Is It Time to Draw the Line?: the Impact of Redistricting on Competition in State House Elections

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Is It Time to Draw the Line?: the Impact of Redistricting on Competition in State House Elections 6122_04_p144-157 3/31/06 10:30 AM Page 144 ELECTION LAW JOURNAL Volume 5, Number 2, 2006 © Mary Ann Liebert, Inc. Is It Time to Draw the Line?: The Impact of Redistricting on Competition in State House Elections DAVID LUBLIN and MICHAEL P. MCDONALD LECTION OBSERVERS of the House of Repre- factors explain declining competition in con- Esentatives have decried the decline of com- gressional elections, their presence should also petition for U.S. House seats. Sam Hirsch notes be associated with lower levels of competition that the number of incumbents reelected by in state legislative elections. Moreover, redis- over 20 points in the post-reapportionment tricting arguably has even greater conse- election of 2002 was much higher than the av- quences in state legislative elections. Congres- erage of other recent post-reapportionment sional redistricting occurs on a state-by-state elections.1 Noted political scientists Bernard basis so no single redistricting authority con- Grofman and Gary Jacobson agree with this as- trols the national process. But power over re- sessment. They show that the number of com- districting at the state level influences the shape petitive seats has declined over the past 40 of the entire state legislature. The potential im- years when measured by the number of seats pact of partisan gerrymandering is therefore won by less than either ten or twenty percent. much greater at the state than the federal level. Like Hirsch, they note that congressional com- This paper takes a first cut at examining com- petition in 2002 was exceptionally low for a petition outside of the congressional election post-reapportionment election. Grofman and arena by exploring the aggregate level of com- Jacobson suggest competition will reach record petition in lower chamber state legislative elec- lows later in the decade if the pattern of de- tions in 37 states in 2000 and 2004. While this clining competition post-redistricting in the study is only a first step toward exploring com- 1980s and 1990s is followed.2 Much of the petition in state legislative races, it should be blame for the decline in congressional compe- highly useful to illuminate the level of compe- tition has been attached to the partisan and in- tition in state legislative elections, and see cumbent-protection redistricting processes and whether theories of the impact of redistricting racial redistricting.3 on electoral competition appear to hold water The focus on congressional elections is nat- outside of the congressional arena from which ural due to the importance of the federal legis- they were abstracted. Before turning to the sta- lature but scholars ought to study competition in state legislative elections more closely. Par- tisan and incumbent protection gerrymander- ing and racial redistricting also occur during 1 Sam Hirsch, “The United States House of Unrepresen- the redrawing of state legislative maps. If these tatives: What Went Wrong in the Latest Round of Con- gressional Redistricting,” Election Law Journal 2: 2(2003): 182–4 2 Bernard Grofman and Gary Jacobson, Vieth v. Jubelirer, Brief as Amici Curiae in Support of Neither Party, No. 02- David Lublin is Associate Professor of Government in the 1580 (August 2003). School of Public Affairs at American University (dlublin@ 3 The claim that redistricting has reduced competitive american.edu). Michael P. McDonald is Assistant Profes- elections appears in editorial pages across the political sor of Public and International Affairs at George Mason spectrum (e.g., The Wall Street Journal. 2004. “No Contest.” University and Visiting Fellow at the Brookings Institu- Nov. 12, 2004. The Washington Post. 2003. “The Partisan tion ([email protected]). Fix” September 14, 2003: B06.) 144 6122_04_p144-157 3/31/06 10:30 AM Page 145 REDISTRICTING AND COMPETITION IN STATE HOUSE ELECTIONS 145 tistical analysis of the level of competition in the efforts of GOP mapmakers to secure a safe state legislative elections and explanations for majority of seats for their party. Forty percent variations among the states, the article briefly of Indiana’s fifty congressional races between explores how partisan gerrymandering and 1982 and 1990 were won with less than 60 per- racial redistricting may undermine competi- cent of the vote and 26 percent were won by tion. less than 55 percent.5 Democrats may miscalculate when they draw redistricting plans, too. Prior to the 2002 PARTISAN GERRYMANDERING, elections, Democrats hoped to win seven out of RACIAL REDISTRICTING, AND thirteen seats in Georgia’s newly expanded ELECTORAL COMPETITION congressional delegation. However, Georgia Republicans increased their support in 2002, Much of the blame for the decline in compe- winning the governor’s mansion for the first tition in congressional elections has been time since Reconstruction. Republicans man- placed on the highly political process used to aged to edge out Democrats in two of the conduct redistricting in most states. Partisan “Democratic” seats. Democrats won only five gerrymanders, such as those enacted by Demo- seats and one of their five winners gained his crats in Maryland and Republicans in Penn- seat by only a one percent margin over his Re- sylvania, attempt to pack many minority party publican opponent.6 voters into a few districts and to limit concen- Due to failed partisan gerrymanders, like trations of minority party voters outside these those in Indiana and Georgia, some believe districts to make it possible for the majority partisan gerrymandering increases electoral party to win the remaining districts as easily as competition. Burham argues that: “ . parti- possible. The ideal partisan gerrymander packs san gerrymandering is the best producer of as many minority party voters into as few dis- competitive districts”7 because parties may act tricts as possible while guaranteeing the ma- sub-optimally in their quest to maximize seats, jority party a solid, but not overwhelming, ma- inadvertently shave their margins too close, jority in the other districts. The majority party and thereby create competitive districts. Burn- must be careful to balance the distribution of ham offers the unsuccessful Republican gerry- voters most efficiently against the desire to as- mander of New York’s congressional seats in sure that their candidate can carry the district 1961 as an example. However, Burnham notes solidly even if there is an electoral swing that “ . comparable efforts have been re- against the party.4 soundingly successful,”8 and provides analysis If the majority party spreads its voters too of successful partisan gerrymanders in eight thinly, overestimates it support, or if there is other states. an electoral swing against it, the plan may not work as intended. For example, Indiana Re- publicans crafted a plan designed to give their 4 Guillermo Owen and Bernard Grofman, “Optimal Par- party a majority of the state’s congressional tisan Gerrymandering.” Political Geography Quarterly, 7: 1(1988) 5–22; Bruce E. Cain, The Reapportionment Puzzle seats throughout the 1980s. The plan worked (Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 1984). reasonably well at first. The Indiana congres- 5 Congressional Elections: 1946–1996 (Washington: Con- sional delegation went from 6-5 Democratic in gressional Quarterly, 1998): 283, 288, 293, 298, 304. 6 Democrats defeated one Republican incumbent in 2004. 1980 to 6-4 Republican in 1982. However, Indi- See Brian Nutting and H. Amy Stern, eds., CQ’s Politics ana Democrats ran strong candidates and in America 2002: The 107th Congress (Washington: Con- gained support over the decade. By 1990, the gressional Quarterly, 2001): 254–81; David Hawkings and Brian Nutting, eds., CQ’s Politics in America 2004: The delegation was 8-2 Democratic—hardly the in- 108th Congress (Washington: Congressional Quarterly, tent of the Republicans who pushed the plan. 2003): 265–92. The failure of the partisan gerrymander had 7 Walter Dean Burham, “Congressional Representation: positive consequences for electoral competi- Theory and Practice of Drawing the Districts” in Reap- portionment in the 1970s. ed, Nelson W. Polsby (Berkeley, tion. Indiana saw a number of congressional CA: University of California Press, 1971): 277. seats change hands during the 1980s despite 8 Id. at 276. 6122_04_p144-157 3/31/06 10:30 AM Page 146 146 LUBLIN AND MCDONALD Both Democrats and Republicans have often California also adopted incumbent protec- augmented their number of seats through par- tion gerrymanders for the state legislature.12 tisan gerrymandering and limited electoral The share of competitive seats dropped, though competition in the process. Arizona Republi- not by as much as the share of marginal con- cans corralled Democrats into a single district gressional seats. In 2000, 20 percent of the 80 in the 1980s by linking the Democratic portions Assembly seats were won by less than 20 of Phoenix and Tucson with Yuma across hun- points, and 10 percent were won by less than dreds of miles of empty desert. Except for one 10 points.13 The share of seats won by less than narrow victory in 1982, Democrats failed to win 20 points fell to 11 percent in 2002 before ris- any congressional elections outside of Ari- ing again to 16 percent in 2004. The share of zona’s Second District from 1982 through 1990. districts where the winner had a 10-point mar- In all but three of the 25 elections held during gin of victory dropped to 5 percent in 2002 and this period, the winner’s margin of victory ex- 6 percent in 2004. ceeded 20 percent.9 The presence of two chambers in all state leg- Maryland Democrats managed to shift the islatures, except Nebraska, makes possible the partisan makeup of their state’s congressional adoption of a different sort of incumbent pro- delegation from a 4-4 even split in 2000 to 6-2 tection gerrymander, where a party cedes con- Democratic in 2002 by manipulating the trol over redistricting in one chamber in ex- boundaries of the state’s districts.
Recommended publications
  • Towards Public Financing of Elections and Political Parties in India: Lessons from Global Experiences
    NOVEMBER 2017 Towards Public Financing of Elections and Political Parties in India: Lessons from Global Experiences NIRANJAN SAHOO Towards Public Financing of Elections and Political Parties in India: Lessons from Global Experiences NIRANJAN SAHOO ABOUT THE AUTHOR Niranjan Sahoo is a Senior Fellow at Observer Research Foundation, with many years of expertise on issues of governance, democracy, campaign finance reforms, insurgency, and conflict studies. He serves as a member of the Carnegie Rising Democracies Network (RDN) in Washington, D.C. ISBN : 978-93-87407-13-8 © 2017 Observer Research Foundation. All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced or transmitted in any form or by any means without permission in writing from ORF. Towards Public Financing of Elections and Political Parties in India: Lessons from Global Experiences ABSTRACT Democracy costs a lot of money. To fight elections and run their routine activities, political parties in India seek donations from all possible sources including “illegal” and “interested” money. This has serious ramifications in preserving the integrity of Indian democracy. An increasing number of countries, meanwhile, have taken the path of public subsidies and direct funding of parties and political activities—aiming to reduce dependence on interested money, equalise political opportunity, and bring greater transparency and accountability to democratic processes. By better targeting state subsidies, countries like Germany and the UK, for example, have made strides in reducing the role of interested money in elections and bringing visible transparency in their electoral politics. While India cannot take a leaf out of these experiences, there is a lot to learn from them.
    [Show full text]
  • A Drawback of Electoral Competition!
    A Drawback of Electoral Competition Alessandro Lizzeri Nicola Persico New York University and CEPRy University of Pennsylvaniaz x Abstract In most major democracies there are very few parties compared to the number of possible policy positions held by voters. We provide an e¢ ciency rationale for why it might be appropriate to limit the proliferation of parties. In our model, the larger is the number of parties, the greater the ine¢ ciency Acknowledgments: We would like to thank two anonymous referees and Xavier Vives for helpful comments. We gratefully acknowledge …nancial support from the NSF under grants SBR 9911496 and 9905564, respectively. We are grateful to Johannes Horner, Antonio Merlo, Roger Myerson, Wolfgang Pesendorfer, Michele Piccione, Chun Seng Yip, and especially Herve Roche. yDepartment of Economics, 269 Mercer Street, New York, NY 10003. Web: http://www.econ.nyu.edu/user/lizzeria zDepartment of Economics, 3718 Locust Walk, Philadelphia PA 19104-6297. Web: http://www.ssc.upenn.edu/~persico/. xE-mail addresses: Lizzeri <[email protected]>, Persico <[email protected]>. 1 of the outcome of electoral competition. The reason is that when the number of parties increases, electoral incentives push each party to focus its electoral promises on a narrower constituency, and special interest policies replace more e¢ cient policies which have di¤use bene…ts. The analysis provides a possible explanation for the existence of insti- tutional features that limit the extent of electoral competition: thresholds of exclusion, run-o¤ electoral systems, and majoritarian two-party political systems. JEL classi…cation: D82, L15 2 1 Introduction Political parties seem to be few, especially when compared to the number of distinct preference pro…les held by voters.
    [Show full text]
  • Seat Safety and Female (Under)Representation in the U.S. Congress
    Seat safety and female (under)representation in the U.S. Congress Akhil Rajan, Alexander Kustov, Maikol Cerda, Frances Rosenbluth, Ian Shapiro Yale University Draft: May 17, 2021 Abstract Women have made significant strides toward equal representation within the U.S. Congress, but their seat share has mostly increased within the Democratic—but not Republican—Party. We argue that one driver of women’s underrepresentation among Republicans is the proliferation of safe seats. Because safe seats encourage ideological extremism in candidates and because women are stereotyped as more liberal than men, we expect women candidates to outperform men in safer Democratic seats but underperform men in safer Republican seats (relative to more competitive seats). Based on a new dataset linking all candidates for the U.S. House and their districts’ partisan composition since 2000, we show women both enter and win elections in safer Republican (Democratic) seats at relatively lower (higher) rates than men. Our results strikingly suggest that, even conditional on running, a female Republican candidate has an overall better chance of winning in a competitive seat than in a safe Republican seat. Keywords: Congress, Gender, Representation, Inequality, Electoral Competition Word count: 3700 Introduction After a record number of women won election to the United States Congress, many commentators declared 2018 to be the “Year of the Woman.” But the use of a caveat is warranted: if 2018 was the year of the woman, it must have been the year of the Democratic woman. By contrast, Republican women lost a whopping ten seats, their largest decline in the history of the United States House of Representatives.
    [Show full text]
  • Electoral Competition and Factional Sabotage ∗
    ∗ Electoral Competition and Factional Sabotage y Giovanna M. Invernizzi December 6, 2020 Abstract Intra-party sabotage is a widespread phenomenon that undermines the strength of political parties. What brings opposing factions to engage in sabotage rather than enhancing the party image, and what strategies can parties adopt to contain it? This paper presents a model of elections in which intra-party factions can devote resources to campaign for the party or to undermine each other and obtain more power. The party redistributes electoral spoils among factions to motivate their investment in campaigning activities. The model shows that sabotage increases when the stakes of the election are low | e.g., in consensus democracies that grant power to the losing party | because the incentives to focus on the fight for internal power increase. It also suggests that the optimal party strategy for winning the election in the face of intra-party competition is to reward factions with high powered incentives when campaigning effort can be easily monitored, but treat factions equally otherwise. Keywords: Party Organization, Electoral Competition, Party Factions, Sabotage. ∗ I am grateful to Peter Buisseret, Alessandra Casella, Sean Gailmard, German Gieczewski, John Huber, Matias Iaryczower, Federica Izzo, Korhan Kocak, Nikitas Konstantinidis, Carlo Prato, Manuel Puente, Gregory Sasso, Michael Ting, Stephane Wolton and 2019-20 LSE students enrolled in GV4J6 for their feedback and their suggestions. I would also like to thank audience members at the Princeton Political Economy Workshop, the 2019 MPSA Annual Meeting, the 2019 and 2020 APSA Annual Meeting, and the 2020 Virtual Formal Theory Workshop. yDepartment of Political Science, Columbia University, Email: [email protected] Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3329622 1.
    [Show full text]
  • ANALYSIS: Patterns of Violence in the Pre- Electoral Period (3-18 Months Before Polls)
    ANALYSIS: Patterns of Violence in the Pre- Electoral Period (3-18 months before polls) ANALYSIS: Patterns of Violence in the Pre-Electoral Period Definition “…Acts or threats of coercion, intimidation or physical harm perpetrated to affect an electoral process or that arises in the context of electoral competition. When perpetrated to affect an electoral process, violence may be employed to influence the process of elections – such as efforts to delay, disrupt, or derail a poll – and to influence the outcomes: the determining of winners in competitive races for political office or to secure approval or disapproval of referendum questions.” UNDP, Timothy Sisk 2009 “Electoral conflict and violence can be defined as any random or organised act or threat to intimidate, physically harm, blackmail or abuse a political stakeholder in seeking to determine, delay, or to otherwise influence an electoral process.” Jeff Fischer 2002 Early phases TOR INSTITUTIONAL CONSTITUTION STRENGTHENING & • Skewing the playingPROFESSIONAL field LEGISLATION DEVELOPMENT AUDITS & ELECTORAL EVALUATIONS ELECTORAL BODIES • Disputes over rulesLEGAL REFORM SYSTEM & BOUNDARIES VOTERS’ LISTS ARCHIVING & UPDATE RESEARCH CODES OF CONDUCT BUDGETING, • Primaries or party FUNDING & OFFICIAL FINANCING RESULTS POST ELECTION LEGAL nominations FRAMEWORK ELECTION CALENDAR COMPLAINTS & APPEALS RECRUITMENT & • Voter registration PROCUREMENT TABULATION OF VERIFICATION OF PLANNING & LOGISTICS & SECURITY RESULTS RESULTS IMPLEMENTATION THE ELECTORAL CYCLE ELEC OPERATIONAL VOTING T- TRAINING
    [Show full text]
  • Electoral Rules and Democratic Electoral Rules, and Governance Democratic Governance Edited by Mala Htun and G
    Report of the Political Science, Task Force on Electoral Rules and Democratic Electoral Rules, and Governance Democratic Governance Edited by Mala Htun and G. Bingham Powell, Jr. AMERICAN POLITICAL SCIENCE AssOCIATION n TasK FORCE REPORT, SEPTEMBER 2013 Political Science, Electoral Rules, and Democratic Governance Report of the Task Force on Electoral Rules and Democratic Governance Edited by Mala Htun and G. Bingham Powell, Jr. SEPTEMBER 2013 AMERICAN POLITICAL SCIENCE AssOCIATION 1527 New Hampshire Avenue, NW Washington, DC 20036-1206 Copyright © 2013 by the American Political Science Association. All rights reserved. ISBN: 978-1-878147-41-7 Task Force on Electoral Rules and Democratic Governance Task Force Members Mala Htun, University of New Mexico, Chair G. Bingham Powell, Jr., University of Rochester; President, APSA, 2011–12 John Carey, Dartmouth College Karen E. Ferree, University of California, San Diego Simon Hix, London School of Economics Mona Lena Krook, Rutgers University Robert G. Moser, University of Texas, Austin Shaheen Mozaffar, Bridgewater State University Andrew Rehfeld, Washington University in St. Louis Andrew Reynolds, University of North Carolina, Chapel Hill Ethan Scheiner, University of California, Davis Melissa Schwartzberg, Columbia University Matthew S. Shugart, University of California, Davis ii American Political Science Assocation Table of Contents TASK FORCE MEMBERS ............................................................................................................................. ii LIST OF
    [Show full text]
  • Redistribution Under the Right in Latin America
    CPSXXX10.1177/0010414017695331Comparative Political StudiesFairfield and Garay 695331research-article2017 Article Comparative Political Studies 2017, Vol. 50(14) 1871 –1906 Redistribution Under © The Author(s) 2017 Reprints and permissions: the Right in Latin sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav https://doi.org/10.1177/0010414017695331DOI: 10.1177/0010414017695331 America: Electoral journals.sagepub.com/home/cps Competition and Organized Actors in Policymaking Tasha Fairfield1 and Candelaria Garay2 Abstract Unexpected social policy expansion and progressive tax reforms initiated by right-wing governments in Latin America highlight the need for further theory development on the politics of redistribution. We focus on electoral competition for low-income voters in conjunction with the power of organized actors—both business and social movements. We argue that electoral competition motivates redistribution under left-wing and right- wing incumbents alike although such initiatives are more modest when conservatives dominate and business is well organized. Social mobilization drives more substantial redistribution by counterbalancing business power and focusing incumbents on securing social peace and surviving in office. By characterizing distinctive features of social-policy politics and tax-policy politics and theorizing linkages between the two realms, we contribute to broader debates on the relative influence of voters versus organized interests in policymaking. We apply our theory to explain “least-likely” cases 1London School of Economics and Political Science, UK 2Harvard University, Cambridge, MA, USA Corresponding Author: Tasha Fairfield, London School of Economics and Political Science, Connaught House, London WC2A 2AE, UK. Email: [email protected] 1872 Comparative Political Studies 50(14) of redistributive policies under conservative governments in Mexico (2000- 2012) and Chile (2010-2014).
    [Show full text]
  • Electoral Competition for Outsiders, Conservative Power, and Restrictive Social Policy in Mexico
    Electoral Competition for Outsiders, Conservative Power, and Restrictive Social Policy in Mexico The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters Citation Garay, Candelaria. 2016. "Electoral Competition for Outsiders, Conservative Power, and Restrictive Social Policy in Mexico." In Social Policy Expansion in Latin America, 222-60. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Published Version https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316585405.006 Citable link http://nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:37108551 Terms of Use This article was downloaded from Harvard University’s DASH repository, and is made available under the terms and conditions applicable to Other Posted Material, as set forth at http:// nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:dash.current.terms-of- use#LAA Social Policy Expansion in Latin America CANDELARIA GARAY Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University CAMBRIDGE UN!VERSITY PRESS CAMBRIDGE UNIVERSITY PRESS One Liberty Plaza, New York, NY rooo6, USA Cambridge University Press is part of the University of Cambridge. It furthers the University's mission by disseminating knowledge in the pursuit of education, Iearning, and research at the highest international Ievels of excellence. www.cambridge.org Information on this title: www.cambridge.org/978r3 r6606407 ro.ror7/978 r 3 r658 5405 © Candelaria Garay 2or6 This publication is in copyright. Subject to statutory exception and to the provisions of relevant collective licensing agreements, no reproduction of any part may take place without the written permission of Cambridge University Press. First published 20 r 6 Printed in the United States of America by Sheridan Books, Inc.
    [Show full text]
  • Electoral Competition and Politician Behavior in India∗
    Too Close to Call: Electoral Competition and Politician Behavior in India∗ Mahvish Shaukaty December 30, 2018 Click HERE for latest version. Abstract This paper presents empirical evidence on the causal effect of electoral competition on political selection and performance. Identifying the effect of competition is challenging due to reverse causality: politician actions before an election determine the competi- tiveness of a race. To overcome this challenge, I propose a shift-share instrument that exploits aggregate shifts in political parties' popularity over time. Unlike the tradi- tional shift-share, these aggregate shifts affect electoral competition across constituen- cies non-monotonically: a positive shift in a party's popularity decreases competition in the party's stronghold, and increases competition where voters prefer the opposi- tion. The instrument relies on this non-monotonicity for identification. Using data on Indian state elections, I find parties respond strategically to competition prior to an election by selecting higher quality candidates and reallocating resources to swing constituencies. The most striking result is in the negative selection of candidates with criminal backgrounds, who are significantly less likely to run in a competitive election. Competitive constituencies also experience a significant, though temporary, increase in night lights. Despite changes in campaign strategy prior to an election, however, I find no evidence that politicians elected in competitive constituencies improve economic outcomes once in office, either through selection or moral hazard. Together, these re- sults suggest that while electoral competition can lead politicians to take costly actions prior to an election, it does not necessarily result in improved governance. Keywords: Electoral competition, political selection, governance JEL Codes: D72, O17, O43 ∗I am extremely grateful to my advisors Abhijit Banerjee, Esther Duflo, and Ben Olken for their in- valuable guidance and support.
    [Show full text]
  • Does Simultaneous Elections Encourage Voting
    ESTUDIOS SOBRE LA ECONOMÍA ESPAÑOLA Influencing ‘Rational Voters’? The Effect of Simultaneous Calls in Regional Elections Turnout Joan Costa-Font Ricard Ramon –Sumoy EEE 216 November 2006 ISSN 1696-6384 Las opiniones contenidas en los Documentos de la Serie EEE, reflejan exclusivamente las de los autores y no necesariamente las de FEDEA. The opinions in the EEE Series are the responsibility of the authors an therefore, do not necessarily coincide with those of the FEDEA. INFLUENCING ‘RATIONAL VOTERS’? THE EFFECT OF SIMULTANEOUS CALLS IN REGIONAL ELECTIONS TURNOUT JOAN COSTA-FONT* Universitat de Barcelona and London School of Economics RICARD RAMON –SUMOY Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona * Contact address: Dr Joan Costa -i-Font, London School of Economics, Cowdray House, J7, Houghton Street, WC2A 2AE, London. E-mail: [email protected] Acknowledgements: This research was supported by the Ministry of Education (Grant number: CICYT SEJ2005-06270) and the Generalitat de Catalunya (Grant number: 2005-SGR-460). 1 Abstract. Rational voting models assume turnout results from net benefits being positive. However, low turnout questions the legitimacy of democracies, especially when it affects newly created institutional structures such as those resulting from decentralisation processes. In this paper we empirically estimate whether turnout rates of “less decisive” elections can be increased by the coincidence of several elections. We use a unique data from Spanish regional elections 1980-1999 where low turn out would influence institutional legitimacy of newly created regional state in a novel democracy. We employ controls for economic voting namely: inflation, unemployment and regional income. Our empirical findings illustrate that simultaneity systematically increases individuals average turnout regardless of the elections considered and that regional income reduces turnout.
    [Show full text]
  • Psephological Fallacies of Public Opinion Polling
    SPECIAL ARTICLE Psephological Fallacies of Public Opinion Polling Praveen Rai Opinion polls in India capture electoral snapshots in time he terms “survey” and “opinion poll” in India would that divulge information on political participation, have remained a professional jargon of market research industry, had it not been used for predicting election ideological orientation of voters and belief in core T outcomes. The green shoots of opinion polls to study Indian democratic values. The survey data provides for crucial national elections emerged in the 1950s, but it caught the ima- social science insights, validation of theoretical research gination of the people and became clichéd in the closing dec- and academic knowledge production. Although the ade of the 20th century. The popularity of election surveys stems from the political socialisation and crystal ball gazing media’s obsession with political forecasting has shifted curiosity of Indians to foresee the outcomes of hustings before to electoral prophecy, psephology continues to provide the pronouncement of formal results. The electoral inquisitive- the best telescopic view of elections based on the ness of the stakeholders created a large canvas of opportunity feedback of citizens. The ascertainment of subaltern for opinion-polling industry and scope for scientifi c forecasting of Indian election competitions. The proliferation of electronic opinion by surveys not only broadens the contours of media and the rapid monetisation in the 1990s provided mo- understanding electoral democracy, but also provides mentum to polling agencies to venture into opinion polling on an empirical alternative to the elitist viewpoint of national electoral politics and state election contests. The opin- competitive politics in India.
    [Show full text]
  • Electoral Rules and Politicians' Behavior
    IZA DP No. 3348 Electoral Rules and Politicians’ Behavior: A Micro Test Stefano Gagliarducci Tommaso Nannicini Paolo Naticchioni DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES DISCUSSION PAPER February 2008 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor Electoral Rules and Politicians’ Behavior: A Micro Test Stefano Gagliarducci CEMFI and IZA Tommaso Nannicini Universidad Carlos III and IZA Paolo Naticchioni University of Rome La Sapienza Discussion Paper No. 3348 February 2008 IZA P.O. Box 7240 53072 Bonn Germany Phone: +49-228-3894-0 Fax: +49-228-3894-180 E-mail: [email protected] Any opinions expressed here are those of the author(s) and not those of IZA. Research published in this series may include views on policy, but the institute itself takes no institutional policy positions. The Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) in Bonn is a local and virtual international research center and a place of communication between science, politics and business. IZA is an independent nonprofit organization supported by Deutsche Post World Net. The center is associated with the University of Bonn and offers a stimulating research environment through its international network, workshops and conferences, data service, project support, research visits and doctoral program. IZA engages in (i) original and internationally competitive research in all fields of labor economics, (ii) development of policy concepts, and (iii) dissemination of research results and concepts to the interested public. IZA Discussion Papers often represent preliminary work and are circulated to encourage discussion. Citation of such a paper should account for its provisional character. A revised version may be available directly from the author.
    [Show full text]