921-5555 1 2 3 4 Tools to Prevent Patent "Hold-U

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

921-5555 1 2 3 4 Tools to Prevent Patent 1 1 2 3 4 TOOLS TO PREVENT PATENT "HOLD-UP" 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 Tuesday, June 21, 2011 13 9:30 a.m. 14 15 16 17 Federal Trade Commission 18 Conference Center 19 601 New Jersey Avenue, NW 20 Washington, D.C. 20001 21 22 23 24 25 For The Record, Inc. (301) 870-8025 - www.ftrinc.net - (800) 921-5555 2 1 I N D E X 2 3 PAGE: 4 Welcoming and Opening Remarks 5 By Commissioner Edith Ramirez 5 6 7 Panel 1: Roundtable Discussion 13 8 9 Presentation: Professor Jorge Contreras 83 10 11 Panel 2: Roundtable Discussion 103 12 13 Panel 3: Roundtable Discussion 146 14 15 Closing Remarks 16 By Joseph Farrell, Director, Bureau of 17 Economics 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 For The Record, Inc. (301) 870-8025 - www.ftrinc.net - (800) 921-5555 3 1 P R O C E E D I N G S 2 - - - - - 3 MR. ROACH: Hello everyone. I want to thank 4 everyone for coming. I'm delighted to see the folks that 5 are here, the interest in the issues today. I must say 6 the welcome, of course, is to the FTC Workshop on 7 Intellectual Property Rights and Standard Setting, the 8 one we've called Tools to Prevent Patent Hold-up. 9 And I am delighted to see the interest among 10 the folks who are here today, and I am very, very 11 grateful to our panelists, to our crew of panelists, who 12 have come and given us their time to be here today to 13 talk about these issues, and some of them have traveled 14 from quite some distance to be here. 15 I have a few housekeeping details I'm compelled 16 to pass on. I'm Pat Roach from the Office of Policy 17 Planning, by the way, at the FTC. And, so, if you'll 18 have the patience to bear with me, several little items 19 to take care of, one of them that is -- may be important 20 around lunchtime is that anyone who goes outside of the 21 building without the FTC badge, or even with the 22 unofficial badge, when you come back into the building 23 you are going to be required to go through the machine, 24 through that screening as you come in, but hold onto your 25 sticky patches because it will make your life a lot For The Record, Inc. (301) 870-8025 - www.ftrinc.net - (800) 921-5555 4 1 easier. You'll just be able to be waived into this room 2 again after lunch. And because of that a reminder that 3 it may take just a little bit to come in and return to 4 the auditorium. 5 There are a few other things here. In the 6 event of a fire or evacuation of the building, leave the 7 building in an orderly fashion. Once you're outside, you 8 need to orient yourself to New Jersey Avenue, which is 9 along here on this side of the building. Across from the 10 FTC is the Georgetown Law Center, and the rallying point 11 is across the street in front of the right front 12 sidewalks in case we have a fire and so forth. 13 In the event it is safer to remain inside the 14 building in an event, we'll need to be told where to go. 15 You will be told where to go. And we have some security 16 folks. If you spot any suspicious activity, please tell 17 security. 18 I'm also going to give a welcome to those who 19 are viewing these festivities by webcast, and also have a 20 reminder to those who are here today that the event is 21 open to the public and it may be photographed, 22 videotaped, webcast or recorded. And by participating in 23 the event, you are agreeing that your image or anything 24 you say or submit may be posted at the ftc.gov websites 25 or on another of the government's -- the Commission's For The Record, Inc. (301) 870-8025 - www.ftrinc.net - (800) 921-5555 5 1 publicly available social media. I'm told to tell you 2 this. 3 With that behind us, I would like to begin the 4 substance of the day today by introducing Commissioner 5 Edith Ramirez for opening remarks. 6 COMMISSIONER RAMIREZ: Thank you, Pat, and good 7 morning, everyone. On behalf of the Commission, I want 8 to welcome you to our standards workshop. Our focus 9 today will be on ways to limit the risk of patent hold-up 10 that occur when patented technologies are incorporated in 11 collaborative standards. But before I start, I'd like to 12 take a few minutes to introduce the key issues and 13 questions our three panels will discuss today. 14 I also want to take just a brief moment to 15 thank those responsible for organizing the workshop and 16 in particular Suzanne Michel and Pat Roach from our 17 Office of Policy Planning; Pete Levitas, Assistant 18 Director of the Bureau of Competition; and Joe Farrell, 19 Director of the Bureau of Economics, who will be speaking 20 to you himself at the close of the day. 21 I also want to thank our panelists for taking 22 the time to participate in today's workshop. Our 23 panelists have extensive experience with the technical, 24 business, and legal issues associated with standard- 25 setting activities, particularly in the high-tech sector, For The Record, Inc. (301) 870-8025 - www.ftrinc.net - (800) 921-5555 6 1 and will no doubt have very interesting things to say 2 about the issues to be discussed today. 3 Standards are, of course, everywhere in 4 everyday life. They guarantee that the electrical plugs 5 on ordinary household products fit the standardized 6 outlets in our homes. Ordinary products like printer 7 cartridges and tires come in standardized sizes and 8 specifications which fosters choice and competition in 9 the supply of replacement parts. 10 Standards play a particularly important role in 11 the communications and high-tech sectors, making it 12 possible for us to exchange information seamlessly across 13 competing carriers, platforms, and devices. 14 Interoperability standards are especially important in 15 network sectors like wireless communications where the 16 value of the product to any one consumer grows with the 17 total number of consumers using the network. 18 Sometimes standards arise de facto in the 19 marketplace, which may not always be ideal. Innovators 20 may be reluctant to invest in R&D until they know which 21 standards will dominate the market, and consumers may 22 delay their purchases until a winner emerges. This is 23 one reason why many industries turn to collaborative 24 development through standard-setting organizations. 25 Collaboration can also lead to the adoption of better For The Record, Inc. (301) 870-8025 - www.ftrinc.net - (800) 921-5555 7 1 technical standards with input from a broad range of 2 knowledgeable engineers and technicians. 3 On the other hand, collaborative standard- 4 setting can raise risks for competition and consumers. 5 SSO members are often product or technology market 6 competitors and collaboration can raise the risk of anti- 7 competitive agreements to exclude rivals or fix prices. 8 But since SSO activities can generate substantial pro- 9 competitive benefits, both courts and agencies evaluate 10 most SSO conduct under the rule of reason. 11 The risk of patent hold-up, the subject of 12 today's workshop, is another important competitive 13 concern associated with collaborative standard-setting. 14 In the context of the standard-setting process, patent 15 hold-up describes the situation where a patentee is able 16 to exercise increased market power in licensing 17 negotiations because its patented technology has been 18 incorporated into a standard. 19 The adoption of technical standards can 20 generate switching costs that change the competitive 21 landscape for an industry. After a standard is adopted, 22 firms may begin to make irreversible investments tied to 23 the adopted standard. Moreover, collaborative standard- 24 setting can be a lengthy process that requires SSO 25 members to reach consensus on a large number of complex For The Record, Inc. (301) 870-8025 - www.ftrinc.net - (800) 921-5555 8 1 technical issues. Changing a standard after the fact can 2 add additional delay that slows the introduction of new 3 products, resulting in lost profits for firms 4 implementing the standard. 5 As a result of these costs, patentees that may 6 have faced meaningful competition prior to adoption of 7 the standard may face little competition after the fact. 8 Hold-up occurs when a patentee uses these switching costs 9 to demand higher royalty rates than it would have -- than 10 it could have negotiated before the standard was adopted. 11 Where a firm acquires market power through 12 deception or other exclusionary conduct, patent hold-up 13 can be an antitrust violation as the Commission 14 maintained in its Dell, Unocal, and Rambus cases. And as 15 the Commission concluded in N-Data, conduct that permits 16 patent hold-up can violate Section 5 of the FTC Act, even 17 if it does not necessarily violate Section 2 of the 18 Sherman Act. 19 However, even where patent hold-up does not 20 raise an antitrust enforcement issue, it raises an 21 important issue for competition policy more broadly.
Recommended publications
  • 00009-60523.Pdf (400.75
    June 14, 2011 Federal Trade Commission Office of the Secretary Room H-113 (Annex X) 600 Pennsylvania Avenue Washington, DC 20580 Re: Patent Standards Workshop, Project No. P11-1204 Dear Commissioners and FTC executive staff: Microsoft appreciates the opportunity to provide comments in response to the Request for Comments and Announcement of Workshop on Standards-Setting Issues regarding ―patent hold- up‖ in connection with standardization efforts. At their most fundamental, technical standards are tools that promote efficiency and innovation by making it easier to create products and services that work together—or ―interoperate‖—better. This is especially true in the information and communications technology (ICT) environment. With new ICT solutions and services appearing in the market almost daily, often connected to one another by the Internet or other networks, interoperability has become a market imperative. The development and implementation of standards is one of the ways in which the technology industry is able to meet consumer demand for interoperability.1 By helping to enhance interoperability among products or services within a market, and being responsive to real marketplace needs, standards can help promote innovation, fuel market growth, and protect investments in new technologies. Microsoft plays a dual role in standardization activities. First, we actively contribute innovative technology to standardization related to computing hardware, software and associated devices, the Internet and its infrastructure, consumer electronics devices, and telecommunications systems. Second, we are an active implementer of standards. Microsoft supports a very large number of standards that are formulated by a broad diversity of standards- setting organizations (SSOs) in our products. For example, Microsoft’s Windows 7 operating 1 Microsoft’s commitment to standardization to help further interoperability is reflected in our Interoperability Principles, available at http://www.microsoft.com/interop/principles/default.mspx.
    [Show full text]
  • THE DEFENSIVE PATENT PLAYBOOK James M
    THE DEFENSIVE PATENT PLAYBOOK James M. Rice† Billionaire entrepreneur Naveen Jain wrote that “[s]uccess doesn’t necessarily come from breakthrough innovation but from flawless execution. A great strategy alone won’t win a game or a battle; the win comes from basic blocking and tackling.”1 Companies with innovative ideas must execute patent strategies effectively to navigate the current patent landscape. But in order to develop a defensive strategy, practitioners must appreciate the development of the defensive patent playbook. Article 1, Section 8, Clause 8 of the U.S. Constitution grants Congress the power to “promote the Progress of Science and useful Arts, by securing for limited Times to Authors and Inventors the exclusive Right to their respective Writings and Discoveries.”2 Congress attempts to promote technological progress by granting patent rights to inventors. Under the utilitarian theory of patent law, patent rights create economic incentives for inventors by providing exclusivity in exchange for public disclosure of technology.3 The exclusive right to make, use, import, and sell a technology incentivizes innovation by enabling inventors to recoup the costs of development and secure profits in the market.4 Despite the conventional theory, in the 1980s and early 1990s, numerous technology companies viewed patents as unnecessary and chose not to file for patents.5 In 1990, Microsoft had seven utility patents.6 Cisco © 2015 James M. Rice. † J.D. Candidate, 2016, University of California, Berkeley, School of Law. 1. Naveen Jain, 10 Secrets of Becoming a Successful Entrepreneur, INC. (Aug. 13, 2012), http://www.inc.com/naveen-jain/10-secrets-of-becoming-a-successful- entrepreneur.html.
    [Show full text]
  • Spreading Green Iot Tech Through Mechanisms of Sharing Intellectual Property Master’S Thesis in Entrepreneurship and Business Design
    Spreading green IoT tech through mechanisms of sharing intellectual property Master’s thesis in Entrepreneurship and Business Design ISAK LIND RASMUS KOCKGÅRD DEPARTMENT OF TECHNOLOGY MANAGEMENT AND ECONOMICS DIVISION OF ENTREPRENEURSHIP AND STRATEGY CHALMERS UNIVERSITY OF TECHNOLOGY Gothenburg, Sweden 2021 www.chalmers.se Report No. E2021:115 REPORT NO. E2021:115 Spreading green IoT tech through mechanisms of sharing intellectual property ISAK LIND RASMUS KOCKGÅRD Department of Technology Management and Economics Division of Entrepreneurship and Strategy CHALMERS UNIVERSITY OF TECHNOLOGY Göteborg, Sweden 2021 Spreading green IoT tech through mechanisms of sharing intellectual property ISAK LIND RASMUS KOCKGÅRD © ISAK LIND © RASMUS KOCKGÅRD Technical report no E2021:115 Department of Technology Management and Economics Division of Entrepreneurship and Strategy Chalmers University of Technology SE-412 96 Göteborg Sweden Telephone + 46 (0)31-772 1000 Göteborg, Sweden 2021 Acknowledgements This master’s thesis is a part of the last semester of the Master of Science program in Entrepreneurship and Business Design at Chalmers University of Technology in Gothenburg. We would like to send our gratitude towards our supervisors at Chalmers University of Technology, Mats Lundqvist and Christoffer Hermansson. It has both been a challenging and inspiring process writing our thesis. Thank you for your guidance and all the interesting conversations we have had. We would also like to send our gratitude towards Ericsson AB, and all the employees who have taken the time to answer our questions. We are especially grateful towards our supervisors Mathias Hellman and Sanna Lundin. Thank you for all the learnings provided, the assistance in finalizing our thesis, and thank you for all the interesting discussions we have had.
    [Show full text]
  • Puzzles of the Zero-Rate Royalty
    Fordham Intellectual Property, Media and Entertainment Law Journal Volume 27 Volume XXVII Number 1 Article 1 2016 Puzzles of the Zero-Rate Royalty Eli Greenbaum Yigal Arnon & Co., [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://ir.lawnet.fordham.edu/iplj Part of the Intellectual Property Law Commons Recommended Citation Eli Greenbaum, Puzzles of the Zero-Rate Royalty, 27 Fordham Intell. Prop. Media & Ent. L.J. 1 (2016). Available at: https://ir.lawnet.fordham.edu/iplj/vol27/iss1/1 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by FLASH: The Fordham Law Archive of Scholarship and History. It has been accepted for inclusion in Fordham Intellectual Property, Media and Entertainment Law Journal by an authorized editor of FLASH: The Fordham Law Archive of Scholarship and History. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Puzzles of the Zero-Rate Royalty Cover Page Footnote Partner, Yigal Arnon & Co. J.D., Yale Law School; M.S., Columbia University. This article is available in Fordham Intellectual Property, Media and Entertainment Law Journal: https://ir.lawnet.fordham.edu/iplj/vol27/iss1/1 Puzzles of the Zero-Rate Royalty Eli Greenbaum* Patentees increasingly exploit their intellectual property rights through royalty-free licensing arrangements. Even though patentees us- ing such frameworks forfeit their right to trade patents for monetary gain, royalty-free arrangements can be used to pursue other significant commercial and collaborative interests. This Article argues that modern royalty-free structures generate tension between various otherwise well- accepted doctrines of patent remedies law that were designed for more traditional licensing models.
    [Show full text]
  • Sustainability 2010, 2, 993-1015; Doi:10.3390/Su2040993 OPEN ACCESS Sustainability ISSN 2071-1050
    Sustainability 2010, 2, 993-1015; doi:10.3390/su2040993 OPEN ACCESS sustainability ISSN 2071-1050 www.mdpi.com/journal/sustainability Article Science, Open Communication and Sustainable Development John T. Wilbanks 1 and Thomas J. Wilbanks 2,* 1 Science Commons, c/o Creative Commons, 71 Second Street, Suite 300, San Francisco, CA 94105, USA; E-Mail: [email protected] 2 Oak Ridge National Laboratory, P.O. Box 2008, MS-6038, Oak Ridge, TN 37831, USA * Author to whom correspondence should be addressed; E-Mail: [email protected]; Tel.: +1-865-574-5515; Fax: +1-865-576-2943. Received: 1 February 2010; in revised form: 19 March 2010 / Accepted: 22 March 2010 / Published: 13 April 2010 Abstract: One of the prerequisites for sustainable development is knowledge, in order to inform coping with sustainability threats and to support innovative sustainability pathways. Transferring knowledge is therefore a fundamental challenge for sustainability, in a context where external knowledge must be integrated with local knowledge in order to promote user-driven action. But effective local co-production of knowledge requires ongoing local access to existing scientific and technical knowledge so that users start on a level playing field. The information technology revolution can be a powerful enabler of such access if intellectual property obstacles can be overcome, with a potential to transform prospects for sustainability in many parts of the world. Keywords: knowledge for sustainability; co-production of knowledge for sustainability; information technology; open access 1. Introduction Sustainable development across the regions, systems, and populations of this world is a path, not a state [1]. The challenges to sustainability evolve constantly, as changes in conditions and driving forces emerge with little notice.
    [Show full text]
  • THE DEFENSIVE PATENT PLAYBOOK James M
    THE DEFENSIVE PATENT PLAYBOOK James M. Rice† Billionaire entrepreneur Naveen Jain wrote that “[s]uccess doesn’t necessarily come from breakthrough innovation but from flawless execution. A great strategy alone won’t win a game or a battle; the win comes from basic blocking and tackling.”1 Companies with innovative ideas must execute patent strategies effectively to navigate the current patent landscape. But in order to develop a defensive strategy, practitioners must appreciate the development of the defensive patent playbook. Article 1, Section 8, Clause 8 of the U.S. Constitution grants Congress the power to “promote the Progress of Science and useful Arts, by securing for limited Times to Authors and Inventors the exclusive Right to their respective Writings and Discoveries.”2 Congress attempts to promote technological progress by granting patent rights to inventors. Under the utilitarian theory of patent law, patent rights create economic incentives for inventors by providing exclusivity in exchange for public disclosure of technology.3 The exclusive right to make, use, import, and sell a technology incentivizes innovation by enabling inventors to recoup the costs of development and secure profits in the market.4 Despite the conventional theory, in the 1980s and early 1990s, numerous technology companies viewed patents as unnecessary and chose not to file for patents.5 In 1990, Microsoft had seven utility patents.6 Cisco © 2015 James M. Rice. † J.D. Candidate, 2016, University of California, Berkeley, School of Law. 1. Naveen Jain, 10 Secrets of Becoming a Successful Entrepreneur, INC. (Aug. 13, 2012), http://www.inc.com/naveen-jain/10-secrets-of-becoming-a-successful- entrepreneur.html.
    [Show full text]
  • Patent Licenses: Key Provisions
    Patent Licenses: Key Provisions Go to: Framing the License Agreement | Identifying Patents Subject to the License | The Patent License Grant Clause | Exclusive vs. Non-exclusive Patent Licenses | Rights Granted to a Patent Licensee | Patent License Payment & Royalty Provisions | Representations and Warranties in Patent Licenses | Patent License Provisions That Protect Against Risk and Govern Future Disputes | Term & Termination of Patent Licenses | Assignability of Patent Licenses Current as of: 09/10/2019 by Michael J. Kasdan, Wiggin and Dana LLP This practice note details the key patent license agreement provisions and terms, namely: 1 Framing the License Agreement 2 Identifying Patents Subject to the License 3 The Patent License Grant Clause 4 Exclusive vs. Non-exclusive Patent Licenses 5 Rights Granted to a Patent Licensee 6 Patent License Payment & Royalty Provisions 7 Representations and Warranties in Patent Licenses 8 Patent License Provisions That Protect Against Risk and Govern Future Disputes 9 Term & Termination of Patent Licenses 10 Assignability of Patent Licenses Framing the License Agreement Identifying the Parties Typically the opening paragraph of a license agreement states the parties to the agreement, as well its effective date. The parties should provide the complete legal name of each entity, as well as its place of incorporation and the address of its principal places of business. The identification of the parties to the agreement serves the obvious purpose of identifying each side of the transaction, both licensor and licensee, thus identifying the specific entities making the promises and receiving the benefits set forth in the agreement. Additional identifying details help to avoid potential confusion over other entities with similar names and to provide a basis for determining parent companies, subsidiaries, and related corporate entities.
    [Show full text]
  • Free and Open Source Software Licensing
    Anna Haapanen FREE AND OPEN SOURCE SOFTWARE LICENSING AND THE MYSTERY OF LICENSOR'S PATENTS Haapanen, Anna: Free and Open Source Software Licensing and the Mystery of Licensor's Patents Anna Haapanen FREE AND OPEN SOURCE SOFTWARE LICENSING and the Mystery of Licensor's Patents Doctoral dissertation to be presented for public examination, by due permission of the Faculty of Law at the University of Helsinki, in Porthania Hall III on April 1, 2017 at 10 a.m. 1 Haapanen, Anna: Free and Open Source Software Licensing and the Mystery of Licensor's Patents Contents ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS ............................................................................................ 4 ABSTRACT ..................................................................................................................... 5 1. INTRODUCTION .................................................................................................. 6 1.1 BACKGROUND ............................................................................................ 6 1.1.1 Concepts .......................................................................................... 6 1.1.2 Brief History of FOSS ..................................................................... 12 1.1.3 FOSS Today .................................................................................... 14 1.1.4 Construction of FOSS Licenses ...................................................... 16 1.1.5 FOSS and Patents ........................................................................... 22 1.1.6 Current Status
    [Show full text]
  • Intellectual Property Pools and Aggregation
    SJ Quinney College of Law, University of Utah Utah Law Digital Commons Utah Law Faculty Scholarship Utah Law Scholarship 10-2020 Intellectual Property Pools and Aggregation Jorge L. Contreras Follow this and additional works at: https://dc.law.utah.edu/scholarship Part of the Intellectual Property Law Commons Contreras IP Licensing and Transactions Chapter 27 CHAPTER 27 – INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY POOLS AND AGGREGATION Summary Contents A. Theories of IP Pooling: Efficiency and Enablement B. Antitrust Analysis of Patent Pools Standard Oil (Indiana) v. United States U.S. Dept. Justice & Fed. Trade Comm’n Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property C. Standards Patent Pools U.S. Dept. Justice MPEG-2 Business Review Letter D. Complementarity and Essentiality in Patent Pools U.S. Dept. Justice 3GPP Business Review Letter As we saw in Chapter 25, agreements among competitors that restrain trade can violate Section 1 of the Sherman Act. Such anticompetitive agreements can involve trademarks, copyrights, patents and other intellectual property rights. If they seek to fix prices, allocate markets or impose similar restraints on competition, such agreements are per se illegal; otherwise they are evaluated under the rule of reason, balancing their pro-competitive and anticompetitive effects. In this chapter, we will consider an important category of agreements among competitors – those in which intellectual property rights are combined or “pooled” for various purposes. The first documented patent pool in the U.S. was formed in 1856 by three leading manufacturers of sewing machines.1 Since then, IP pools have evolved and The crux of an IP pooling grown in complexity.
    [Show full text]
  • The Non-Discrimination Principle in Open Source Licensing
    GREENBAUM.37.4.4 (Do Not Delete) 4/3/2016 1:48 PM THE NON-DISCRIMINATION PRINCIPLE IN OPEN SOURCE LICENSING Eli Greenbaum† Open source communities have required licenses to satisfy requirements of non-discrimination. This principle of non-discrimination, however, has remained peripheral to the interpretation of open source licenses, with legal analysis concentrating on other aspects of open source regimes. This Article argues that non- discrimination, far from being marginal to open source, constitutes the central legal characteristic of the licensing model, and that an appreciation of the non- discrimination requirement is essential for understanding the economic incentives and effects of the open source license. This Article applies this understanding of the non-discrimination principle to interpret specific terms in free and open source licenses. In a number of instances, the interpretation consistent with the non- discrimination principle stands in contrast to generally accepted understandings of specific license provisions. TABLE OF CONTENTS INTRODUCTION .............................................................................................................. 1298 I. DEBIAN AND THE DEFINITIONS ............................................................................. 1302 A. History of the Non-Discrimination Principle .......................................... 1302 B. Interpretive Potential ................................................................................. 1306 C. In the Licenses ............................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Strategic Patent Acquisitions
    STRATEGIC PATENT ACQUISITIONS FIONA M. SCOTT MORTON CARL SHAPIRO* In recent years, we have seen a dramatic upsurge of “strategic patent acqui- sitions.” We define this as the acquisition of a portfolio of patents reading on a specified area such as flash memory, biosensors, database management, or wireless digital messaging, which may be asserted against “target products” in that area. In this article, we examine the economic effects of strategic patent acquisitions and discuss their antitrust implications. Antitrust attorneys and economists regularly study the economic effects of one species of asset acquisitions, namely mergers and acquisitions, that typi- cally involve the transfer of an entire line of business from one party to an- other. Our analysis has much in common with merger analysis: we study how a strategic patent acquisition changes economic incentives and trace through the likely economic effects of those changed incentives. Antitrust has long been interested in the implications of transactions involv- ing the transfer of assets from one party to another, including mergers. In today’s economy, where intellectual property is often the key source of com- petitive advantage, antitrust issues naturally and commonly arise when patents are transferred from one party to another. Some of the economic effects of patent acquisitions—such as enhancing market power by consolidating own- ership of substitute technologies—are familiar but appear with new twists. Others—such as evading a commitment to license on reasonable terms, or removing the ability of a patent defendant to counterattack—are more novel. These effects are amenable to economic analysis. * Fiona Scott Morton is Professor of Economics, Yale University School of Management, and is an NBER Research Associate; Carl Shapiro is the Transamerica Professor of Business Strategy at the Haas School of Business and Professor of Economics, University of California, Berkeley.
    [Show full text]
  • CIFRA: Challenging the ICT Patent Framework for Responsible Innovation
    Ref. Ares(2017)3832329 - 31/07/2017 Grant Agreement No.731940 Research and Innovation Action Call: H2020-ICT-35-2016 CIFRA: Challenging the ICT Patent Framework for Responsible Innovation D3.1: Report on potential new framings, identifying needs for changing the current IPR regime relevant for ICT industries Revision 31.7.2017 Work Package WP3 Task 3.1 Dissemination Level PU - Public Deliverable Lead Telefónica Investigación y Desarrollo (TID) Authors Antonio López-Carrasco (Telefónica) Eduardo Fullea (Telefónica) Blind Knut (Fraunhofer) Esmeralda Florez Ramos (Fraunhofer) Andrea Fosfuri (Bocconi&CRIOS) Ester Martínez (UC3M) Silvana Álvarez (UC3M) Disclaimer The information, documentation and figures available in this deliverable, is written by the CIFRA project consortium under EC grant agreement Grant Agreement No.731940 and does not necessarily reflect the views of the European Commission. The European Commission is not liable for any use that may be made of the information contained herein. Copyright notice© 2017 CIFRA Consortium © CIFRA Consortium 2017 Page 2 of 39 INDEX 1 Introduction ........................................................................................................................ 4 2 Proposed solutions to the fragmentation with a special focus on ICT .............................. 4 2.1 Strict novelty requirement .......................................................................................... 5 2.2 Higher fees .................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]