Society for Comparative Studies in Society and History

The Scandinavian Origins of the Social Interpretation of the Welfare State Author(s): Peter Baldwin Source: Comparative Studies in Society and History, Vol. 31, No. 1 (Jan., 1989), pp. 3-24 Published by: Cambridge University Press Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/178792 . Accessed: 31/01/2011 12:30

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.

Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at . http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=cup. .

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission.

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].

Cambridge University Press and Society for Comparative Studies in Society and History are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Comparative Studies in Society and History.

http://www.jstor.org The ScandinavianOrigins of the Social Interpretation of the Welfare State

PETER BALDWIN

Harvard University

If a question can be mal posee, surely an interpretationcan be mal etendue. This has been the fate of the social interpretationof the welfare state. The cousin of social theories of bourgeois revolution, the social interpretationof the welfare state is part of a broader conception of the course of modem Europeanhistory that until recently has laid claim to the status of a standard. The social interpretationsees the welfare states of certain countries as a victory for the working class and confirmationof the ability of its political representativeson the Left to use universalist, egalitarian, solidaristic mea- sures of social policy on behalf of the least advantaged.Because the poor and the workingclass were groups that overlappedduring the initial development of the welfare state, social policy was linked with the worker's needs. Faced with the ever-presentprobability of immiseration,the proletariatchampioned the cause of all needy and developed more pronounced sentiments of soli- daritythan other classes.2 Where it achieved sufficient power, the privileged classes were forced to consent to measuresthat apportionedthe cost of risks among all, helping those buffetedby fate and social injusticeat the expense of those docked in safe berths. One of the attractionsof the social interpretationof the welfare state has been its snug fit with a broader social interpretationof Western European history. In this, the bourgeois revolution paved the way for liberal capitalist democracy, which, in turn, would eventually be swept away in the pro- letariat'srise to power. Merely a reading of past events, the first half of this analysis was left to historiansto pick over. The second containeda prediction that has proven to be inaccurate.As a result, there developed an alternative This essay is partof a largerstudy on "The Politics of Social Solidarityand the Class Basis of the EuropeanWelfare State, 1875-1975" that will also cover France, Germany, and Britain. I am gratefulto LawrenceStone, Peter Mandler,and other membersof the Davis Seminarat Princeton for a thorough working over, and to the American-ScandinavianFoundation for resources to conduct the research. I also owe Daniel Levine a helpful reading of the manuscript. 1 Jean-JacquesDupeyroux, Evolution et tendances des systemes de Securite sociale des pays membresdes communauteseuropeennes et de la Grande-Bretagne(Luxembourg, 1966), 55-59. 2 Franz-XaverKaufmann, Sicherheit als soziologisches und sozialpolitischesProblem: Unter- suchungen zu einer Wertideehochdifferenzierter Gesellschaften (Stuttgart, 1970), 18. 0010-4175/89/1163-2336 $5.00 ? 1989 Society for ComparativeStudy of Society and History 3 4 PETER BALDWIN version of the social interpretation,a reformistsocialist account that sought to identify significant victories won peacefully by the Left to mark a gradual transformationfrom the bourgeois era to that of the working class. In this scheme, certainsocial-policy reformsin certaincountries took the place of the socialist revolution.Under the right circumstances,social policy went beyond fine tuning the capitalist system or appeasing the laboring classes. Certain kinds of social policy restrictedthe rule of the marketover basic conditions of existence, taking a step beyond capitalism. The social interpretationof the welfare state became part of a social-democratic variant of the traditional Marxist reading of modem history. Its outcome was social reform, not so- cialist revolution; a pensioned, not a dictatorial,proletariat; not the stateless society, but the welfare state. Although simple, the social interpretationof the welfare state was not immediatelyobvious. It seemed to work only for some countries. It fit certain periods better than others. In liberal Britain, the working class was at best partially responsible for first forays into welfare statism. Even worse, Bismarck's Bonapartistgoals were impossible to reconcile with the social interpretation.The working class was the passive object of social policy, not its initiator. Welfare measures were meant to preserve an unjust order by improving, while not fundamentallychanging it. On the other hand, William Beveridge and Labour'sreforms in Britainafter World War II and the success of egalitarian social policy in socialist , offered examples of an alternativeapproach to the welfare state, one that went beyond liberal tinker- ing, one that reflected the interestsof workers, not their masters. Out of this contrast a conceptual tension developed between at least two kinds of social policy, two kinds of welfare states: the conservative and the authentically reformist. Observersof the Anglo-Scandinavianscene (especially afterWorld War II) could, and largely did, rest content with some variantof the social interpretation.3Observers of other countrieswere left to seek explanationsfor why social policy there did not resemble this ideal. The result has been a curious ambivalence about the social interpretation.Often taken for granted, rarely articulated, it frequently lies implicit in discussions of social policy without informingthem. The cause of this mixtureof widespreadassumption and rudimentaryexpression is a fundamentalambiguity at the heart of the welfare state as an historical concept. The bourgeois revolution, in the mannerthat constructwas used before its recent decline, assumed its classic form in France. Subsequentand analogous events in Germanywere judged a failurein comparisonto what they ought, by

3 This is why general histories only of Britainand seek to define the essence of their currentincarnations as welfare states: T. O. Lloyd, Empire to Welfare State: English History, 1906-1967 (Oxford, 1970); Pauline Gregg, The WelfareState: An Economic and Social History of Great Britainfrom 1945 to the Present Day (London, 1967); Kurt Samuelson, From Great Power to WelfareState: Three Hundred Years of Swedish Social Development (London, 1968). SCANDINAVIAN ORIGINS OF WELFARE STATE 5 this account, to have been. The ideal natureof the French phenomenon was not marredby Germany's inability to emulate it. On the contrary, not the model, but the circumstancesacross the Rhine were pronouncedan aberra- tion. For the welfare state, the path from event to interpretation,from the classic historicalexample to its deviations, was reversed. At almost the same time as Bismarcktainted the bourgeois revolutionin Germanyby imposing it from above on the class that ought, in the traditionalsocial interpretation,to have been its initiator,he associatedthe inaugurationof the welfare state with the preservationof an archaic social order, the smooth functioning of the capitalist system, the political dominationof conservatives.4 The social interpretationof the welfare state has been made possible only to the extent that social policy was freed from its tie to Bismarck and Bonaparte and associatedpositively with the downtrodden,particularly the workers, and their strivings for greaterequality and a fairerdistribution of burdens. Based on a selective reading of certain historical experiences, it was first made plausible by the world-wide push for a universalist, egalitariansocial policy that culminated during the final years of World War II, spilling over into majorattempts at change, of which the Beveridge Plan and Clement Attlee's legislation were the crowning achievements. The postwar wave of reform underminedthe Bonapartistview of social policy that Bismarck's legislation had encouraged. Social policy could be used for reactionarypurposes, but, given the right circumstances, social legislation could also be the autono- mous, authenticallyemancipatory action of the underprivileged. While Labour's reforms inaugurateda new conception of social policy, they were unable to sustain it alone. Illuminatingthe sky like a flare, bril- liantly but briefly, wartimeefforts permittedthe discovery of a non-Bismarck- ian strainof social policy that both preceded and was to outlive it. Develop- ments in the Scandinaviancountries had generally passed unremarkeduntil Beveridge.5 With the attentiondevoted to reform during and after the war, it no longer escaped notice that, in the North, long traditionsof socialist power coincided with social policy of an universalist,egalitarian sort. Neither social policy nor Scandinaviahas ever been the same. With the failure of postwar reforms in France and Germany, and Britain's decline from welfare ideality, the Scandinaviancountries came into their own as examples of nations where enlightened, egalitariansocial policy seemed to have been the independent achievementof the neediest classes. Where Scandinaviahad earlier attracted the attention mainly of those interested in, say, pig farming or temperance movements, the North suddenly found itself the center of internationalatten-

4 Asa Briggs refuses to anoint Bismarck's reforms with the title "welfare state" because of theirBonapartist intent ("The Welfare State in HistoricalPerspective," Archives europeennesde sociologie, 2:2 (1961), 247-49). 5 An exception is discussed in Daniel Levine, "The Danish Connection: A Note on the Making of British Old-Age Pensions," Albion, 17:2 (Summer 1985), 181-85. 6 PETER BALDWIN

tion. Admiredby many, it was reviled only by a shrill coterie, whose use of epithets like "the new totalitarians" for what more reasonable spirits de- scribedas "the middle way" suggested a degree of hyperbolelikely to defeat its own purposes.6 Languishingon the peripheryof Europeanhistory, Scan- dinavia, in certain respects, suddenly became its cynosure. By extending its geographicalhorizons, the social interpretationseemed to have demonstrated its continued power. The ideal case of the bourgeois revolution had been French. The peaceful victory of the working class proved to be Scandi- navian.7 Novelty and accuracy have not in this case been completely compatible bedfellows. The result of this new focus has been an anachronisticreading of the historyof Nordic social policy. To the extent that Scandinaviais taken, in these respects, as the standardagainst which to measureother countries, this distortionhas consequences for an understandingof developments south of the Eider. The long traditionof social-democraticrule in the North has en- couraged a tendency to associate even reforms inherited from another age with the socialists who followed. The Nordic welfare states came, with good cause, to be hailed as the pinnacleof social-policy achievement. More impor- tant for the social interpretation,they were regardedas the antithesis of the Bismarckianapproach. Bismarck's social policy is usually considered reactionary, Bonapartist, and unsolidaristic.It reflected these characteristicsin at least three ways: It focussed only on the workers, in the hope of politically defusing that dan- gerous class. It avoided any wide-ranging social equalization and gave ex- pression to existing markethierarchies through benefits differentiatedaccord- ing to wages. It relied on unredistributivefinancing collected directly as premiums or through regressive consumption taxes. Conversely, Scandina- vian welfare policy was the fruit of the common masses' political power, representedby the socialists. It thereforeincorporated a solidarityof the entire communityby including all citizens, offering them egalitarianflat-rate bene- fits, and relying heavily on tax financing to distributeburdens by ability to shoulder them. Socialist success in implementing measures of universalist, flat-rate, tax-financedsocial policy, it is claimed, qualitativelydistinguishes social-democraticwelfare states from liberal and conservative systems else- where. Scandinaviansocial policy is seen as most closely embodyingthe ideal "institutional" model of the welfare state that fulfills the concept of social

6 Roland Huntford, The New Totalitarians (London, 1971); Marquis Childs, Sweden: The Middle Way (New Haven, 1936). 7 On Sweden's careeras an ideal type, Are Ruth, "The Second New Nation:The Mythology of Modem Sweden," in Norden: The Passion for Equality, Stephen R. Graubard,ed. (Oslo, 1986), 240-82. SCANDINAVIAN ORIGINS OF WELFARE STATE 7 citizenship, limits the free workingof marketrelations in importantareas, and lessens inequalities.8 The social interpretationasserts that the Scandinavianwelfare states were the autonomousachievement of the underprivilegedclasses, that their nature was determinedby the needs of the impoverished. In other countries, where social policy reflected a fear of social upheaval, measures were restricted, divisive, and manipulative. The features that define the exceptionalism of Nordic welfare policy were, in contrast,the resultof the Left's ability to forge a coalition of the downtroddenpowerful enough to implementthe demandof the poor and unfortunatefor help from the affluentand favored.9This view- that there was an essential link between the apparentsolidarity, the univer- salism of early Scandinavianwelfare policy, and the socialists-is mislead- ing.10 It anachronisticallyreads back a misunderstandingof postwar reforms to an earlierperiod in which other factors were at work. " The characteristic featuresof Scandinaviansocial insurancewere not bom in the postwarperiod, when socialist power reachedits height, but were formed at the time the first legislation went on the books, at the turn of the century. They were deter- mined at the behest of parties and social groups not associated with the Left. Universalist, solidaristic social policy was, in this case, not the sort of qualitative change claimed by social interpretation.Only apparentlydid it

8 On the Nordic, institutionalmodel of the welfare state, Richard Titmuss, Social Policy (London, 1974), 30-31; Anne-Lise Seip, Om velferdsstatensfremvekst (Oslo, 1981), 11-18; NormanFurniss and Timothy Tilton, The Case for the WelfareState (Bloomington, 1977), 14- 20; Bent Rold Andersen, "Rationalityand Irrationalityof the Nordic Welfare State," in Norden: The Passion for Equality, Stephen R. Graubard,ed., 117-21; Michael Shalev, "The Social- Democratic Model and Beyond: Two 'Generations' of ComparativeResearch on the Welfare State," ComparativeSocial Research, 6 (1983), 315-51. 9 "The congruence of Scandinaviansocial-democratic welfare policy," one recent account would have its readers believe, "is explained by two critical factors. One was that the parties chose to abandon the ghetto model in favor of parliamentarymajoritarianism. They had to cultivate, and fabricate, unity among workers, peasants, and the rising white collar strata. This naturallyled to an insistence on universalism" (G0sta Esping-Andersen,Politics against Mar- kets: The Social Democratic Road to Power (Princeton, 1985), 154, 145, 148). 10 Examplesof an anachronisticmisattribution of the apparentsolidarity of early Scandinavian welfare reforms to the socialists: Ake Elmer, Frin Fattigsverige till vdlfirdsstaten: Sociala forhallandenoch socialpolitiki Sverige under nittonhundratalet,7th ed. (, 1975), 127; Stein Kuhnle, "The Beginnings of the Nordic Welfare States: Similarities and Differences," Acta Sociologica, 21, supplement(1978), 26; Guy Perrin, "L'assurance sociale-ses particu- larites-son role dans le passe, le present et l'avenir," in Beitrdge zu Geschichte und aktueller Situationder Sozialversicherung,Peter A. Kohler and Hans F. Zacher, eds. (Berlin, 1983), 40- 41; ThomasWilson, ed., Pensions, Inflation, and Growth:A ComparativeStudy of the Elderly in the WelfareState (L6ndon, 1974), 159; G0sta Esping-Andersenand Walter Korpi, "From Poor Relief to InstitutionalWelfare States: The Development of ScandinavianSocial Policy," in The ScandinavianModel, John Erikson et al., eds. (Armonk, 1987), 45-46. 11 An explanation of why the universalism of postwar reforms in Scandinavia was not a socialist initiative is given in Peter Baldwin, "How Socialist is Solidaristic Social Policy? Swedish PostwarReform as a Case in Point," InternationalReview of Social History, 2 (1988), 121-147. 8 PETER BALDWIN transcendnarrow class or group interests. Only in retrospecthas it come to seem the demand of the rising working class and the Left. When first intro- duced in Scandinavia,universalist, egalitarian, tax-financed welfare measures were a goal some bourgeois groups and parties were able to inflict in their own interestson the rest of society. The rest of this account argues the case for these assertionsby examining the origins of Scandinaviansocial policy's unique features. It analyzes the reasons why measureshere were universalist,covering all regardlessof social class, and why they were financed significantlythrough taxes, not premiums. It takes pension policy as the most convenient gateway to these issues. It concludes that universalism and tax financing were not the expression in terms of welfare policy of any uniquely Nordic sense of social solidarityand certainly not one inspired by socialists or workers. Instead, these features were the result of narrowinterest disputes fought out between the rising rural middle class and the entrenchedbureaucratic and urbanelites. It follows that the social interpretationof the welfare state rests on shaky foundationseven in its Scandinavianredoubt.

FARMERS, CONSERVATIVES, AND THE ORIGINS OF UNIVERSALIST SOCIAL POLICY: The first Danish social-insurancereforms were articulatedin the context of the major political dispute of the late nineteenth century. This crisis was sparked by the unwillingness of the conservative H0jre (the party of the monarchicalbureaucracy, the urban professional and manufacturingclasses and the aristocraticlandowners) to grant the mainly agrarianliberal Party the political representationto which farmers' growing social and eco- nomic importance gave them a claim. Farmers sought reforms that would benefit them financially. When the constitutionalconflict draggedon, social policy became partof the largerpolitical strugglebetween liberalsand conser- vatives, and eventually was an element in its resolution. Social reform was taken up as an alternativeway of achieving the effects of the fiscal demands still blocked by the conservatives. Farmersused social policy tailoredto their specifications to squeeze concessions from a state they did not yet control, before more direct solutions were possible. Withoutcoverage of all, agrarians would not benefit from social measures. Without tax financing and state subsidies, farmers, as employers, would be disadvantagedby higher produc- tion costs that they, as exporters, could accept less sanguinelythan the urban manufacturersamong their political opponents, who aimed only at the home market. The political victory for the liberals that permittedfarmers to reform the tax system and shift burdensfrom the countrysideto the cities had to wait until the turn of the century. Universalist, tax-financedsocial policy was its herald. Early discussions of social-policy reformgave farmerstheir first chance to SCANDINAVIAN ORIGINS OF WELFARE STATE 9

demand a respite from the growing burdens of poor relief on local au- thorities.12 As more of the populationwas granteda voice in politics during the late eighteenth and early nineteenthcenturies, the contradictionwas ag- gravated between the absolutist monarch's comparatively generous social policy, and the disinclinationof farmers, who paid the lion's share of local taxes, to bear a heavier load than necessary. Especially after 1835, with widened representationin the estates, farmerslamented the growing cost of poor relief, and debatedthe merits of workhouseson the British model and a declassing treatmentof the poor. In 1874, liberals first tried to reduce their costs throughanother, and ultimatelymore successful, approach,demanding subsidies from the state for self-help, praisingthe relief this would bringto tax burdens.13The report of the Commission on Workers' Conditions in 1878 continuedthe liberal farmers'interest in state subsidies.14 They worried, lest employers bear the brunt of the social provision, especially in agriculture, where a dependence on foreign markets made it difficult to pass along ex- penses. If low wages in the countrysidewere not to be raised, costs would have to be shifted to consumersor employers. Neither possibility was attrac- tive, so the farmers' solution for pensions was based on voluntary arrange- ments, with the state responsiblefor half of the funding.15The commission's conservativeminority, on the otherhand, saw no justificationfor state financ- ing. Shifting the burdensfrom local governmentsto the state did not lessen the demoralizing effect of public subsidies as such. Farmers had long ex- ploited poor relief as a subsidy to their laborers'inadequate wages, but it was not the public's task to supplementincomes. Since wages that were sufficient

12 Older, but still useful, accounts include Danmarkssociallovgivning (, 1918- 20); HaraldJ0rgensen, Studierover det offentligeFattigvtesens historiske Udvikling i Danmarki det 19. aarhundrede(Copenhagen, 1940); Kjeld Philip, Staten og Fattigdommen:Fern Kapitler af dansk Kulturpolitik(Copenhagen, 1947); Cordt Trap, Om Statens Stilling til Ubemidledes Alderdomsfors0rgelsei flere europceiskeLande (Copenhagen, 1892); J0rgen Dich, "Kompen- dium i socialpolitikkens historie: I. Udviklingen indtil 2. Verdenskrig," manuscript, 2d ed. (1967). Systematizing and expanding the rather schematic works of Dich and others is J0rn Henrik Petersen's recent and extensive account of pension policy in Den danske alder- domsforsorgelseslovgivningsudvikling: Bind I. Oprindelsen(Odense, 1985) (citations from Pe- tersen are to the more detailed, unpublished manuscriptof the dissertation of the same title (Odense University, 1985). 13 Dich, "Kompendium," 19. Petersen, Den danske alderdomsfors0rgelseslovgivningsud- vikling, 143-48. 14 Betcenkningafgiven af den ifolge Kgl. Resolutionaf 20de September1875 til Unders0gelse af Arbeiderforholdenei Danmark nedsatte Kommission (Copenhagen, 1878), 71-77, 81-83. Backgroundin G. Warmdahl, "Statens Stilling til Arbejdersp0rgsmaaleti halvfjerdseme:Arbe- jderkommissionenaf 1875," in Sociale studier i dansk historie efter 1857, Povl Engelstoft and Hans Jensen, eds. (Copenhagen, 1930), 64-81. 15 Rigsarkivet, Copenhagen, PR 404-07-2, Arbejderkommissionenaf 1875, Minutes of a meeting 8 December 1875 or 1876. This was the argumentput forth by V. Falbe-Hansen. A professorof statistics, he was a conservativedeputy at the time, but laterjoined the upper house in 1909 as a royal appointee and a liberal. 10 PETER BALDWIN even in times of old age and disability were the employer's responsibility, contributoryfinancing was the solution.16 For the time being, farmers'hopes for state-subsidizedsocial policy failed with the sharpeningof the constitutionalconflict that pitted the liberal major- ity in the lower house against a conservativegovernment. Once moderatesin the opposing camps wearied of battle, a rapprochement,phrased in terms of social policy, became possible, and eventually it was consummatedin the 1891 pension law that sent Denmarkinto the welfare vanguardas the bearerof a universalist,tax-financed pension system unlike thatof Bismarck.17 Among liberals, the conflict was coming to a head between radicals, who resisted cooperationwith the governmentbefore settlementof the constitutionalissue, and moderates, who were willing to compromise.18Moderates were willing to trade an end to the hostilities for conservativesupport of agriculturaltariff reform.19 They proposed replacing tariffs on raw sugar with a tax on the urban workingman'sbeer, and to distributesmall gardenparcels to otherwise land- less agriculturallaborers.20 Cheaper sugar and land redistributionmight, they hoped, stimulatea preserves industryand supplementrural incomes. Among the conservatives, estate owners were encouragedto compromisewith liberals by the problems they shared in common as agrarians. In 1890, poor relief and reform of tariffs and taxes intersected with the chance to resolve the constitutionaldispute to bring forth the first pension legislation. Faced with an understandingbetween moderateliberals and con- servatives for new taxes on the urbanand laboringclasses' favoriteinebriants, radical liberals proposed using their income to finance noncontributorypen- sions for the poor of all classes.21 Four months later, in March 1891, moder- ates from the parties to the future rapprochementagreed on a response. A compromise over tariffs foundered on the upper house's unwillingness to relax protectionism, but was reached instead on pensions. The moderates' move was an overbid that shifted tax burdensfrom sugar to beer and carved

16 Betcnkning, 87-89. 17 On the complicated negotiations leading up to 1891, Petersen, Den danske alder- domsfors0rgelseslovgivningsudvikling, ch. 12; Dich, "Kompendium," 23-26; Trap, Statens stilling, 260-77. 18 N. Neergaard, Erindringer (Copenhagen, 1935), 235-40. Frede Bojsens politiske erindringer, KristianHvidt, ed. (Copenhagen, 1963), 189ff. 19 Rigsdagstidende, FT, 14 October 1890, col. 44-46. A general account is Poul Kierke- gaard, "Frede Bojsen som Socialpolitiker," in Mcendog Meninger i Dansk Socialpolitik, 1866- 1901, Povl Engelstoft and Hans Jensen, eds. (Copenhagen, 1933), 67-107. 20 Rigsdagstidende,Fr, 30 October 1890, col. 440-47. 21 Marcus Rubin, "Hvad koster en Alderdomsfors0rgelse for de danske Arbejdere?" NationalokonomiskTidsskrift, 26 (1888), 357-58; idem, "Alderdomsfors0rgelsesforslaget," National0konomiskTidsskrift, 29 (1891), 44-48; Trap, Statens stilling, 256; MarcusRubin, Om Alderdomsfors0rgelsen(Copenhagen, 1891), 12-16; Letter, Rubin to Edvard Brandes, 9 De- cember 1890, in Marcus Rubins brevveksling, 1870-1922, Lorenz Rerup, ed. (Copenhagen, 1963), I, 319-20; Marcus Rubin, Nogle erindringer(Copenhagen, 1914), 143-44. SCANDINAVIAN ORIGINS OF WELFARE STATE II

out of a previous governmentproposal on poor relief a bill on statutoryaid for the worthy elderly.22 Local authoritieswere to grant pensions to all morally upright needy over age sixty, with half their expenses reimbursedby the state.23 What the moderate liberals and conservatives had agreed on was to begin to end the constitutionalconflict and, in return, to shift a significant fraction of local poor-relief expenses from agrarians'shoulders, to the state. Two points standout on the socialists' attitudeto this effort at social-policy reform. First, Denmark's agrariansociety prevented the socialists, to the extent they entertainedambitions to power, from limiting their concern to the urban working class.24 In social policy, this meant not restricting arrange- ments to any particularclass. Nor could special considerationfor urbanareas be pressed.25 The socialists' need to appeal to the petite bourgeoisie also introducedan ambivalencein their relations with the unskilled lowest layers of the workingclass, allowing them to accept the demeaningcriteria of moral worth and respectabilitythat remained a persistent characteristicof Danish social policy.26 Second, like their British colleagues, Danish socialists re- jected the contributoryand self-help principlesof pension policy. Membersof the extensive network of voluntarysickness funds could pay premiums, but furthercontributions, for otherforms of social policy would strainthe average budget.27 Wages were modest, the right to work was not recognized, and workers were the source of surplus value; unconditionalhelp from the state was, therefore, their right in times of distress.28This derivationof the right to

22 In 1890, the governmenthad proposedlegislation to reformpoor relief by grantingit, shorn of its usual demeaningconsequences, to the worthy needy. Rigsdagstidende, 1890/91, TillaegA, col. 3393ff.; FT, 11 March 1891, col. 4537-45, 4591-97. 23 The conservativesmanaged to limit the state's obligation to refund municipal expenses to two million crowns annually. Not until 1902, afterthe final resolutionof the parliamentarybattle and liberal victory was this limit removed. 24 An excellent account of the relation between socialists and their political clientele in Denmark'sagrarian society, with importantimplications for the history of in general, is Hans-NorbertLahme, Sozialdemokratieund Landarbeiterin Danemark (1871-1900), (Odense, 1982). Also, Henning Grelle, Socialdemokratieti det danske landbrugssamfund,1871-ca.1903 (Copenhagen, 1978), and Georg N0rregaardand Hans Jensen, "Organisationsfors0gblandt Landarbejderne,"in Bidrag til Arbejderklassensog ArbejdersporgsmaaletsHistorie i Danmark fra 1864 til 1900, Povl Engelstoft and Hans Jensen, eds. (Copenhagen, 1931), 54-202. 25 Thus, for example, socialists rejectedthe assumptionof the Radical Liberals' bill that life was cheaper in rural than urban areas and that differential benefits were necessary. Rigs- dagstidende, FT, 20 December 1890, col. 1823. 26 Torben Berg S0rensen, Arbejderklassens organisering og socialpolitikkens dannelse (Copenhagen, 1978), 104-05, 168-74. 27 This is the argumentmade, with much supportingevidence on wages and contributions,in P. Knudsen, Sygeforsikring og Alderdomsforsorgelse: Betcenkningafgiven af det paa de k0benhavnskeog frederiksbergskeSygekassers Fcellesm0de den 29de og 30te August 1883 ned- satte Udvalg (Copenhagen, 1888), 245-63 et passim. 28 Else Rasmussen, "SocialdemokraternesStilling til de sociale Sp0rgsmaalpaa Rigsdagen, 1884-1890," in Mcend og Meninger i Dansk Socialpolitik, 1866-1901, Povl Engelstoft and Hans Jensen, eds. (Copenhagen, 1933), 149. 12 PETER BALDWIN aid from the theory of surplus value was a common socialist position at the time, shared with the German Left.29 The right to benefits founded on the production of surplus value remained a purely theoreticalideal among Ger- man socialists, soon replaced in practice by contractualentitlement based on contributions.30In Denmark, where a happy overlap of interests between socialists and liberals allowed significant public participationand a non- contributorysystem, reliance on the state remainedboth theory and practice. Socialists, however, were not the ones who matteredin this period. With- out a doubt, liberals and conservatives hoped to dampenthe Left's appeal by supportingsocial policy and other improvementsfor rurallaborers and small- holders. Nevertheless, the nature of social reform was determined by the agrarian liberals, for their own reasons. The constitutional conflict saw Danish politics split between the conservatives and liberals. Much has been made of earlier land reforms, the influence of popular education, and the flowering cooperative movement to explain the political liberalismof Danish farmers.31These were certainly factors. Their liberalism was provoked by conservative unwillingness to grantthem political power proportionalto their social importance.One of the peculiaritiesof the Danish situation, however, was the mannerin which farmersreacted to the agriculturalcrisis, undergird- ing their political opposition with economic motives that prevented their division into protectionistsand free-traders. Danish farmers, who were exporters dependent on cheap foreign fodder, had obvious cause to be economic liberals. What distinguished them from their German and Swedish colleagues was their ability, once grain prices began to drop, to shift to dairy farming and livestock and continue export- ing.32Their consistent support for free trade, even as the rest of Europeturned coats, made impossiblethe common groundbehind high tariffs between some agricultureand some industry, that Germany achieved with the marriageof iron and rye in 1879.33 Because Danish industrialistsand manufacturerspro- duced for the home market, political realignments-based on a common

29 Hertha Woolf, Die Stellung der Sozialdemokratiezur deutschen Arbeiterversicherungs- gesetzgebung von ihrer Entstehungan bis zur Reichsversicherungsordnung(Berlin, 1933), 45- 46. 30 The German socialists' interest in contributoryfinancing was tied to the relation between premiumsand representationin the social insuranceadministrative councils, a motive absent in Denmark, where local authoritieswere to run the system. 31 Danes boasted that, whereas among their larger neighbors the cities were progressive and the countrysidereactionary, in Denmarkthe situationwas reversed (EdvardBrandes, Fra 85 til 91: En politisk Oversigt (Copenhagen, 1891), 82). 32 Svend Aage Hansen, 0konomisk vceksti Danmark (Copenhagen, 1972), I, chs. 8, 9; Ole Bus Henriksen and Anders 0lgaard, Danmarks udenrigshandel, 1874-1958 (Copenhagen, 1960). Overviews in English in Michael Tracy, Agriculture in Western Europe (New York, 1964), and Roy Millward, ScandinavianLands (London, 1964), ch. 8. 33 The comparisonbetween Germanyand Denmarkin this respect was memorablydrawn by AlexanderGerschenkron in Bread and Democracy in Germany (Berkeley, 1943), 39-40. SCANDINAVIAN ORIGINS OF WELFARE STATE 13 protectionist position, cutting across occupational categories-were ham- pered. The farmers' inability to compromise with protectionistconservatives laid the socioeconomic foundationof the constitutionalconflict. The political deadlock, in turn, preventedliberal agrariansfrom introducingthe tax reforms on their agenda, above all income and wealth taxes to lessen those on land, until after social reform had passed.34 Tax reform was a longstandingagrarian demand. Direct state income and wealth taxes had been on the liberalprogram since 1882. The large aristocrat- ic landowners among the conservatives wished to retain land and property taxes that, though weighty, founded their claim to disproportionalpower. Since land taxes affected them only slightly, the conservative urbanmercan- tile and manufacturingclasses agreed. On the other side, farmersresented the old tax structure,since their debt burdens, increased during the shift to live- stock and dairy farming, were ignored. Local taxes seem to have prompted the most justified reason for complaint. Unlike the income of the state, raised largely from indirect taxes, local revenues were the fruit of direct property taxes that increased during that century.35As agriculturegradually became more differentiated,with otherprofessions making inroadsin the countryside, the inheritedlocal tax system was unable to adjust, promptingincreasingly vociferous complaints.36Since poor relief was funded by local taxes, there was a direct connection between social and tax reform. State-financedpen- sions promisedto shift the costs of maintainingthe indigent elderly from local authorities' propertytaxes to the central state's indirect consumptionlevies. Farmersexpected to gain most from this displacement. Because the constitu- tional conflict blocked more direct reforms, publicly-financedpensions be- came a partial substitutefor tax reform. Both state financing and premiums on the German model would have relieved the weight that instead fell on the most progressivelyassessed levies of the day: local cadastraltaxes. While farmers'ambition to reduce their fiscal burdenscould have been satisfied by either means, financing through taxes promised them several advantages. First, it eliminated the need for an em- ployer's contribution.Far and away the largest group of employers, farmers

34 The tax reformsof 1903 confirmedthe political shift of 1901, when liberals finally replaced conservativesin government. Urban propertywas drawn into the distributionof burdens, and a general tax on income and wealth was introduced.Burdens were markedlyshifted from ruralto urban areas. Accounts are in H. C. Henningsen, "Beskatningsproblemeti Nutiden," in Den danske Stat, 2d ed. Even Marstrandet al., eds, (Copenhagen, 1933), 320-64; Sven R0gind, Danmarks Stats- og Kommuneskatter(Copenhagen, 1915), 7-12; Michael Koefoed, "Skat- tesystemerneaf 1802 og 1903," National0konomiskTidsskrift, 41 (1903), 337-63; K. A. Wieth- Knudsen, Dansk Skattepolitikog Finansvcesen(Copenhagen, 1928), 47-52. 35 Helge Nielsen and Victor Thalbitzer, Skatter og Skatteforvaltningi celdre Tider (Copen- hagen, 1948), 127; K., "Hvorledes fordele Skatternei Danmarksig paa de forskellige Sam- fundsklasser?"National0konomisk Tidsskrift, 32 (1894), 203-05. 36 A. Clausager, "Godsernesbeskatningsforhold," in Herregaardeneog Samfundet,Therkel Mathiassen(Copenhagen, 1943), 283-84. 14 PETER BALDWIN stood to bear the bruntof costs distributedin this way. Because most farms were small or medium-sizedenterprises practicing labor-intensive agriculture, they could not bear premiumswith the same facility as the large protectionist industriesof Germany.37Second, the use of tax financing avoided the higher wages needed to enable workersto pay premiums.38Unlike the protectionist Germansand Swedes, Danish farmerssold at prices determinedon the world marketand could absorbhigher productioncosts only at the risk of decreased competitiveness. State financing held out special economic advantages to farmersto the extent they could side-step the higher taxes that would follow. Related to these considerationswas a third factor born of the severity of the late nineteenth-centuryagricultural crisis. Funded contributorysocial insur- ance could have begun only after a lengthy transitionperiod duringwhich the currently needy would still be without aid. Tax-financed, noncontributory measures, on the other hand, took effect at once.39 Such factors determinedagriculture's reluctance to assume social burdens directly. There still remainedthe question of where they could be placed. The inheritedtax structureand antagonismsbetween urbanand ruralgroups gave state financing the advantageof shifting burdensnot merely away from the farmers,but from the countrysideto the cities. Farmersattached great impor- tance to the state-financedpensions' ability to reduce their local poor-relief costs by displacing the expense of providing for the elderly to state taxes.40 The countrysidecontributed proportionally less to the state's revenue (raised largely from indirect taxes) than cities. The new taxes introducedto help finance pensions, they reasoned, would affect urbanworkers more than their rural colleagues, and, generally, economies based on cash more than in kind.4' Finally, there was also an element of institutionalinertia that tipped the balance toward tax financing. The 1891 pension law resembled the old poor-relief system, shorn of its most disagreeableaspects. Avoiding a mas- sive new bureaucracyin the train of a Bismarckiansystem appealed to the

37 In general, large businesses throughoutEurope, especially if protectedby tariffs, feared the increased productivecosts of contributorysocial insuranceleast, small businesses most. Free- tradingsmall businessmen, like Danish farmers, were thereforethe strongest supportersof tax- financed social policy. Where they won, so did it. On business interests elsewhere, see Hans- Peter Ullmann, "Industrielle Interessen und die Entstehungder deutschen Sozialversicherung 1880-1889," Historische Zeitschrift, 229: 3 (December 1979), 574-610; Henri Hatzfeld, Du pauperisme d la Securite sociale (Paris, 1971), 137-41. 38 The Germancontributory system worked because it was aimed at the well-paid industrial labor aristocracy.Since Danish legislation focussed first and foremost on agriculturallaborers with their lower wages, this would not do. 39 Poul M0ller, Gennembrudsdr:Dansk politik i 50' erne (Copenhagen, 1974), 2. 40 A later account found that rurallocalities had profited most from the pension legislation. Rigsdagstidende, 1896/97, Tillaeg B, col. 3101-10. 41 FredeBojsen, Lovgivningsvcerket1890-95 og dets Folger (Copenhagen, 1898), 4-5; L. V. Birck, Told og Accise (Copenhagen, 1920), 217; Michael Koefoed, "Skatternei Danmark1870- 1900," NationalokonomiskTidsskrift, 40 (1902), 374. SCANDINAVIAN ORIGINS OF WELFARE STATE 15 liberals' penchant for administrativeminimalism and their disinclination to swell the ranks of civil servants, who usually voted for conservatives.42 Taxes were only one of the reasons why farmersfavored reform that prom- ised to ease their burdens. Despite a successful shift in products, they faced worsening problems as the agriculturalcrisis deepened.43 Agrarians were affected simultaneouslyby two problems.The transitionto animalproduction was profitablebecause livestock and dairy prices remainedstable, while feed costs declined. In the 1890s, transportationefficiencies intensified competi- tion with the New World and pressed livestock prices. As profits were squeezed, labor problems arose. Animal and dairy farming were more labor intensive than grain, while, perversely, the new productive techniques al- lowed smallholders to withdraw from wage earning to cultivate their own land. Large farmersneeded more labor at the same time that competition and falling prices limited their ability to improve conditions and to stem migra- tion. How to make rurallife more attractivewas an importantconcern. Pen- sions were but one of the most successful measures considered that demon- stratedthe close connectionbetween the agriculturalcrisis and social reform. Because agrarianssought to improve the lot of their laborers, and because their work force includedboth wage earnersand smallholders,dependent only partially on outside employment, limiting social measures to wage earners, not to mention the urban working class, was out of the question.44

FARMERS, CONSERVATIVES, AND THE ORIGINS OF UNIVERSALIST SOCIAL POLICY: SWEDEN Although the political circumstancessurrounding pension reform in Sweden differed from those in Denmark, the most importantfeatures were shared. Above all, universalistlegislation was rooted in its agrariansocial structure. Both the government administrationand the socialists initially favored pen- sions aimed at the working class alone. The bureaucratsand the Left could do little against the wishes of farmersnot to be excluded from statutorybenefi-

42 Aage S0rensen, "Om Alderdomsunderst0ttelsei Danmark,Australian med Ny Zeland og England," Tidsskriftfor Arbejderforsikring,5 (1909/10), 3-7. 43 The most sustainedanalysis linking the agriculturalcrisis, tax policy, and social reform is undertakenin Petersen, Den danske alderdomsforsorgelseslovgivningsudvikling, ch. 10, which fleshes out the hypotheses mentioned, but never developed, in Philip, Staten og Fattigdommen, 68-70, and J0rgen Dich, Den herskende klasse: En kritisk analyse af social udbytning og midlerne imod den, 4th ed. (Copenhagen, 1973), 25-28. Also, Hans Jensen, "Landarbej- dersp0rgsmaletsUdvikling i Danmarkfra ca. 1870 til ca. 1900," in Bidrag til Arbejderklassens og Arbejdersp0rgsmaaletsHistorie i Danmarkfra 1864 til 1900, Povl Engelstoft and H. Jensen, eds. (Copenhagen, 1931), 48-54. 44 It was no coincidence, Frede Bojsen, leader of the moderateliberals, explained in retro- spect, that social reform was concerned with the groups most in need, with the working rural populationthat had not yet fallen to socialist agitation. The legislation passed was, in the main, aimed to fit ruralconditions, without, however, giving other groupsreason to complain (Bojsen, Lovgivningsvcerket,4). I6 PETER BALDWIN cence and their disinclinationto pay for measuresfrom whose enjoymentthey were barred. The decision against contributorysocial insuranceon the Ger- man model was the result of similar forces. Extendingpensions to all citizens underminedfinancing by premiums. The self-employed, especially farmers, saw no reason to pay for their benefits alone, while workerswere helped out by their employers. Tax financing proved necessary in a countrywhere most citizens were still independents.While contributionswere tolerablefor large businesses, they were, for the mass of small agriculturalemployers, an un- acceptable burden that could be transferredto the state and the tax-paying community at large. The universalist and largely tax-financedpension sys- tem, in these ways, reflected the demands of small farmers. Attempts to solve the pension problem in Sweden at the end of the nine- teenth centuryfailed, with success reservedfor a law in 1913 based on novel principles.This legislation introduced,for the first time, "folk pensions" that gave all citizens at least token benefits, regardlessof class or income. Reform came late because farmers opposed the bureaucracy'sinclination to follow Bismarck'sexample but, for the time being, they could only obstructgovern- ment plans, not yet implement their own. At the same time, while farmers were still unable to dictate change, their desires were less clearly opposed to the conservative program than in Denmark. Previous satisfaction of agri- culturaldemands on tax and military issues, that to the south were resolved only with or after disputes over social policy, moderatedantagonisms be- tween farmers and landed aristocratson the one hand, and industrialists, manufacturers,urban professional classes, and the civil service on the other. Among the issues of concern to farmers, two were closely connected: military reorganizationand tax reform. Military burdens were distributed unevenly, resting with particularweight in the countryside.Taxes, too, were archaicallyand unfairly apportioned.The conservatives' ambitions to mod- ernize the armed forces and the farmers' contradictinghopes of a frugal administrationand their determinationnot to concede militaryreform without tax reform were reconciled by degrees over two decades. Taxes that es- pecially burdened agriculturalland were gradually reapportioned,and the army was reformed.45Unlike in Denmark, where social reform coincided with the political deadlock between urban and rural groups, major agrarian demands had been satisfied in Sweden by the time social reformwas first put on the agenda. Tariffs were anotherissue over which the Swedish agrarians and conservatives fought less bitterly than across the Kattegat. Ratherthan

45 Accounts of military and tax reform are in Per Hultqvist, Forsvar och skatter: Studier i svensk riksdagspolitikfrdan representationsreformentill kimpromissen1873 (Goteborg, 1955); idem, Forsvarsorganisationen, vdrnpliktenoch skatterna i svensk riksdagspolitik1867-1878 (Goteborg, 1959); and Torgny Nev6us, Ett betryggandeforsvar: Vdrnpliktenoch armeorganisa- tionen i svensk politik 1880-1885 (Stockholm, 1965). SCANDINAVIAN ORIGINS OF WELFARE STATE 17

following their Danish colleagues on free trade, Swedish farmers reacted much like their German counterparts.46Those with rye for sale, generally largerfarmers in central Sweden, welcomed high tariffs. Dairy and livestock farmers, who were grain consumers, opposed them.47 Protectionist agri- culture, representedby landed aristocratsin the senate and rye-producing farmersin the lower chamber,made itself heard. Politically, the tariff dispute had far-reachingeffects. The agrarianssplit, dividing into free-tradingand protectionist wings, with other parties following suit. Large farmers in the lower chamber, and landed aristocratsand industrialistsin the senate, identi- fied common interests and inaugurateda tradition of agrarian-conservative cooperation that lasted until the 1930s. In the lower house, the traditional oppositionbetween city and countrysidewas moderatedby new realignments over tariffs as workers and free-tradingliberals found common ground.48 Developments in social insurancebegan in Sweden at about the same time as in Denmark.49For pensions, the First Workers' InsuranceCommission's report in 1889 unsuccessfully proposed measures covering all with flat-rate contributorybenefits. Deciding whom to include, the commission defied its mandateto provide only for workers and those in comparablecircumstances. Insurmountabledifficulties, it concluded, would plague attempts to dis- tinguish workers from the self-employed and to deal with the many who would cross any such line duringtheir careers.50The Second Workers'Insur- ance Commission's proposals differed.51 Following Bismarck's lead, mea- sures were now limited to the working class.52 The need for insurancevaried

46 J6rn Svensson, Jordbruk och depression 1870-1900: En kritik av statistikens utveck- lingsbild (Malmo, 1965). An overview in English is G. A. Montgomery, The Rise of Modern Industryin Sweden (London, 1939), 145ff. 47 Sten Carlsson, Lantmannapolitikenoch industrialismen: Partigruppering och opin- ionsforskjutningari svenskpolitik 1890-1902 (Stockholm, 1953), 65-81; ArthurMontgomery, Svensk tullpolitik1816-1911 (Stockholm, 1921), ch. 7; Jan Kuuse, "Mechanisation, Commer- cialisation, and the ProtectionistMovement in Swedish Agriculture, 1860-1910," Scandinavian Economic History Review, 19: 1 (1971), 23-44. 48 DankwartA. Rustow, The Politics of Compromise:A Studyof Parties and Cabinet Govern- ment in Sweden (Princeton, 1955), 40-42; EdvardThermtenius, Rigsdagspartierna, Vol. XVII of Sveriges (Stockholm, 1935), ch. 6, esp. pp. 128-30; Per Sundberg, Ministdrerna Bildt och Akerhielm:En studie i den svenskaparlamentarismens forgardar (Stockholm, 1961). 49 The standardwork on pensions is Ake Elm6r, Folkpensioneringeni Sverige: Med sdrskild hdnsyntill alderspensioneringen(Lund, 1960). Detailed accounts of the early phase of Swedish social insurance are Karl Englund, Arbetarforsdkringsfragani svensk politik, 1884-1901 (Uppsala, 1976), and Hans Peter Mensing, Erscheinungsformenschwedischer Sozialpolitik im ausgehenden 19. Jahrhundert:Adolf Hedin, das Arbeiterversicherungskomiteeund die Gewer- beaufsicht nach 1890 (Kiel, 1979). An account in English is in Hugh Heclo, Modern Social Politics in Britain and Sweden: From Relief to Income Maintenance(New Haven, 1974), 178- 95. The beginnings of the social-insurancedebate are surveyed in ArthurMontgomery, Svensk socialpolitik under 1800-talet, 2d ed. (Stockholm 1951). 50 Arbetareforsdkringskomitensbetdnkande (Stockholm, 1889), I, 3, 43-73. 51 Nya arbetareforsdkringskomitensbetdnkande (Stockholm, 1893), I, 25-107. 52 The working class was defined to include those employed by others and having an income lower than 1,800 crowns annually, but to exclude casual laborerson the fringes between wage I8 PETER BALDWIN among social groups, it concluded. Wage earners were more dependenton poor relief than independents,who enjoyed a certainprotection through their property.As increasingnumbers of workersrelied on poor relief, burdensthat were unequally distributedthrough local taxes increased. The workers and their employers were thereforeto pay premiums. The clarity of the commis- sion's proposalwas marred,however, by the dissenting opinion of the agrar- ian leader, A. P. Danielson.53Speaking for the interestsof farmersnot to be barredfrom what otherwise threatenedto become exclusively working-class legislation, he regrettedthe exclusion of the most ruralinhabitants, classified by the law as employers. And he wanted the financing foreseen for employer contributionsto be assumed by the state, in order to distributethe required sacrifices among all. The government'sbill, introducedin 1895, was able closely to follow the commission's recommendationsbecause the farmershad not yet made their objectionsfelt.54 In parliament,however, the relevantcommittee, more influ- enced by Danielson, remainedunpersuaded.55 Employer contributions, even as limited in the bill, hurt small employers, while the greaterreliance on tax funds spared unreasonableburdens for independents.56The government's next try, still unsuccessful, was a compromisebill in 1898 that took another step toward the universalist, state-financed measures that were farmers' goal.57 The classes covered remained largely limited to workers, but em- ployer premiumswere eliminated altogether, and state subsidies increased. With this bill's defeat, the government's efforts reached their final rest in this round. Matterslay fallow until, at the end of 1907, the Old Age Pensions Commission was appointed.Its report, five years later, surveyed the field.58 Industrialworkers now challenged agrariansas the dominant social group. Even though social insurancewas relatedto the increasedimportance of wage earnersas a class, it should not cover them alone. The German system was inadequate in excluding independents and reserving the blessings of state subsidies for only one group. Complete state financing of universalistpen- sions, on the other hand, was prohibitivelyexpensive.59 Were all included, earnersand the self-employed. These laborershad been included in Germanybut with unfortu- nate results that the Swedes saw no reason to duplicate. To start with, 15 percent of the total population(35 percent of the working population)were to be included. 53 Nya arbetareforsakringskomitensbetankande, I, 141-48. 54 Prop. 1895:22, pp. 37-39, 43-58. 55 2SaU 1895:2, pp. 42-44, 49-50. 56 FK 1895:26, 27 April 1895, pp. 11-12, 45; FK 1895: 27, 27 April 1895, pp. 10-11. 57 Prop. 1898:55, pp. 12-21. 58 Alderdomsforsikringskommitten,I, Betankandeoch forslag angaende allmanpensionsfor- sdkring (Stockholm, 1912), 19-21, 40-44. 59 An importantcause of the Swedes' concern with costs related to their demographicpecu- liarities. Blessed by unusuallongevity and cursedby high emigration,the population'sage profile was markedlyskewed towardthe older end. In 1900, Sweden had almost twice as many inhabi- tantsover age seventy as Britainand Germany,and 15 and 20 percentmore than even Franceand SCANDINAVIAN ORIGINS OF WELFARE STATE 19 contributionswould have to be collected. Employer contributionsplayed no role in a system not limited to wage earners,but state subsidies allowed higher benefits than otherwise possible. To keep residents of expensive urbanareas off poor relief, means-testedlocal supplementsto the otherwise inadequate pensions were permitted.The goverment's bill followed the commission.60 Had measures been passed some decades earlier, it admitted, they would probably have been limited to wage earners. Favorable economic develop- ments now allowed all to be included. Employerpremiums had been replaced by state financing for fear that wage earnerswould be privileged while small employers were called on to pay both for themselves and their workers. The socialists' approachto this reformwas interesting.Unlike their Danish colleagues in the late nineteenthcentury, Swedish socialists focussed atten- tion on the urbanindustrial working class, undistractedby the desire to appeal to agrarians. The social and economic complexions of the two countries partiallyexplain this result. Sweden's mining and timber gave the economy an industrializedhue.61 Denmarkwas still more urbanizedthan Sweden, but agricultureplayed a dominantrole. Danish agriculturewas characterizedby comparativelylarge farms worked by laborers, who were riper for socialist recruitmentthan Sweden's generally small independentfarmers. Socialist ideology in Sweden reflectedthese differences. When formulating its first partyprogram, the Swedish Left ignoredthe agrarianquestion, assum- ing, and thereforeassuring, the futility of winning supportamong ruralwork- ers.62 A Kautskianapproach to agriculturesquared off against a Danish-style attempt at a "folk party" in internal debate.63 Only after the turn of the centurydid the orthodox approachmake way for a more reformist angle. In part, the Swedes replicated an adjustmentof Marxist doctrine to political reality found across Europeansocialist parties. In equal measure, they took

Denmark,respectively. Alderdomsforsakringskommitten,Kostnadsberikningar, (Stockholm) II, 120; Alderdomsf6rsakringskommitten,Allman pensionforsdkring, 61-63; Riksarkivet, Stock- holm, 20/1, Alderdomsforsakringskommitten,Letter, Commission to Statsradet,9 March 1910; And. Lindstedt, Forslaget till lag om allman pensionsforsdkring(Stockholm, 1913), 8-10. 60 Prop. 1913:126, pp. 28, 34, 48, 50, 126-27, 186-87. 61 Overviews in LennartJorberg, "The IndustrialRevolution in the Nordic Countries," The Fontana EconomicHistory of Europe, IV, 2; idem, Growthand Fluctuationof SwedishIndustry, 1869-1912 (Lund, 1961); idem, The IndustrialRevolution in Scandinavia, 1850-1914 (London, 1970). 62 This program,formulated by August Palm, was largely a translationof the Danish Gimle programfrom 1876, in turn a rendition of the German socialists' Gotha program with, as its particulartwist, a separate point on the agriculturalquestion: John Lindgren, Det socialdemo- kratiska arbetarpartietsuppkomst i Sverige 1881-1889 (Stockholm, 1927), 291-94. 63 In Denmark, agriculturalworkers were significantly representedin the party;this was not the case in Sweden in the 1890s. was the main Kautskien, the reformist in the party (G. Hilding Nordstrom, Sveriges socialdemokratiskaarbetarparti under gennombrottsaren1889-1894 (Stockholm, 1938), 184-85, 256, 261, 388-98, 613-23). On Branting's attitude, his "Industriarbetarpartieller folkparti?" (1895) in Tal och skrifter, 8, (Stockholm, 1929), 48-50. 20 PETER BALDWIN

account of domestic social peculiarities, the political costs of ignoring rural classes with too blindereda favoritismfor workers.The advantagesof appeal- ing to agrariansbecame especially obvious after the electoral reforms of 1907-09 extended the franchise. In 1911, the year of the first elections with universalmanhood suffrage, a major revision of the party's platform shifted its focus from the workingclass, narrowlydefined, to all oppressed, whatever their social origin.64 Despite such shifts, socialist supportfor the 1913 pension bill, coinciding with a sharpeninginternal conflict between doctrinairesand reformists, was far from unanimous.65Early in the year, the party's parliamentarydeputies had decided for an universalistapproach. Later discussion revealed the pres- ence of a minority in favor of treating various social groups differently. Several supporteda contributorysystem.66 Although the parliamentarygroup accepted the governmentbill, conflicts arose within the broadermovement. The partyexecutive was displeasedthat the deputies had abandonedemployer contributions,and were seconded in their doubts by the unions.67 Some, like Gustav Steffen, the well-known sociologist in the senate, preferredpensions on the Germanmodel that treatedworkers and independentsseparately. Im- posing on all citizens a social-insurancesystem developed for wage earners was unfortunate,he admitted, but no worse than the government's converse choice of extending to all a system formulated in the interests of the self- employed. The productive process ought to meet the cost of old age and disability throughemployer premiums.68 On the other side, HjalmarBranting, leader of the socialists, accepted the bill. His defense of it in parliamentwas a masterfulsummation of the pension issue and its social background.Had the Swedish working class been more powerful when legislation was first proposed, he conceded, the problem might have been resolved as in Germany. But even with measures limited to workers, changes would have followed. Contributoryworkers' insurance could not have been extended beyond the ranksof large industrialemployers. In Sweden, small employers were powerful and able to resist contributory financing more resolutely than their counterpartsacross the Baltic.

64 HerbertTingsten, The SwedishSocial Democrats: TheirIdeological Development(Totowa, N.J., 1973), 115-95. More specifically on agrarianissues, Lars Bjorlin, "Jordfragani svensk arbetarrorelse1890-1920," Arbetarrorelsensdrsbok, (Stockholm, 1974). 65 Seppo Hentila, Den svenska arbetarklassenoch reformismensgenombrott inom SAPfore 1914 (Helsinki, 1979), 228-29; RagnarEdenman, Socialdemokratiskariksdagsgruppen 1903- 1920 (Uppsala, 1946), 165-99, 278-80. 66 Arbetarr6relsensArkiv, Stockholm, SAP, Riksdagsgruppen,minutes, 19 February1913, 28 March 1913, 31 March 1913, 10 April 1913. 67 ArbetarrorelsensArkiv, Partistyrelsen,minutes, 14 April 1913. The unions wanted public subsidies raised substantiallyand the question of employer contributionsre-examined because, they argued, some way had to be found to allow higher benefits than those foreseen in the 1913 law. LO, Berattelse, 1913, p. 10. 68 FK 1913:34, 21 May 1913, pp. 31-36. SCANDINAVIAN ORIGINS OF WELFARE STATE 21

The socialists had shifted their stance, he admitted. They had supported insurance limited to workers, but now favored universalist measures. This broadacceptance of all-inclusive arrangementswas due to the advance of the popularclasses in the countryside,whose interestshad been given representa- tion throughelectoral reform. Sweden was not an industrializedsociety like Germanyor Britain, and small independentsrelied on poor relief as much as wage earners. Thus social insurancethat focussed only on workers ignored Sweden's social structure.Conceding that universalistsocial policy was un- avoidable, Brantingwent on to the difficulties of securing fair treatmentfor workerswithin a system thatcovered all: That harmonizingthe interestsof the poorestrural inhabitants, with those of urbanworkers, was troublesome.State subsidies should be given in proportionto the premiumpaid, more to urban than ruralgroups. Eliminatingurban municipal supplementsthat would have given workerslarger pensions than farmershad been a step backwards.It was difficult with universalistnational insurance to maintainsufficient differentia- tion between well- and poorly-paidgroups. Improvementsfor the worst-off should not be broughtat the expense of the industrialworking class.69 In both Denmark and Sweden, social-policy reform was born during a period of majorpolitical change and struggle as the child of native social and economic circumstances.The late nineteenthcentury saw the breakthroughof democraticpolitics and the coming to power of the broad middle classes, in Scandinaviancircumstances primarily farmers and peasants. In this clash, agrarianswrested from the traditionalpolitical elites of urban professionals, royal bureaucrats,and aristocraticestate owners that influence to which their growing social and economic importanceentitled them. Social-policy reform was colored by its coincidence with this battle. Reforms reflected the strengthenedpower of farmersand their determinationnot to be deprived of new forms of statutorybenevolence. Socialists were not without a presence during these changes. Vaguely Bonapartistfears encouraged the bourgeois parties to implement some form of statutorysocial measures. Nevertheless, the contentand natureof those finally chosen were determinedby the needs of the agrarians,who were emerging as dominantamong the bourgeois groups. The occasional and grudging approvalby the socialists of those features of social reform for which they would later take and be given credit were re- sponses to demands advanced by agrariansand liberals. In 1891 Denmarkintroduced universal, noncontributory,tax-financed pen- sions. The universalismof these reforms was the result, most generally, of Denmark's agrariansociety, more specifically of the farmers' desire to im- prove theirconditions through social measuresduring the ruralcrisis. Because their work force included cottagers and small holders as well as landless

69 AK 1913:48, 21 May 1913, pp. 44-64; AK 1913:49, 21 May 1913, pp. 31-36. 22 PETER BALDWIN laborers,attempts to distinguishbetween the dependentlyemployed and inde- pendents, focusing measures on one or the other, made little sense. The agriculturallabor force was poorly paid because remunerationwas still partly in natura, because rural conditions hindered workers' claims for higher in- comes, and because costs were low in the countryside. Contributorysocial insuranceof the sort Bismarck had aimed at the urban worker aristocracy, could help the agriculturallabor force only if farmers raised wages. State financing, however, especially in the context of longstanding agrariande- mands for tax reform, provided a solution. The tax system of nineteenth- century Denmark had evolved to suit the needs of a predominantlyrural nation in which tillers of the soil had not yet developed the political clout to shift burdenselsewhere. Direct taxes on land and its products supplied the local administrationson which the cost of poor relief fell. The manufacturing and industrialclasses were treated leniently. Social policy financed through indirectstate taxes helped shift the cost of poor relief and local taxes to urban groups. Even though an income tax, long a liberal agrariandemand, was not introduceduntil afterthe turnof the century, farmerswere convinced that the consumptiontaxes now used for statutorysocial policy would afflict urban more than rural workers. Before the era of graduatedincome taxes, state- financed welfare policy in effect shifted the weight of social risk away from the most progressivelyassessed levies of the period, cadastraltaxes, and onto the shoulders both of the liberals' urban opponents and of those classes supposedly among the direct beneficiaries of the new measures. In Sweden, matters took a somewhat different course. Well-developed, efficient, and insulated by the rudimentarynature of Swedish politics from outside pressures,the governmentbureaucracy was initially able to formulate plans for social reform that followed lessons learned from Bismarck more closely than native social circumstancesand the wishes of not yet powerful groups. Reformers at first set their sights on contributorysocial insurance restrictedto the working class. But, while capable of formulatingreforms in isolation, they could not pass and implementmeasures that ignoredthe wishes of importantinterests.70 Because antagonismsbetween liberals and conser- vatives, and ruraland urbangroups, were less pronouncedthan in Denmark, the main dispute in Sweden arose between farmersand the powerful govern- ment bureaucracythat was eventually forced to consider their desires. At- tempts at reform were stymied for over two decades until, in 1913, Sweden finally implemented universalist, largely tax-financed, pensions. This ar-

70 This is, of course, where the analysis here differs most markedlyfrom that in Hugh Heclo, Modern Social Politics in Britain and Sweden (New Haven, 1974), and in other attempts to "bring the state back in," for example, Ann Shola Orloff and Theda Skocpol, "Why Not Equal Protection?Explaining the Politics of Public Social Spending in Britain, 1900-1911, and the United States, 1880s-1920," AmericanSociological Review, 49: 6 (December 1984), 726-50; and, more generally, Peter B. Evans et al., eds., Bringing the State Back In (Cambridge, 1985). SCANDINAVIAN ORIGINS OF WELFARE STATE 23 rangementrejected Bismarck's legacy, anticipatedBeveridge, and embodied the major features later regardedas the essence of the Nordic welfare state. Far from being the realizationof demands put forth by the oppressed or the Left, they reflected farmers' wishes not to be deprived of state-subsidized measuresthat were otherwise targetedat workers only. In the social interpretationof the welfare state, Bismarck's reforms ex- emplified social policy used for reactionary,Bonapartist purposes. They were limited to workers, who posed the most immediate threatto social stability. Benefits were differentiatedby income to preserve the hierarchies of the marketplaceeven outside its sphere. Financingwas assuredthrough employer and workerpremiums with little state financing in orderto hold redistribution to a minimum. The Scandinavian welfare states, on the contrary, were qualitativelydifferent in realizingthe need of the disadvantagedfor solidarity. Nordic social policy supposedlydemonstrated that real reformcould be wrung from the privileged by the oppressed themselves, on their own terms. It embodied equality, not hierarchy; consensus, not conflict; solidarity, not separatism. Scandinavian measures were universal in their embrace of all citizens. They were financed through taxes that fairly apportionedburdens and had a penchantfor being formally egalitarianflat-rate benefits. The social interpretationanachronistically attributes these features to the power of the social democratsand the working class. Decisions in favor of universalist, tax-financed, egalitarian measures were taken before the so- cialists had much say in the matter and often against their will. The cor- nerstoneof the unique Nordic welfare edifice was set alreadyduring the late nineteenthcentury, not in the 1930s or after World War II, when the social democratsgained power. Social insurancehad been formulatedfirst in Ger- many to deal with well-paid urban workers. In Scandinavia, these classes could not be the focus. North of the Eider, priorities were defined by the emerging agrarianmiddle classes. Scandinavianpensions were made univer- salist because farmersrefused to be excluded from these new forms of statuto- ry generosity. They were tax-financedbecause, in this way, the ruralclasses expected to gain more than they lost. State-financedsocial policy is no better than the tax system on which it rests. To attributethe (often dubious) pro- gressivity of twentieth-centurymeasures to an earlier period is to misunder- standthe natureof battles then fought out between social groups, in the guise of fiscal and welfare reform. In Scandinaviaof the late nineteenth century, government-financedsocial policy was an element of a drawn-out dispute between ruraland urbanelites whose resolutionallowed farmersto shift social burdensto their urbanopponents. Both of these characteristics-universality and tax financing-did, in fact, later become progressive, solidaristicaspects of welfare policy in the North. When the decision was first made to follow this Sonderweg in Scandinavian social policy, however, these featureswere the result of demandsput forth by 24 PETER BALDWIN the emergingagrarian middle classes on theirown behalf. Such characteristics were not created,only continued,by the socialists in the 1930s and later. This is not necessarily to denigratethese aspects of Scandinaviansocial policy. It is, however, to take a realistic look at their genealogies and to make an accurate appraisal of their origins, one that can explain why the Nordic welfare states were unusual without resortingeither to the vagueness of sup- posedly unique Scandinavian social virtues or to the anachronism of so- cialism's heroic marchin these most quintessentiallypetty bourgeois of Euro- pean nations. The origins of virtue turn out to be mundane:The solidarity of one age has its roots in the selfishness of another.