John Maynard Keynes Volume One: Hopes Betrayed 1883 – 1920

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

John Maynard Keynes Volume One: Hopes Betrayed 1883 – 1920 John Maynard Keynes Volume One: Hopes Betrayed 1883 – 1920 By Robert Skidelsky Summarized by Jay Lotz somebookblog.wordpress.com SomeBookBlog Chapter One: Dynastic Origins John Neville Keynes, Maynard’s father, was born on August 31, 1852. His father, Maynard’s grandfather, John Keynes, born in 1805, was a successful, self-made businessman who made his fortune on flowers. John Keynes’s nurseries were in Salisbury, where Neville lived with his father, mother, and aunt and grandmother from his father’s side. The family was Nonconformist—that is, Protestants who did conform to the practices established by the Church of England—and John Keynes believed his success was due to his religious discipline. A man without education, he recognized Neville’s intelligence, and set him off on a path to escape the trades through education, paying £70 per year to send Neville to Amersham Hall in 1864. Neville made good marks in classics, but showed particular ability for mathematics. He was awarded a Gilchrist scholarship to University College, London, in 1869. Apart from his studies, Neville devoted considerable time to hobbies, including chess, collecting stamps, and going to the theater. Neville obtained his B.A. in 1871. In June 1872, Neville won the first mathematical scholarship to Pembroke College, a constituent of Cambridge University. Soon after arriving, however, Neville realized he was in the wrong subject. By October of that year, Neville was writing his parents, asking permission to leave Cambridge. A man given to anxiety, and always beset by headaches and toothaches, Neville’s nerves seemed to be getting the better of him. Under the influence of his parents and his college tutor, Neville decided to stick with mathematics through the end of his first year, in May. Not liking it any better, Neville would give up mathematics in favor of moral sciences, a relatively new field of study. He would do so at considerable risk to his career. In those days, fellowships were awarded primarily to those studying mathematics and the classics. Fortunately for Neville, conditions in the University system were just beginning to shift in his favor. As an age of industrialism, increased secularism, and democracy took hold, many promising students were moving over to the moral sciences to study moral and political philosophy, psychology, and economics. The moral science tradition that Maynard Keynes would take part and thrive in was just being established. Neville worked hard at Cambridge, as he had at London, and in 1875 was declared Senior Moralist, having placed first in his class of the moral science tripos. In August 1876, Neville was elected a Fellow of Pembroke. It was a great accomplishment, one that in previous times would have guaranteed him a position for life. But the old fellowship system was at this time coming under attack from University reformers. Parliament instituted reforms of college statutes. One change they made was fortunate for Neville; the Parliament removed the celibacy requirement for the tenure of a fellowship. Another reform, however, limited the tenure of certain fellowships—like the one Neville had earned—to just six years. Neville had the choice of keeping his fellowship 1 SomeBookBlog indefinitely and remaining celibate under the old statutes, or marrying and giving up his fellowship in 1882. Under the influence of Alfred Marshall, Neville chose to specialize in economics. But Neville would fail to produce any meaningful work during his tenure. With help from Marshall, he wrote an essay on the effects of machinery on wages, but the essay failed to win the hoped-for prize. A plan to write an economics textbook was vetoed by Marshall, who was protective of the material Neville learned from his lectures, and would take the project on himself. Apart from these unsuccessful or aborted projects, Neville contributed some useful criticism to the works of some of his colleagues, and taught logic at the two new women’s colleges at Cambridge—Girton and Newnham. It was at Newnham that Neville would encounter the seventeen year old Florence Ada Brown. In 1880, Neville made his choice, and proposed. Florence Ada Brown was born on March 10, 1861, the eldest daughter of John Brown, and Ada Haydon Ford. Soon after her birth, the family moved to Bedford where her father, a Nonconformist preacher, got work as a Minister. In Bedford, five more children would be added to the family. Unlike Neville, Florence descended from men and women, on both sides of the family, who pursued literary, political, and theological interests. Florence’s mother, Ada Haydon Ford, ran a school, as did her mother before her. Thus Florence was encouraged towards education from an early age, and entered Newnham in the first decade of that college’s existence. Then, women could sit for the tripos only unofficially, on the initiative of the lecturer. They were allowed to do so officially starting in 1881, but not until 1947 were they allowed to take their degrees. Florence, despite her ambition, would not sit for the tripos, even unofficially. In her later life, however, she would become a well known figure in Cambridge life, participating in all manner of social and public movements. After meeting Neville in 1879 an accepting his proposal a year later, Florence would channel her ambitions into her husband. Neville, however, was not as ambitious for himself as Florence hoped. After their marriage in August 1882—scheduled to coincide with the end of Neville’s fellowship—Neville accepted a job within the Cambridge administration, rather than pursue a professorship. Between his salary from the administrative job and a considerable inheritance from his father, who died in 1878, Neville was able to provide a comfortable, upper middle class lifestyle for his family. In the first year of their marriage the couple moved into a new, four-story house, in Cambridge. Florence would eventually shift her ambitions for her husband to their children. The couple’s first child would come soon after their marriage, on June 5, 1883. Neville wrote to his father-in-law John Brown that the child’s name would be John Maynard Keynes. John Brown wrote back: “John Maynard Keynes sounds like the substantial name of the solid hero of a sensible novel.” 2 SomeBookBlog Chapter Two: Cambridge Civilization: Sidgwick and Marshall John Maynard Keynes was a product of Cambridge, an inheritor of its intellectual traditions, and schisms. Two figures in particular, who illustrate these tensions, are of great importance to the environment Keynes would grow up in. One was Henry Sidgwick, a moral philosopher of the utilitarian school, the other Alfred Marshall, an economist. Both taught for the Moral Sciences Tripos, and were teachers and then colleagues of John Neville Keynes. The two took very different approaches to resolving the crisis in authority roiling the intellectual landscape of the late Victorian era. The 1860’s were a tumultuous time for English intellectuals. Darwin’s Origin of Species, published in 1859, combined with the influence of the Second Reform Act of 1867, which doubled the number of enfranchised men in England, plunged the old relationship between individual conduct and social order into a crisis. The intellectual class, robbed of their faith, rushed to provide a secular philosophy that would serve as a basis for moral individual behavior and societal structure. Moral philosophy offered two traditions where answers could be sought: Intuitionism and Utilitarianism. Intuitionism focused on motives, a code of behavior that was right or wrong regardless of the results it might bring. Utilitarianism focused on consequences, the attainment of good results, good being defined as, in the Benthamite or hedonist version, increasing human happiness. Utilitarianists often view Intuitionism as a intellectually lazy way of justifying current practices without subjecting them to rational thought. Intuitionists believed Utilitarianism would pave the way for a violent disruption of society. Eventually, in the field of social structure, a compromise was reached: Intuitionists admitted that utility had to be considered in the final test of any conduct, Utilitarianists admitted that many existing social arrangements had some utility after all. Utilitarianism won the day in the field of social philosophy, but the difficulties came in deciding the relationship between social and individual conduct. When it came to individual conduct, how could one sacrifice the hedonistic call of ‘wine, women, and song,’ as Mill had put it, to social duty? Mill believed that cultivating the ‘higher pleasures’ would provide men with altruistic motives. But under Hedonism, it was simply impossible to prefer some, less pleasant, pleasures over some, more pleasant, pleasures. Mill could not solve the problem; Henry Sidgwick would try to succeed where Mill failed. As Maynard Keynes would write in 1906, Sidgwick “never did anything but wonder whether Christianity was true and prove that it wasn’t and hope that is was.” The son of an Anglican clergyman, Sidgwick was more troubled by his society’s—and his own—loss of faith than many of his fellow skeptics. He wrote in 1881: 3 SomeBookBlog While I cannot myself discover adequate rational basis for the Christian hope of happy immortality, it seems to me that the general loss of such a hope… would be an evil of which I cannot pretend to measure the extent. Sidgwick could not find a way to reconcile the public and private except through a religious faith. How could an individual subordinate their own happiness to the call of duty, without the prospect of heavenly reward? Sidgwick believed that certain behaviors and dispositions were inherently valuable, but struggled all his life to provide a utilitarian basis for these behaviors and dispositions—to substitute results pleasing to man for results pleasing to God.
Recommended publications
  • MODES for Windows Print
    Marshall Library of Economics J.N. Keynes Papers Sections 2 - 5 Identity code JNKeynes 2/1 Previous number Keynes 3(37-48) Description level 4 Record creation Date 8.6.1951 (postmark) Place Document form Record type Correspondence Specific type Envelope Language English Acquisition Summary Deposited by Mrs. J.N. [Florence Ada] Keynes Content Summary Envelope addressed to Mrs. F.A. Keynes, J.P., but address crossed out. Annotated in ink, in Mrs. Keynes's hand, "Letters in reference to 'Formal Logic' by J.N.K." Once contained letters now numbered JNKeynes 2/2 - 2/13. Free field Subject keywords JNKeynes - Studies and Exercises in Formal Logic Physical descript Summary Brown manila envelope, 229 mm x 151 mm Condition Somewhat creased; small tear and small red stain on reverse Identity code JNKeynes 2/2 Previous number Keynes 3(38) Description level 4 Record creation Person Role Writer Name Bryant, Sophie Descriptor Doctor of Science, Moral Science branch, London University Person Role Recipient Name Keynes, John Neville Descriptor Lecturer in Moral Science, Cambridge University Date 10.4.1884 Place London, N., 2 Anson Road Document form Record type Correspondence Specific type Letter Language English Acquisition Summary Deposited by Mrs. J.N. [Florence Ada] Keynes Content Summary Thanks Keynes for sending her copy of ['Studies and Exercises in] Formal Logic'. Compliments him on methodology. Subject keywords JNKeynes - Studies and Exercises in Formal Logic Physical descript Summary 1 sheet; 3 pp. text Condition Sound Publication record Type Reference Identity code JNKeynes 2/3 Previous number Keynes 3(37) Description level 4 Record creation Person Role Writer Name d'Alfonso, Nicolo Descriptor Professor of Philosophy Person Role Recipient Name Keynes, John Neville Descriptor Lecturer in Moral Science, Cambridge University Date 5.6.1886 Place Italy, Santa Severina di Calabria Document form Record type Correspondence Specific type Letter Language French Acquisition Summary Deposited by Mrs.
    [Show full text]
  • Economics 390S.03 Keynes in Context Syllabus: Spring 2013 Professor E. Roy Weintraub Office: Social Sciences 07D; Phone (And
    Economics 390S.03 Keynes in Context Syllabus: Spring 2013 Professor E. Roy Weintraub Office: Social Sciences 07D; Phone (and voice mail): 660-1838; E-mail: [email protected] This seminar will examine the life and work of one of the most important figures of the twentieth century, John Maynard Keynes. The context of the development of Keynes's thought in late Victorian Cambridge, and the influence of Moore and the Apostles, and Alfred Marshall, sets the stage for an examination of Keynes's emerging role as government advisor, journalist, teacher, and economist. The seminar will study, in addition to his economic writings, his connections to the Bloomsbury Group and his non-economic writings, both political and biographical. The emergent focus will be Keynes's influential General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, its intellectual background, and its consequences. Each student should purchase the single volume paperback abridgement (of his three volume biography of Keynes) by Lord Robert Skidelsky titled John Maynard Keynes 1883-1946: Economist, Statesman, Philosopher. There are additional readings from Keynes’s book Essays in Persuasion (paperback), which is also available at the Duke bookstore. Students should also purchase Skidelsky’s 2009 paperback (or Kindle) book Keynes: The Return of the Master or Skidelsky’s and Skidelsky’s 2012 paperback (or Kindle) book How Much Is Enough? Other readings will be linked at the Course Materials section on the course’s Sakai site. The class will meet twice a week. Each class will be organized as a discussion about the weekly readings. Generally the first class in the week will discuss the Skidelsky reading, while the second class will discuss the other reading for that week.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 John Neville Keynes Heinrich Bortis
    1 John Neville Keynes Heinrich Bortis John Neville Keynes (1852–1949) has, in association with Alfred Marshall and his son John Maynard, decisively shaped the development of economic theory from the late nineteenth century to the early twenty-first century. He started lecturing on formal logic at Pembroke College (Cambridge) in the 1870s (Deane 2001, ch. 3),1 became a university lecturer in his preferred subject, political economy, within the framework of the moral sciences (ch. 5). The return of Alfred Marshall as professor of political economy severely limited his possibilities in this field and confined his teaching of political economy to an elementary course for Indian Civil Service candidates (Deane 1987). Given this, he increasingly turned to academic administration where he was associated with the reform of the moral sciences tripos 1885–97 and the creation of an economics tripos 1897–1908 (Deane 2001, ch. 8) to finally occupy the top bureaucratic post, University Registrar, from 1910 to 1925 (ch. 7). Let us now consider Neville Keynes’s activities and assess, in a final section, the results of his direct and indirect influence on the development of economic theory. LECTURING AND WRITING ON FORMAL LOGIC Neville Keynes was not a charismatic lecturer. However, students ‘found his methodi- cal, clearheaded approach to formal logic particularly helpful when preparing for examinations. They were often explicitly grateful for the time and effort he put into giving advice and detailed explanations’ (Deane 2001, p. 115). In mid-1883 he felt sufficiently in control of his material on formal logic to write a students’ manual which was published as Studies and Exercises on Formal Logic early in 1884.
    [Show full text]
  • Alphabet B Ooks Book Beautiful Cambridge Dodgson
    a l phabet b ooks the b ook beautiful ambridge c odgson d from the library of christopher hogwood BERNARD QUARITCH LTD 40 SOUTH AUDLEY STREET, LONDON W1K 2PR +44 (0)20 7297 4888 [email protected] www.quaritch.com For enquiries about this catalogue, please contact: Anke Timmermann ([email protected]) or Mark James ([email protected]) Bankers: Barclays Bank PLC, 1 Churchill Place, London E14 5HP Sort code: 20-65-82 Swift code: BARCGB22 Sterling account IBAN: GB98 BARC 206582 10511722 Euro account IBAN: GB30 BARC 206582 45447011 US Dollar account IBAN: GB46 BARC 206582 63992444 Mastercard, Visa and American Express accepted. VAT number: GB 840 1358 54 Cheques should be made payable to: Bernard Quaritch Limited. List 2016/17 © Bernard Quaritch Ltd 2016 christopher hogwood cbe (1941- 0114 Throughout his 50-year career, conductor, musicologist and keyboard player Christopher Hogwood applied his synthesis of scholarship and performance with enormous artistic and popular success. Spearheading the movement that became known as ‘historically-informed performance’, he promoted it to the mainstream through his work on 17th- and 18th-century repertoire with the Academy of Ancient Music, and went on to apply its principles to music of all periods with the world’s leading symphony orchestras and opera houses. His editions of music were published by the major international houses, and in his writings, lectures and broadcasts he was admired equally for his intellectual rigour and his accessible presentation. Born in Notingham, Christopher was educated at Notingham High School, The Skinners' School, Royal Tunbridge Wells, and Pembroke College, University of Cambridge, where he read Classics and Music.
    [Show full text]
  • Keynes on Judgment, Moral Science, and the Civilization of The
    Journal of Markets & Morality Volume 20, Number 1 (Spring 2017): 69–78 Copyright © 2017 Keynes on Judgment, Moral Science, and the Civilization Ross B. Emmett James Madison College of the Few Michigan State University The irony is that, for so long, Keynes has been portrayed as a positivist who promoted the political and scientific neutrality of economics. Yet he was neither a positivist nor a socialist. He stood for the principle of a just and wisely managed economy, directed toward an ethical ideal “with intellect and feelings in tune.” —Athol Fitzgibbons1 [Keynes] concluded that civilization was a precarious crust erected by the personality and will of a very few. —John Toye2 Introduction In his 1924 Ball Lecture at Oxford, Maynard Keynes announced that, finally, the end of laissez-faire was close at hand: “For more than a hundred years our philosophers ruled us because, by a miracle, they nearly all agreed or seemed to agree on this one thing [i.e., laissez-faire]. We do not dance even yet to a new tune. But a change is in the air.”3 The General Theory4 was still more than a decade away; indeed, A Tract on Monetary Reform5 and its extended version, A Treatise on Money,6 had seemed to confirm Keynes’s place in the laissez-faire- oriented Cambridge tradition. Yet Keynes was already prepared to turn away from the classical tradition of Smith, Mill, Marshall, and Pigou and champion the end of laissez-faire. 69 Ross B. Emmett Employing the tactic of quoting those he opposed, Keynes went on in his 1924 lecture to reference Jeremy Bentham:
    [Show full text]
  • Plumbers, Designers, Or Dentists? a Triad of Metaphors and How They Reflect the Current Debate on the Role and Scope of Economists in Society and Science Felix A
    1 Plumbers, designers, or dentists? A triad of metaphors and how they reflect the current debate on the role and scope of economists in society and science Felix A. Dörstelmann1 Abstract The discussion on the role of economists is characterised by metaphors, which range from plumber to designer to dentist. This paper aims to clarify the meaning of these metaphors for applied economists. To this end, the source of theses metaphors, which is located in John Neville Keynes’ conception of the art of economics, is examined. In this context, it is argued that a return to John Neville Keynes’ tripartite systematisation of economics, namely positive, normative, and art of economics, can provide both structure and framework for the demands for theoretical-methodological complementarity, application orientation, and transparent values in economics. Through the synthesis of Kant's sensus communis with Keynes' tripartite systematisation of the economics, interdependencies between the three sub-areas are discussed. A central finding of this synthesis is that the disclosure of normative aspects in economics is necessary in order to establish intersubjectivity and thus create the conditions for an open discourse, which ultimately increases the resilience of economic analysis. Keywords: Keynes, Kant, applied economics, history of economic thought, systematisation of economics. JEL Classification Codes: A10, A11, B10, B20. 1. Introduction What are economists: philosophers, plumbers, designers, or even dentists? The wide variety of metaphors shows that answers to this question are multifaceted. The question also arises what these metaphors stand for. The answer to this is directly related to the debate on the role and scope of economists in society and science.
    [Show full text]
  • In Her Own Words: Works by Exceptional Women
    london Peter Harrington ININ HERHER OWN WORDS WORKS BY EXCEPTIONAL WOMEN ur first catalogue focussed on women spans the Others have been overlooked despite brilliant contributions Ocenturies from Sappho to Maya Angelou, showcasing the to their fields. Early works by Joan Robinson (122 and 123) and work of exceptional women in many different fields. Rosa Luxemburg (96) are well-known to economists, but less These were women who pushed legal, intellectual, and well-known are those by Helen Makower (97) and S. F. Porter physical boundaries. Millicent Fawcett Garrett signed our (118). Rosalind Franklin and Jocelyn Bell were both denied copy of Women’s Victory in July 1928, the same month the Equal Nobel prizes, despite playing crucial roles in the discovery of the Franchise Act gave British women electoral equality with men structure of DNA and radio pulsars respectively (70 and 22). In (item 66). Maria Gaetana Agnesi’s Analytical Institutions is the the suffrage movement, the works of Christabel (109) and Sylvia first advanced mathematics book by a woman (1). Trailblazers Pankhurst (110) sit alongside work by their exiled sister, Adela such as Fanny Parks, “characterized by remarkable physical (108), comparatively overlooked, yet no less fierce a Pankhurst stamina” (112), Amelia Edwards, who carried out the first for it. general archaeological survey of Egypt’s ruins (60), and Lady Within the catalogue, works on paper appear alongside items Hester Stanhope, “Queen of the Desert” (144), cleared the way in different media. Amelia Earhart’s Fun of It, inscribed (59), for later intrepid travellers such as Gertrude Bell (21) and Freya complements the pearl carried on the maiden voyage of the Stark (145).
    [Show full text]
  • 1 John Neville Keynes Heinrich Bortis
    1 John Neville Keynes Heinrich Bortis John Neville Keynes (1852–1949) has, in association with Alfred Marshall and his son John Maynard, decisively shaped the development of economic theory from the late nineteenth century to the early twenty-first century. He started lecturing on formal logic at Pembroke College (Cambridge) in the 1870s (Deane 2001, ch. 3),1 became a university lecturer in his preferred subject, political economy, within the framework of the moral sciences (ch. 5). The return of Alfred Marshall as professor of political economy severely limited his possibilities in this field and confined his teaching of political economy to an elementary course for Indian Civil Service candidates (Deane 1987). Given this, he increasingly turned to academic administration where he was associated with the reform of the moral sciences tripos 1885–97 and the creation of an economics tripos 1897–1908 (Deane 2001, ch. 8) to finally occupy the top bureaucratic post, University Registrar, from 1910 to 1925 (ch. 7). Let us now consider Neville Keynes’s activities and assess, in a final section, the results of his direct and indirect influence on the development of economic theory. LECTURING AND WRITING ON FORMAL LOGIC Neville Keynes was not a charismatic lecturer. However, students ‘found his methodi- cal, clearheaded approach to formal logic particularly helpful when preparing for examinations. They were often explicitly grateful for the time and effort he put into giving advice and detailed explanations’ (Deane 2001, p. 115). In mid-1883 he felt sufficiently in control of his material on formal logic to write a students’ manual which was published as Studies and Exercises on Formal Logic early in 1884.
    [Show full text]
  • Lifelong Liberal John Maynard Keynes: Some Highlights from His Life
    LIFELONG LIBERAL JOHN MAYNARD KEYNES: SOME HIGHLIGHTS FROM HIS LIFE Erdal GÜMÜŞ* ABSTRACT History has witnessed many great individuals who have had unforgettable impact and great influences on societies that they may not last for centuries. Among these, doubtless to say, John Maynard Keynes was one of the most influenced social scientists. It is therefore the subject of this study to briefly examine his personal life from his birth and school years. This study shows that John Maynard Keynes life carries so many distinguished features that are to be invaluable examples for young economists and scientists. Key words: J. M. Keynes, Liberalism and Keynes, Keynes’s Personal Life, Keynes’s School Years. ÖZET Tarih, toplumlara büyük katkılar ve unutulmaz izler bırakan ve etkileri yüzyıllarca süren nice şahsiyetlere şahitlik etmektedir. Söz konusu şahıslar arasında şüphesiz sosyal bilimci olarak çok büyük izler bırakan John Maynard Keynes de gelmektedir. Dolayısıyla bu makelede onun doğumundan üniversite yıllarının sonuna kadar olan zaman dilimi içinde şahsi hayatı incelenmektedir. Bu çalışma, John Maynard Keynes’in hayatından genç economistlere ve bilim adamlarına örnek olabilecek çok çeşitli kesitlerin olduğunu göstermektedir. Anahtar Kelimeler: J. M. Keynes, Liberalizm ve Keynes, Keynes’in Şahsi hayatı, Keynes’in Okul Yılları. * Dr., Osmangazi Üniversitesi, Maliye Bölümü. 1. INTRODUCTION History has witnessed many great individuals who have had unforgettable impact and great influence. From ancient Greece to present time these individuals have played very significant roles for humanity. These roles were in the disciplines of religion, philosophy, physics, politics, economics and many other areas. Aristotle, Plato, Adam Smith, D. Ricardo, Marshall, J. S. Mill, J.
    [Show full text]
  • History of Economic Thought
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive Lifelong Liberal John Maynard Keynes: Some Highlights from His Life Gumus, Erdal Eskisehir Osmangazi University 2003 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/43351/ MPRA Paper No. 43351, posted 20 Dec 2012 22:48 UTC LIFELONG LIBERAL JOHN MAYNARD KEYNES: SOME HIGHLIGHTS FROM HIS LIFE Erdal Gümüş1 ABSTRACT History has witnessed many great individuals who have had unforgettable impact and great influences on societies that they may not last for centuries. Among these, doubtless to say, John Maynard Keynes was one of the most influenced social scientists. It is therefore the subject of this study to briefly examine his personal life from his birth and school years. This study shows that John Maynard Keynes life carries so many distinguished features that are to be invaluable examples for young economists and scientists. Key words: J. M. Keynes, Liberalism and Keynes, Keynes’s Personal Life, Keynes’s School Years. ÖZET Tarih, toplumlara büyük katkılar ve unutulmaz izler bırakan ve etkileri yüzyıllarca süren nice şahsiyetlere şahitlik etmektedir. Söz konusu şahıslar arasında şüphesiz sosyal bilimci olarak çok büyük izler bırakan John Maynard Keynes de gelmektedir. Dolayısıyla bu makelede onun doğumundan üniversite yıllarının sonuna kadar olan zaman dilimi içinde şahsi hayatı incelenmektedir. Bu çalışma, John Maynard Keynes’in hayatından genç economistlere ve bilim adamlarına örnek olabilecek çok çeşitli kesitlerin olduğunu göstermektedir. Anahtar Kelimeler: J. M. Keynes, Liberalizm ve Keynes, Keynes’in Şahsi hayatı, Keynes’in Okul Yılları. 1 Dr., Department of Public Finance, Osmangazi University, Eskişehir, Turkey. 1. INTRODUCTION History has witnessed many great individuals who have had unforgettable impact and great influence.
    [Show full text]
  • HETSA/5-8 July 2011 Why Did Keynes Promote Grace I in 1921? A
    HETSA/5-8 July 2011 Why did Keynes promote Grace I in 1921? A Cambridge University Officer’s Attitude towards Conferring Degrees on Women Atsushi KOMINE 20 June 2011 Provisional Version: 1.2 Section 1 Introduction Section 2 Three Steps in the Women’s Degrees Problem 2-1 Step 1: Total Failure 2-2 Step 2: Compromise Strategy 2-3 Step 3: Virtual Victory Section 3 Why did Keynes promote Grace I? Section 4 Concluding Remarks 4-1 Summary 4-2 Three Lessons Section 1 Introduction Broad studies of Keynes’s economic thought gathered momentum as the ‘Counter Revolution’ against him has strengthened since the 1970s. For, it was necessary to research his visions located deep in his rules of process (theories) in order to take seriously the lessons regarding contemporary economic difficulties. Harrod (1982[1951]), Milo Keynes (1979[1975]), or Patinkin & Leith (1977) had already revealed Keynes’s thought based on 1 the memories and testimony of his contemporaries. The Corrected Writings (1971-1989) further enabled deeper research on the basis of primary documents. The fruits of this research are ample; for example, Dostaler (2007), Hirai (2008) and four biographies 1. Among them, not a little research paid attention to Keynes on the side of practical man as well as theorist. Dostaler (2007: 2) regarded him as “a man of action as much as thought” and Nasu (1995: 3) argued that “the so called ‘Keynesian Revolution’ could not have happened without his wide experience as a man of affairs”. Skidelsky (2009: 56) summarized as follows: Keynes was also extremely practical.
    [Show full text]
  • Students Brief
    Students Brief JOHN MAYNARD KEYNES, 1883 - 1916 - THE MAN BEHIND THE NAME by R H Grieve, Department of Economics University of Strathclyde On the 5th June this year there falls the hundredth anniversary of the birth of John Maynard Keynes - Lord Keynes of Tilton - the greatest and most influential economist of this century. His is one of the few names of economists familiar to the general public. That this is so, nearly forty years after his death, is an indication of the enormous impact which his ideas have had on economic theory and policy. Since the publication in 1936 of his General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money a great part of the intellectual effort of the economics profession has been devoted to explaining, extending or attempting to escape from the interpretation of the working of the economic system presented in that work. In academic and in popular discussion of unemployment and inflation the epithet "Keynesian" is bandied about by theorists, journalists and politicians - applied sometimes as a term of commendation, sometimes as a term of abuse. The purpose of the present piece is to convey some impression - as it may be gleaned from his writings and from the memoirs of those who knew him - of the man behind the name. It is opportune to give thought to Keynes and to the nature of his contribution not simply because this happens to be his centenary year, but particularly because the social disaster of mass unemployment, to the elimination of which his energies were passionately committed, has again befallen the world economy.
    [Show full text]