 2008, macro-financial events took center stage in the macroeconomic landscape. The “financial collapse,” as many have termed it, had its proximate cause in the U.S., as several financial-sector institutions experienced severe or catastrophic downturns in the values of their financial assets. Various and large-scale policy efforts were implemented very quickly in the U.S. to try to contain possible consequences. The motivation behind these policy efforts was not to save the financial sector for its own sake. Instead, the rationale for policy responses was that severe financial downturns often lead to contraction in real macroeconomic markets (for example, think in terms of goods markets). Despite a raft of policy measures to try to prevent such effects, the severe financial disruption did cause a sharp contraction of economic activity in real markets: GDP declined by nearly four percent in the third quarter of 2008, the time period during which financial disruptions were at their most severe. This quarterly decline was the largest in the U.S. since the early 1980s, and GDP continued declining for the next three quarters. But the reason this pullback in GDP was especially worrisome was something history shows is common. When it is triggered by financial turbulence, a contraction in real economic activity can further exacerbate the financial downturn. This downstream effect was the real fear of policy makers. If this downstream effect occurred, the now- steeper financial downturn then could even further worsen the macro downturn, which in turn could even further worsen the financial downturn, which in turn could even further worsen the macro downturn, and ….
    [Show full text]
  • An Introduction to Post-Keynesian Models of Distribution and Growth
    An Introduction to Post-Keynesian Theories of Distribution and Growth: Alternative Models and Empirical Findings Robert A. Blecker Professor of Economics, American University Washington, DC, USA, [email protected] Introductory Lecture, 22nd FMM/IMK Conference “10 Years After the Crash: What Have We Learned?” Berlin, Germany, 25 October, 2018 Shameless advertisement and important acknowledgement • Portions of this presentation are based on the book manuscript: Robert A. Blecker and Mark Setterfield, Heterodox Macroeconomics: Models of Demand, Distribution and Growth, Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing, Ltd., 2019, forthcoming. • I also present results from the dissertation of one of my doctoral students (used with permission): Michael Cauvel, Three Essays on the Empirical Estimation of Wage-led and Profit-led Demand Regimes, unpublished PhD dissertation, American University, Washington, DC, USA, July 2018. Distribution and growth: the big questions • Does a society have to endure worse inequality for its economy to grow and create jobs? • Or can growth and employment creation be consistent with greater distributive equity? • Historically, economists believed that distributional equity had to be sacrificed to achieve faster growth • Ricardo, Marx, Lewis-Ranis-Fei, Kaldor, etc.: faster growth generally requires a higher profit share or greater inequality • At least in the early stages of development (Kuznets curve) • Kuznets curve now largely debunked by Piketty • Recent empirical studies are finding that lower inequality is often
    [Show full text]
  • Capacity Utilization, Inflation and Monetary Policy
    Capacity Utilization, Inflation and Monetary Policy: Classicals, post-Keynesians and the New Keynesian Consensus Peter Kriesler and Marc Lavoie1 Abstract The paper looks at the adjustment process towards long run equilibrium within Marxian models, defined in terms of normal rates of capacity utilization. The model is reduced to three essential equations: an IS equation, a Phillips curve equation and an central bank reaction function. It is shown that long run convergence depends on the specific inflation (Phillips curve) equation, and on the central bank setting a zero inflationary target. When these conditions are relaxed, the results are shown to accord more closely with post-Keynesian results. The Marxian model is then contrasted with New Consensus models, which only varies in its inflation/Phillips curve equation. Post-Keynesian criticisms of both the IS and the Phillips curve equation are considered, and suggestions for a post-Keynesian alternative are made. Keywords: monetary policy, central bank, inflation, capacity utilization, post-Keynesian, New- Keynesian JEL classification: E12, E40, E52, E58 In an extremely interesting paper, Duménil and Lévy (Duménil and Lévy 1999) explore the adjustment mechanism of an economy towards a long run equilibrium with capacity utilization at normal levels − a fully adjusted position as the Sraffians would call it, or a classical long-term equilibrium as Duménil and Lévy have it. Short run equilibrium within their model is of the Keynes/Kalecki type, with variability in levels of capacity utilization. One distinctive feature of their model is that it is not the forces of competition which push the economy to a fully adjusted position, but rather aspects of the macro economy coupled with the behaviour of the central bank.
    [Show full text]
  • Employment and Capacity Utilization Over the Business Cycle
    2016 n Number 19 ECONOMIC Synopses Employment and Capacity Utilization Over the Business Cycle Ana Maria Santacreu, Economist he fraction of the labor force that is currently Capacity Utilization: Total Industry (left) 100-Civilian Unemployment Rate (right) 98 employed is often interpreted as a measure of the 90 utilization rate of an economy’s labor force. There is 96 T 85 a corresponding concept that tries to measure the utiliza- tion rate of an economy’s capital stock—the capacity utili- 94 80 zation rate.1 The capacity utilization rate is constructed as 100-% 92 the percentage of resources (i.e., labor and capital) used 75 Percent of Capacity by corporations and factories to produce enough finished 90 goods to meet demand. 70 88 The figure plots U.S. capacity utilization at a quarterly 65 frequency from 1967:Q1–2016:Q1. In normal times, facto- 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 ries tend to use around 80 percent of their available pro- fred.stlouisfed.org myf.red/g/6ZXZ ductive capacity (as the capacity utilization average in the NOTE: The gray bars indicate recessions as determined by the National Bureau figure suggests). Because demand fluctuates, factories may of Economic Research. SOURCE: FRED®, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis; not want to use 100 percent of their installed capacity to https://fred.stlouisfed.org/graph/?g=6TA4; August 2016. avoid production bottlenecks so they can meet consumer demand. Thus, they may permit the utilization rate to fluctuate with demand. increases during expansions and decreases during recessions. In principle, capacity utilization and employment should Capacity and employment are affected comove closely, which was the case in the United States by cyclical factors, but employment during the period 1967:Q1–1990:Q1.
    [Show full text]
  • Research on the Effect of Monetary Policy on Financial Accelerator-- Based on the Empirical Analysis of Chinese Steel Enterprises
    E3S Web of Conferences 235, 01064 (2021) https://doi.org/10.1051/e3sconf/202123501064 NETID 2020 Research on the Effect of Monetary Policy on Financial Accelerator-- Based on the empirical analysis of Chinese steel enterprises Chenyi Zhao1*,a, Xuefei Yu2,b 1Wuhan university of technology, Wuhan, China 2Changjiang Futures Co. LTD, Wuhan, China Abstract—From the perspective of principal-agent, the theory of financial acceleration holds that due to the defects of the financial market, external shocks will be amplified by the financial market and accelerate the transmission in the real economy, and the impact on small enterprises is greater than that on large enterprises. According to the theory of financial deceleration, the agency cost caused by financial friction is counter- cyclical, which restrains credit scale to some extent, prevents excessive debt, and thus alleviates external shocks. According to the empirical analysis of panel data of iron and steel enterprises and the existing empirical results of the real estate industry, it is found that there is no financial accelerator effect or financial reducer effect in the field of iron and steel enterprises. China's financial accelerator is more focused on bubbly assets where growth is expected and continues to be overheated despite policy tightening. That would trigger a bigger debt crisis and greater economic volatility. [1]. They call this phenomenon a financial accelerator. 1 Introduction The following is the transmission mechanism of monetary policy (>>> represents financial acceleration): In 2008, under the influence of national monetary policy M↑→ R↓→ P↑→ Na↑→ Loan↑→(I↑→ Y↑)→Debt control and domestic and foreign situations, the real estate Crisis>>>Na↓→( I↓→ Y↓ ) industry once fell into a serious contraction situation.
    [Show full text]
  • U N I V E R S I T Y O F M I C H I G a N B U S I N E S S S C H O
    University of Michigan Business School Fall 2000 “I thought they’d give me a few tools. But I walked away with a shiny new toolbox.” Ann Arbor, Hong Kong, São Paulo, Singapore and other selected locations. Company-specific and public programs. For more information, please call 734.763.1000 (U.S.), e-mail [email protected], or visit www.execed.bus.umich.edu Fall 2000 FEATURES DEPARTMENTS 3 Across the Board 19 On Testing for Common Sense Top B-Schools Partner on E-Business When Michigan announced it was piloting a new admissions method for measuring Offerings… From Idea to IPO in 14 prospective students’ “practical” intelligence, The New York Times wanted to know Weeks… E-Lab Wins Major Award… more. Read about this innovative effort to test leadership skills not captured by Michigan Faculty Rank Second in Research standardized tests. Performance… C.K. Prahalad Discusses “The Digital Dividend” and more… 22 Local to Global: Stanley Frankel 9 Quote Unquote Underwrites International Who is saying what—and where. 13 Faculty Research Entrepreneurship Good-bye Flexible Manufacturing; When Stanley Frankel was a student, the business school Hello Reconfigurability experience was more or less local and entrepreneurial It’s a long word that describes the newest opportunities were non-existent. Today, it is just the opposite: Students can elect to way to shorten new product development participate in international, entrepreneurial assignments as part of their course work. time—and save money in the process. PLUS: A list of recent journal articles 25 Why Aren’t More Women in Business? written by University of Michigan Business Michigan initiates a national debate on women and business with the release of the School faculty and how to obtain copies.
    [Show full text]
  • Imbalance Game 2.0: a Tale of Two Productivities
    NEW THINKING Imbalance Game 2.0: A Tale of Two Productivities Michael Craig, CFA Vice President & Director Haining Zha, CFA Vice President September 2017 Almost nine years after the financial crisis, the global economy remains mired in low growth. Low productivity growth is certainly a key contributing factor, but our research shows that current productivity measures don’t tell the whole story. In this article, we propose a fundamental change to how people should examine productivity: we believe the supply and demand sides should be viewed separately to obtain more robust insights. Taking this approach allows us to differentiate supply-side progress from demand-side malaise and shows that the economy may be more promising than commonly thought. In addition, it highlights large supply-side divergences within and across different sectors of the economy, which are not reflected in the aggregate productivity measure – potentially leading to a distorted economic picture. Viewing productivity through this new lens, we believe that: • Nominal economic growth will remain low • Inflation will remain subdued • Interest rates will stay lower for longer • Technology-driven progress and persistent supply-side divergence will create investment risks and opportunities in equity markets In the investment world, economic growth is a big deal. We believe investment returns across asset classes can ultimately be traced back to one source: economic growth. Occasionally, asset prices can deviate from fundamentals, but over the long term, the relationship between returns and growth is very strong. That’s why it is critical to have a better understanding of the low growth phenomenon and key contributing factors, such as productivity.
    [Show full text]
  • Myrdal Revisited May 2011
    1 GUNNAR MYRDAL REVISITED: CUMULATIVE CAUSATION, ACCUMULATION AND LEGITIMISATION The aim of this paper is to provide a reconstruction of Myrdal’s analysis of the factors determining the path of accumulation, in view of the pivotal role played by political institutions in promoting it. It will be shown that Myrdal’s theory of cumulative causation, combined with his idea that consensus on the existing social order is a “created harmony”, is a powerful analytical tool in understanding a key contradiction of capitalist reproduction (particularly in a neo-liberal regime): namely the trade-off between accumulation and legitimisation. Keywords: Gunnar Myrdal, accumulation, welfare state, political institutions JEL: B25, H11, E25 by Guglielmo Forges Davanzati* 1 - Introduction Gunnar Myrdal’s contribution can be regarded as diametrically opposed to the Walrasian picture of the functioning of market economies on two main grounds. First, the idea that the economic process does not develop in equilibrium conditions, and that – by contrast – disequilibrium is the normal outcome of the dynamics of deregulated market economies. Second, the conviction that the power factor – in market relations as well in socio-political arena - plays a crucial role in economic theory (cf. Dostaler, Ethier, Lepage, eds., 1992; Applequist and Andersson, eds., 2004). In the Walrasian world, the absence of different degrees of bargaining power among agents is justified on the grounds that markets are in equilibrium, so that – as Samuelson (1957, p.894) maintained - “in
    [Show full text]
  • Macroeconomic Implications of Financial Imperfections: a Survey
    BIS Working Papers No 677 Macroeconomic implications of financial imperfections: a survey by Stijn Claessens and M Ayhan Kose Monetary and Economic Department November 2017 JEL classification: D53, E21, E32, E44, E51, F36, F44, F65, G01, G10, G12, G14, G15, G21 Keywords: asset prices, balance sheets, credit, financial accelerator, financial intermediation, financial linkages, international linkages, leverage, liquidity, macrofinancial linkages, output, real-financial linkages BIS Working Papers are written by members of the Monetary and Economic Department of the Bank for International Settlements, and from time to time by other economists, and are published by the Bank. The papers are on subjects of topical interest and are technical in character. The views expressed in them are those of their authors and not necessarily the views of the BIS. This publication is available on the BIS website (www.bis.org). © Bank for International Settlements 2017. All rights reserved. Brief excerpts may be reproduced or translated provided the source is stated. ISSN 1020-0959 (print) ISSN 1682-7678 (online) Macroeconomic implications of financial imperfections: a survey Stijn Claessens and M. Ayhan Kose Abstract This paper surveys the theoretical and empirical literature on the macroeconomic implications of financial imperfections. It focuses on two major channels through which financial imperfections can affect macroeconomic outcomes. The first channel, which operates through the demand side of finance and is captured by financial accelerator-type mechanisms, describes how changes in borrowers’ balance sheets can affect their access to finance and thereby amplify and propagate economic and financial shocks. The second channel, which is associated with the supply side of finance, emphasises the implications of changes in financial intermediaries’ balance sheets for the supply of credit, liquidity and asset prices, and, consequently, for macroeconomic outcomes.
    [Show full text]
  • Notes on the Accumulation and Utilization of Capital: Some Theoretical Issues
    Working Paper No. 952 Notes on the Accumulation and Utilization of Capital: Some Theoretical Issues by Michalis Nikiforos* Levy Economics Institute of Bard College April 2020 * For useful comments, the author would like to thank participants at the 45th annual Eastern Economic Association conference in New York and those at the 23rd Forum for Microeconomics and Macroeconomics conference in Berlin. The usual disclaimer applies The Levy Economics Institute Working Paper Collection presents research in progress by Levy Institute scholars and conference participants. The purpose of the series is to disseminate ideas to and elicit comments from academics and professionals. Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, founded in 1986, is a nonprofit, nonpartisan, independently funded research organization devoted to public service. Through scholarship and economic research it generates viable, effective public policy responses to important economic problems that profoundly affect the quality of life in the United States and abroad. Levy Economics Institute P.O. Box 5000 Annandale-on-Hudson, NY 12504-5000 http://www.levyinstitute.org Copyright © Levy Economics Institute 2020 All rights reserved ISSN 1547-366X ABSTRACT This paper discusses some issues related to the triangle between capital accumulation, distribution, and capacity utilization. First, it explains why utilization is a crucial variable for the various theories of growth and distribution—more precisely, with regards to their ability to combine an autonomous role for demand (along Keynesian lines) and an institutionally determined distribution (along classical lines). Second, it responds to some recent criticism by Girardi and Pariboni (2019). I explain that their interpretation of the model in Nikiforos (2013) is misguided, and that the results of the model can be extended to the case of a monopolist.
    [Show full text]
  • The Great Depression As a Historical Problem
    Upjohn Institute Press The Great Depression as a Historical Problem Michael A. Bernstein University of California, San Diego Chapter 3 (pp. 63-94) in: The Economics of the Great Depression Mark Wheeler, ed. Kalamazoo, MI: W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research, 1998 DOI: 10.17848/9780585322049.ch3 Copyright ©1998. W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research. All rights reserved. 3 The Great Depression as a Historical Problem Michael A. Bernstein University of California, San Diego It is now over a half-century since the Great Depression of the 1930s, the most severe and protracted economic crisis in American his tory. To this day, there exists no general agreement about its causes, although there tends to be a consensus about its consequences. Those who at the time argued that the Depression was symptomatic of a pro found weakness in the mechanisms of capitalism were only briefly heard. After World War II, their views appeared hysterical and exag gerated, as the industrialized nations (the United States most prominent among them) sustained dramatic rates of growth and as the economics profession became increasingly preoccupied with the development of Keynesian theory and the management of the mixed economy. As a consequence, the economic slump of the inter-war period came to be viewed as a policy problem rather than as an outgrowth of fundamental tendencies in capitalist development. Within that new context, a debate persisted for a few years, but it too eventually subsided. The presump tion was that the Great Depression could never be repeated owing to the increasing sophistication of economic analysis and policy formula tion.
    [Show full text]
  • Alumni Magazine C2-C4camjf07 12/21/06 2:50 PM Page C2 001-001Camjf07toc 12/21/06 1:39 PM Page 1
    c1-c1CAMJF07 12/22/06 1:58 PM Page c1 January/February 2007 $6.00 alumni magazine c2-c4CAMJF07 12/21/06 2:50 PM Page c2 001-001CAMJF07toc 12/21/06 1:39 PM Page 1 Contents JANUARY / FEBRUARY 2007 VOLUME 109 NUMBER 4 alumni magazine Features 52 2 From David Skorton Residence life 4 Correspondence Under the hood 8 From the Hill Remembering “Superman.” Plus: Peres lectures, seven figures for Lehman, a time capsule discovered, and a piece of Poe’s coffin. 12 Sports Small players, big win 16 Authors 40 Pynchon goes Against the Day 40 Going the Distance 35 Camps DAVID DUDLEY For three years, Cornell astronomers have been overseeing Spirit 38 Wines of the Finger Lakes and Opportunity,the plucky pair of Mars rovers that have far out- 2005 Atwater Estate Vineyards lived their expected lifespans.As the mission goes on (and on), Vidal Blanc Associate Professor Jim Bell has published Postcards from Mars,a striking collection of snapshots from the Red Planet. 58 Classifieds & Cornellians in Business 112 46 Happy Birthday, Ezra 61 Alma Matters BETH SAULNIER As the University celebrates the 200th birthday of its founder on 64 Class Notes January 11, we ask: who was Ezra Cornell? A look at the humble Quaker farm boy who suffered countless financial reversals before 104 Alumni Deaths he made his fortune in the telegraph industry—and promptly gave it away. 112 Cornelliana What’s your Ezra I.Q.? 52 Ultra Man BRAD HERZOG ’90 18 Currents Every morning at 3:30, Mike Trevino ’95 ANATOMY OF A CAMPAIGN | Aiming for $4 billion cycles a fifty-mile loop—just for practice.
    [Show full text]