Christopher T. Marsden London: Bloomsbury Academic, 2010, 320 Pp, £60, ISBN 978-1-84966-006-8 (Hbk)

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Christopher T. Marsden London: Bloomsbury Academic, 2010, 320 Pp, £60, ISBN 978-1-84966-006-8 (Hbk) BOOK REVIEW ‘NET NEUTRALITY: TOWARDS A CO-REGULATORY SOLUTION’ Christopher T. Marsden London: Bloomsbury Academic, 2010, 320 pp, £60, ISBN 978-1-84966-006-8 (hbk). Net neutrality, explains Christopher T. Marsden on the second page of this book, is about the rules of the road for Internet users, and about the relationship between the owners of those roads and the users. Government is asked to make a decision as to which users have priority and whether road charging should be introduced, ostensibly to build wider and faster roads in future. On 20 October 1999, the IDT Corporation, then a big a New Jersey based Internet service provider, blocked all email from the UK because some of its customers had received a large number of offensive unsolicited emails. These appeared to come from a UK address, but the spammer had actually exploited a security hole in a UK university system, making it appear as if the bulk emails were originating there. Just before Christmas 2004, Verizon reportedly 1 blacklisted and blocked email coming from IP addresses allocated to a collection of UK and European ISPs. IDT did not, allegedly, contact the University (of Leeds) before the action was taken. The blocking continued for several weeks. The response – to cut off a whole country - was a bit drastic, even if the emails had come from the UK. Given congestion on the network, traffic management is standard practice for ISPs everywhere, though there is a dearth of independent empirical research as to the extent, the precise pattern or the nature of such activity. We simply have no idea whether countrywide lockdowns or similar widespread filtering are commonplace or rare. I mention the IDT story in particular because it was in 1999 that Chris Marsden began his residential fellowship at Harvard Kennedy School, where the seed that was to grow into his excellent book, ‘ Net Neutrality: towards a co-regulatory solution ’, was planted. It was the beginning of 10 years of globe trotting research and engagement with a who’s who of the smartest minds in the business: legal and technical scholars, practitioners and cross disciplinary polymaths who helped to shape the author’s ideas on this complex but hugely important subject. The first and most important thing to say about this book is that it should be compulsory reading for policymakers everywhere. It manages to serve the dual purpose of being a primer on the subject for the general reader while also being an essential handbook for the specialist and the policymaker. Dr Marsden gets to the heart of the key issues of net neutrality: 1 J Gartner, “Verizon's E-Mail Embargo Enrages”, 1 October 2005, available at http://www.wired.com/techbiz/media/news/2005/01/66226 . SCRIPTed (2010) 7:3 579 • Network economics • Vertical integration and oligopolistic market evolution and concentration • Traffic management and quality of service • Civil rights – speech and privacy • Conflicting needs of the large spectrum of Net users • Regulators’ limitations • Intermediary liability • Commercial and political forces driving the internet towards a future of control • European law • The absence of individual Net user influence on policymakers • Co regulatory policy proposals And indeed many more. It is probably the single most comprehensive analysis of net neutrality you will find between the covers of a single volume. If I had one generic criticism of the book it is that the author does not provide enough detail in relation to the engineering and technology of networks. I think there is real value in regulators and policymakers understanding the difference between circuit and packet switching, for example, and this could avoid a lot of confusion. But I would say that, because I am an engineer. In conversation with the author, he pointed out to me that the literature on technology and engineering in this area is already rich, which is true, but it is unlikely to be perused by many non technical policymakers. That is, however, a minor criticism. Dr Marsden had no choice but to leave out vast swathes of material that he would no doubt have liked to have included – that is the nature of a monograph. Tom Standage, digital editor at The Economist magazine, recently criticised the concept of net neutrality as being ‘silly’ 2 and too vague – if you get three geeks in a room you will get four different definitions of the concept (which is probably true!) – and that thing that gets invoked by anyone complaining about something they dislike about the Internet. Geeks and consumer advocates have been arguing that the law should guarantee net neutrality, thereby disabling network operators’ power to engage in discriminatory practices. Mr Standage is concerned that attempts to write net neutrality into law on both sides of the Atlantic will just end up making matters worse. The Internet is not neutral now, and there are lots of things that we do not want to be neutral. For example, it is desirable that spam is blocked, or gamers might want superfast low latency broadband services that they would be prepared to pay extra for. The danger of saying that things must stay as they are is that you fossilise the Internet in its current state. A simplistic net neutrality law might just do that, making illegal a lot of useful things that are presently being done. So the best legislation in relation to net neutrality is none. I share the concerns of the author about the complexity and the dangers of getting it wrong. On the other hand, the vagueness and complexity of the concept and its multiple advocates is not necessarily a bad thing. Just as James Boyle has invoked the environment and environmentalism in his call to protect the public domain, perhaps net neutrality can serve a similar function in relation to the open Internet. After all, ‘environment’ is quite a vague term with many meanings, but it is also an articulation 2 BBC Radio 4, ‘Click On’, Monday 18 October 2010. SCRIPTed (2010) 7:3 580 of a shared interest that brings that interest into being. 3 The hunter and the animal rights activist may dislike each other intensely, but they have a shared interest in protecting the ecology and habitat of the animals they are interested in. In any case, you will not find any over-simplified, table-thumping advocacy in Chris Marsden’s book - of either the ‘cure it with net neutrality’ or ‘cure it with market forces’ variety. This is despite the fact that the introductory chapter begins with a quote from Barack Obama that concludes: “ We can’t have a situation in which the corporate duopoly dictates the future of the Internet and that’s why I’m supporting what is called net neutrality.” Dr Marsden, on the contrary, provides a comprehensive and pragmatic analysis of the state of net neutrality and its regulation and expects both free market fundamentalists and net neutrality purists to disagree with his suggested co-regulatory way forward. You get an idea of the scope of the book through the Introduction, which provides a whistle-stop tour of: net neutrality, network economics, European digital television regulation, interoperability, Microsoft litigation, Napster, Skype, mergers and acquisitions, EU telecoms liberalisation (and the variability in the effectiveness of national regulatory authorities in ensuring local loop competition), GERT (Group of European Regulators in Telecoms), 4 the 2001-2002 unravelling of the universal service commitment in the US, Machiavellian incumbent power games, the need to recognise broadband infrastructure as public works, the ruthless competition and government direction in Korea, the end to end principle, transparency failures, absence of empirical research, quality of service guarantees, 3G in Japan, traffic management, deep packet inspection, and the inevitability of discrimination where architecture permits it. All that and more – including a passionate assertion (with which I wholeheartedly agree 5) that the creation, operation and monitoring of open Internet policy is too important to be left to the experts, since it is about fundamental human rights and consumer welfare, necessitating a balanced approach to net neutrality – in an introduction, before he even outlines the structure of the book, leaves you in little doubt that although it is written in an accessible style, this is a tome that will require the full concentration of the reader. It is clear that net neutrality resides firmly in the realm of what Russel L Ackoff would have described as a ‘mess’, a collection of complex problems interacting with other complex problems and therefore part of a set of interrelated problems, or a system of problems. 6 It is important to point out that Dr Marsden distinguishes two separate non- discrimination commitments in net neutrality, something which itself would likely illicit gnashing of purists’ teeth. What he calls ‘net neutrality lite’ and something that 3 J Boyle, “The Second Enclosure Movement and the Construction of the Public Domain ” (2003) 66:33 Law and Contemporary Problems, 33 -74. 4 Note that between the editing and publication of the book the Group of European Regulators in Telecoms (GERT) was renamed the Body of European Regulators for Electronic Communications (BEREC). 5 R Corrigan, Digital Decision Making: Back to the Future (London: Springer-Verlag, 2007), at chapters 9 and 10. 6 RL Ackoff, Redesigning the Future: Systems Approach to Societal Problems (New York: John Wiley & Sons Inc, 1974). SCRIPTed (2010) 7:3 581 ultimately forms a central plank of his co-regulatory way forward, relates to ensuring that ISPs are not allowed to engage in opaque and discriminatory traffic management to the detriment of Internet users of any class. ‘Positive net neutrality’ on the other hand is about ensuring a balance whereby investment in future broadband infrastructure is not discouraged.
Recommended publications
  • Google—Do Not Pass Go, Do Not Collect $200: Why the Tech Giant Is a “Bad” Monopoly
    Hastings Law Journal Volume 71 Issue 3 Article 7 4-2020 Google—Do Not Pass Go, Do Not Collect $200: Why the Tech Giant Is a “Bad” Monopoly Alicia Ginsberg Follow this and additional works at: https://repository.uchastings.edu/hastings_law_journal Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Alicia Ginsberg, Google—Do Not Pass Go, Do Not Collect $200: Why the Tech Giant Is a “Bad” Monopoly, 71 HASTINGS L.J. 783 (2020). Available at: https://repository.uchastings.edu/hastings_law_journal/vol71/iss3/7 This Note is brought to you for free and open access by the Law Journals at UC Hastings Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Hastings Law Journal by an authorized editor of UC Hastings Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Notes Google—Do Not Pass Go, Do Not Collect $200: Why the Tech Giant Is a “Bad” Monopoly † ALICIA GINSBERG Congress enacted the Sherman Act in 1890 to promote competition and creativity in the marketplace. The Sherman Act prohibits agreements that restrain trade and lays out rules regarding monopoly power. This Note explores three distinct theories under which Google, one of the most successful technology companies in the world, could be found to have violated the Sherman Act. Specifically, in violation of Sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act, Google “ties” its products together and forces mobile device manufacturers to sign exclusive dealing agreements preventing them from purchasing products from Google’s competitors. Further, Google’s systematic obstruction of competing Android operating systems is a form of anticompetitive conduct in violation of Section 2 of the Sherman Act.
    [Show full text]
  • CHOICE – a NEW STANDARD for COMPETITION LAW ANALYSIS? a Choice — a New Standard for Competition Law Analysis?
    GO TO TABLE OF CONTENTS GO TO TABLE OF CONTENTS CHOICE – A NEW STANDARD FOR COMPETITION LAW ANALYSIS? a Choice — A New Standard for Competition Law Analysis? Editors Paul Nihoul Nicolas Charbit Elisa Ramundo Associate Editor Duy D. Pham © Concurrences Review, 2016 GO TO TABLE OF CONTENTS All rights reserved. No photocopying: copyright licenses do not apply. The information provided in this publication is general and may not apply in a specifc situation. Legal advice should always be sought before taking any legal action based on the information provided. The publisher accepts no responsibility for any acts or omissions contained herein. Enquiries concerning reproduction should be sent to the Institute of Competition Law, at the address below. Copyright © 2016 by Institute of Competition Law 60 Broad Street, Suite 3502, NY 10004 www.concurrences.com [email protected] Printed in the United States of America First Printing, 2016 Publisher’s Cataloging-in-Publication (Provided by Quality Books, Inc.) Choice—a new standard for competition law analysis? Editors, Paul Nihoul, Nicolas Charbit, Elisa Ramundo. pages cm LCCN 2016939447 ISBN 978-1-939007-51-3 ISBN 978-1-939007-54-4 ISBN 978-1-939007-55-1 1. Antitrust law. 2. Antitrust law—Europe. 3. Antitrust law—United States. 4. European Union. 5. Consumer behavior. 6. Consumers—Attitudes. 7. Consumption (Economics) I. Nihoul, Paul, editor. II. Charbit, Nicolas, editor. III. Ramundo, Elisa, editor. K3850.C485 2016 343.07’21 QBI16-600070 Cover and book design: Yves Buliard, www.yvesbuliard.fr Layout implementation: Darlene Swanson, www.van-garde.com GO TO TABLE OF CONTENTS ii CHOICE – A NEW STANDARD FOR COMPETITION LAW ANALYSIS? Editors’ Note PAUL NIHOUL NICOLAS CHARBIT ELISA RAMUNDO In this book, ten prominent authors offer eleven contributions that provide their varying perspectives on the subject of consumer choice: Paul Nihoul discusses how freedom of choice has emerged as a crucial concept in the application of EU competition law; Neil W.
    [Show full text]
  • The Strategic Use of Public and Private Litigation in Antitrust As Business Strategy
    University of Florida Levin College of Law UF Law Scholarship Repository UF Law Faculty Publications Faculty Scholarship 3-2012 The Strategic Use of Public and Private Litigation in Antitrust as Business Strategy D. Daniel Sokol University of Florida Levin College of Law, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.ufl.edu/facultypub Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons, Litigation Commons, and the Public Law and Legal Theory Commons Recommended Citation D. Daniel Sokol, Strategic Use of Public and Private Litigation in Antitrust as Business Strategy, 85 S. Cal. L. Rev. 689 (2012), available at http://scholarship.law.ufl.edu/facultypub/320 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at UF Law Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in UF Law Faculty Publications by an authorized administrator of UF Law Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. THE STRATEGIC USE OF PUBLIC AND PRIVATE LITIGATION IN ANTITRUST AS BUSINESS STRATEGY D. DANIEL SOKOL I. INTRODUCTION One understudied area of the formative period of antitrust and of Standard Oil's conduct during this period is in the use and nature of antitrust private claims against Standard Oil. In contemporary antitrust, the ratio of private to government brought cases is ten to one.' In contrast, one hundred years ago government cases constituted nearly all antitrust cases,2 and many of such cases were state cases.3 On the hundredth anniversary of the Standard Oil decision,' the present Article uses a discussion of the antitrust private actions against Standard Oil prior to the company's court- ordered break up in 1911 as a starting point for a broader discussion about the interaction between public and private rights of action in antitrust in the modern era.
    [Show full text]
  • Microsoft Settlement Benefits Available Until June 30, 2007
    MICROSOFT SETTLEMENT BENEFITS AVAILABLE UNTIL JUNE 30, 2007 Wisconsin businesses, governments, and individuals who bought Microsoft software between December 7, 1993, and April 30, 2003, are entitled to receive benefits from a class action settlement with Microsoft, but they must act by June 30, 2007. Several Wisconsin plaintiffs brought lawsuits in Wisconsin courts claiming that Microsoft’s marketing practices violated Wisconsin antitrust and unfair trade laws. Microsoft denied the allegations, but did agree to a settlement which could provide as much as $224,000,000 in benefits to Wisconsin consumers, businesses, and local governments. To qualify for benefits, the individual, business, or governmental unit must have purchased for use in Wisconsin one or more of certain Microsoft programs either as a standalone purchase or already installed in a computer between December 7, 1993, and April 30, 2003. The software programs at issue are: Microsoft Office, Microsoft Excel, Windows, MS-DOS and Microsoft “Word”. In addition to the initial program, each upgrade purchased is eligible as well as each license that was multiply purchased. To get the benefits, eligible Wisconsin individuals, businesses, and governments should go to the following web site and obtain a claim form: www.microsoftwisuit.com. The form must be completed and mailed by June 30, 2007, to “Microsoft-Wisconsin Settlement, P.O. Box 1626, Minneapolis, MN 55440-1626.” For each Windows or MS-DOS program purchased during the applicable period, the purchaser is entitled to a $15 voucher. Each Office and Excel purchase yields a $23 voucher and each Word purchase yields a $10 voucher. Claims under $100 may be filed online and supporting documentation is not required.
    [Show full text]
  • MICROSOFT V. MOTOROLA and STANDARD-ESSENTIAL PATENT LITIGATION Kassandra Maldonado†
    BREACHING RAND AND REACHING FOR REASONABLE: MICROSOFT V. MOTOROLA AND STANDARD-ESSENTIAL PATENT LITIGATION Kassandra Maldonado† Technological innovation is rarely, if ever, created without utilizing prior innovations. As Carl Shapiro noted, “[t]he essence of science is cumulative innovation,” and cumulative innovation “is central to the scientific method.”1 However, cumulative innovation can be complicated by a vast array of intellectual property rights.2 These intellectual property rights are particularly problematic in the context of standard setting.3 In standard setting, any patents that are necessary to implement a chosen standard are labeled standard essential patents (“SEPs”).4 As new technological creations incorporate prior discoveries, individual patent holders, upon whose technological discoveries broader technological creations are built, are endowed with significant market power to determine licensing rates.5 As a result, standard-setting organizations (“SSOs”) typically require their members to commit to license any SEP on reasonable and nondiscriminatory (“RAND”) terms prior to incorporation into a standard.6 Although the RAND commitment is meant to incentivize adoption of the standard by requiring SEP holders to license on reasonable terms, patentees are given considerable power in setting rates.7 The power to set rates is magnified by © 2014 Kassandra Maldonado. † J.D. Candidate, 2015, University of California, Berkeley, School of Law. 1. Carl Shapiro, Navigating the Patent Thicket: Cross Licenses, Patent Pools, and Standard Setting, in INNOVATION POLICY AND THE ECONOMY 119, 119 (Adam B. Jaffe, Josh Lerner & Scott Stern eds., 2000). 2. Id. at 120 (stating that, in light of cumulative innovation, stronger patent rights can stifle innovation by creating a maze of patent rights that innovators must navigate through).
    [Show full text]
  • A Guide to Microsoft Office 365 Data Protection with NAKIVO Backup & Replication White Paper
    White Paper White Paper A Guide to Microsoft Office 365 Data Protection with NAKIVO Backup & Replication White Paper Overview The cloud shift has been happening for a while, but the COVID-19 pandemic has further accelerated it. The cloud computing market and especially SaaS offerings are growing at an unprecedented pace. According to forecasts, this market is set to reach USD 832.1 billion by 2025, up from USD 371.4 billion in 20201. Microsoft 365 alone has reached over 1 million user organizations worldwide in 20202. With the Microsoft Office 365 suite’s impressive results in improving business productivity and reducing IT costs, and the platform’s reliable track record in maintaining platform uptime, organizations have been relying on different Microsoft Office 365 applications in their day-to- day operations. This shift to Microsoft’s cloud platform has meant that these organizations’ business data resides exclusively in the cloud, more precisely on Microsoft’s servers. However, the mindset shift about data protection in the cloud has been slow to happen. One common misconception persists among these organizations about how much control they retain over their cloud data and who is responsible for its safety. Backups and third-party solutions like NAKIVO Backup & Replication have long become the standard for ensuring data protection and recoverability in any failure scenario. However, when it comes to Exchange Online, OneDrive for Business and SharePoint Online data, organizations are only starting to recognize one glaring blind spot — the need for data protection, and specifically third-party backup solutions for SaaS data. Confusion over terms like availability, redundancy, recoverability and backups may have been the culprit.
    [Show full text]
  • Vaporware: Imaginary High-Tech Products and Real Antitrust Liability
    Vaporware: Imaginary H-igh-Tech Products and Real Antitrust Liability in a Post-Chicago World ROBERT PRBNTICE* I. INTRODUCTION In rejecting a consent decree in the antitrust case United States v. Microsoft Corp.,1 Judge Stanley Sporkin noted that "vaporware," the high- technology industry's marketing ploy of preannouncing products that do not exist at the time of the announcement and may never come into existence in anything like their described form,2 "is a practice that is deceitful on its face and everybody in the business community knows it." 3 In part because of his misgivings about Microsoft Corporation's alleged * University Distinguished Teaching Professor and Ed and Molly Smith Centennial Professor of Business Law, Graduate School of Business, University of Texas, Austin, Texas. 1 159 F.R.D. 318 (D.D.C. 1995), rev'dper curiam, 56 F.3d 1448 (D.C. Cir. 1995). The original complaint charged Microsoft with violating sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act in the market for personal computer operating systems for the x86 class of microprocessors. The complaint attacked three of Microsoft's marketing practices: (a) "per processor" licenses by which Microsoft required original equipment manufacturers (OEMs) to pay a royalty for each computer the OEM sold regardless of whether it contained a Microsoft operating system; (b) "minimum commitments" distribution practices whereby Microsoft induced OEMs to commit to buy a minimum number of units of Microsoft operating systems under circumstances making it economically unattractive to install any non-Microsoft system; and (c) use of non-disclosure agreements (NDAs) to discourage independent software developers (ISVs) from developing applications for competing operating systems.
    [Show full text]
  • Java and Microsoft: How Does the Antitrust Story Unfold
    Volume 44 Issue 1 Article 2 1999 Java and Microsoft: How Does the Antitrust Story Unfold Daniel J. Gifford Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.law.villanova.edu/vlr Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons Recommended Citation Daniel J. Gifford, Java and Microsoft: How Does the Antitrust Story Unfold, 44 Vill. L. Rev. 67 (1999). Available at: https://digitalcommons.law.villanova.edu/vlr/vol44/iss1/2 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Villanova University Charles Widger School of Law Digital Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Villanova Law Review by an authorized editor of Villanova University Charles Widger School of Law Digital Repository. Gifford: Java and Microsoft: How Does the Antitrust Story Unfold 1999] JAVA AND MICROSOFT: HOW DOES THE ANTITRUST STORY UNFOLD? DANIEL J. GIWFORD* TABLE OF CONTENTS I. INTRODUCTION ........................................... 67 II. THE VISION OF THE JAVA PLATFORM ........................ 72 A. The Government and Microsoft .......................... 72 B. The Java Platform Paradigm: A Vision of the Future? . 74 C. The Technology ........................................ 81 1. Operating Systems .................................. 81 2. The Internet and the World Wide Web ................ 84 3. Browsers .......................................... 85 4. Java .............................................. 87 5. Java Rivals ....................................... 89 III. PATH DEPENDENCY, NETWORK EFFECTS AND THE DEVELOPMENT OF COMPUTER SOFTWARE
    [Show full text]
  • Against Data Exceptionalism
    University of Kentucky UKnowledge Law Faculty Scholarly Articles Law Faculty Publications 4-2016 Against Data Exceptionalism Andrew Keane Woods University of Kentucky, College of Law, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://uknowledge.uky.edu/law_facpub Part of the Internet Law Commons, and the Privacy Law Commons Right click to open a feedback form in a new tab to let us know how this document benefits ou.y Repository Citation Woods, Andrew Keane, "Against Data Exceptionalism" (2016). Law Faculty Scholarly Articles. 593. https://uknowledge.uky.edu/law_facpub/593 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Law Faculty Publications at UKnowledge. It has been accepted for inclusion in Law Faculty Scholarly Articles by an authorized administrator of UKnowledge. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Against Data Exceptionalism Notes/Citation Information Andrew Keane Woods, Against Data Exceptionalism, 68 Stan. L. Rev. 729 (2016). This article is available at UKnowledge: https://uknowledge.uky.edu/law_facpub/593 ARTICLE Against Data Exceptionalism Andrew Keane Woods* Abstract. One of the great regulatory challenges of the Internet era-indeed, one of today's most pressing privacy questions-is how to define the limits of government access to personal data stored in the cloud. This is particularly true today because the cloud has gone global, raising a number of questions about the proper reach of one state's authority over cloud-based data. The prevailing response to these questions by scholars, practitioners, and major Internet companies like Google and Facebook has been to argue that data is different.
    [Show full text]
  • An Antitrust Rule for Software Integration
    An Antitrust Rule for Software Integration J. Gregory Sidakt What is the proper legal standardfor product integration involving software? Because software is subject to low marginal costs, network effects, and rapid technological innovation, the Supreme Court's existing antitrust rules on tying arrangements, which evolved from industries not possessing such characteristics, are inappropriate. In this Article, I ask why firms integrate software products. Next, I review the Supreme Court's tying decisions in Jefferson Parish and Eastman Kodak. I propose an approach to judging the lawfulness of product integration in technologically dynamic markets that supplements the Supreme Court's current standard with four additionalsteps in cases of tying of computer software. Thereafter, I examine the D.C. Circuit's approach to software integration, which arose from that court's 1998 interpretation, in Microsoft II, of an antitrust consent decree between the US. Department of Justice and Microsoft Corporation. I argue that the D.C. Circuit's rule has general applicabilityand should be recognized as the appropriate standardfor software integration under antitrust law. I show how my approach imparts greater clarity to the D.C. Circuit's rule. I examine the competing product integration rule proposed in 2000 by Professor Lawrence Lessig as amicus curiae in the government's subsequent antitrust case against Microsoft, concerning the integration of Internet Explorer and Windows 98. My approach enables Professor Lessig's analysis to be reconciled with the D.C. Circuit's rule, but Professor Lessig's rule, on its own, would contain serious shortcomings. Thereafter, I evaluate Judge Thomas Penfield Jackson's April 2000 findings of law on the integration of Internet Explorer and Windows 98.
    [Show full text]
  • Microsoft Corporation Vs. the U.S. Court of Justice and the European Community
    Robert Schuman Microsoft Corporation vs. The U.S. Court of Justice and the European Community Francisco J. Lorca Jean Monnet/Robert Schuman Paper Series Vol. 9 No. 10 June 2009 Published with the support of the EU Commission The JeanMonnet/Robert Schuman Paper Series The Jean Monnet/Robert Schuman Paper Series is produced by the Jean Monnet Chair of the University of Miami, in cooperation with the Miami-Florida European Union Center of Excellence, a partnership with Florida International University (FIU). These monographic papers analyze ongoing developments within the European Union as well as recent trends which influence the EU’s relationship with the rest of the world. Broad themes include, but are not limited to: ♦ EU Enlargement ♦ The Evolution of the Constitutional Process ♦ The EU as a Global Player ♦ Comparative Regionalisms ♦ The Trans-Atlantic Agenda ♦ EU-Latin American Relations ♦ Economic issues ♦ Governance ♦ The EU and its Citizens ♦ EU Law As the process of European integration evolves further, the Jean Monnet/Robert Schuman Papers is intended to provide current analyses on a wide range of issues relevant to the EU. The overall purpose of the monographic papers is to contribute to a better understanding of the unique nature of the EU and the significance of its role in the world. Miami - Florida European Union Center Jean Monnet Chair Staff University of Miami Joaquín Roy (Director) 1000 Memorial Drive Astrid Boening (Associate Director) 101 Ferré Building María Lorca (Associate Editor) Coral Gables, FL 33124-2231 Maxime
    [Show full text]
  • G:\Civil\05 Cases\05 C 6869\Civix.Amend.Answer.Wpd
    Case: 1:05-cv-06869 Document #: 580 Filed: 02/01/10 Page 1 of 22 PageID #:<pageID> IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE NORTHERN DISTRICT OF ILLINOIS EASTERN DIVISION CIVIX-DDI, LLC, ) ) Plaintiff, ) ) v. ) No. 05 C 6869 ) HOTELS.COM, L.P., HOTELS.COM GP LLC, ) and YAHOO! INC., ) ) Defendants. ) MEMORANDUM OPINION AND ORDER AMY J. ST. EVE, District Court Judge: Defendants Hotels.com, L.P., Hotels.com GP, LLC (collectively “Hotels.com”), and Yahoo! Inc. (“Yahoo”) move the Court for leave to file Second Amended Answers and Counterclaims pursuant to Federal Rule of Civil Procedure 15(a). In response, Plaintiff CIVIX- DLI, LLC’s (“Civix”) filed a motion for judgment on the pleadings regarding Defendants’ inequitable conduct claims pursuant to Rule 12(c). The Court presumes familiarity with its previous orders in this litigation and the related Expedia litigation. See Civix-DDI, LLC v. Cellco P’ship, 387 F.Supp.2d 869 (N.D. Ill. 2005). For the following reasons, the Court, in its discretion, grants Defendants’ motions. The Court denies Civix’s motion for judgment on the pleadings. BACKGROUND On August 24, 2006, Civix filed a Second Amended Complaint in this matter alleging that Defendants infringed U.S. Patent Nos. 6,385,622 (the “‘622 patent”), 6,408,307 (the “‘307 patent”), 6,415,291 (the “‘291 patent”), and 6,473,692 (the “‘692 patent”). On September 17, 2007, the Court stayed the present litigation pending the Patent and Trademark Office’s (“PTO”) Case: 1:05-cv-06869 Document #: 580 Filed: 02/01/10 Page 2 of 22 PageID #:<pageID> ex parte reexamination of these four patents.
    [Show full text]