EU & Competition Law Update

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

EU & Competition Law Update EU & Competition Law Update October 2013 CJEU reaffirms parent company liability for competition law Key Contacts infringement The Court of Justice of the European Union (CJEU) dismissed an appeal by For further details on Alliance One International on 26 September 2013 of a decision upholding the these articles and other European Commission’s fines against a raw tobacco cartel in Spain, (see Case developments please C-668/11 P Alliance One International Inc. v European Commission.) contact one of the following authors or your In October 2004, the Commission fined (amongst others), the Spanish raw usual Bryan Cave contact: tobacco producer, Agroexpansion EUR 2.59 million, for participation in a raw tobacco cartel concerning the delivery price for tobacco. The parent company Robert Bell of Agroexpansion, Alliance One International Inc. (Alliance), then called Dimon Partner - London Inc., was held jointly and severally responsible for the payment of the fine. Eckart Budelmann Alliance was held responsible on the basis that it exercised a decisive influence Partner – Hamburg over the conduct of Agroexpansion as owner of its entire share capital. Kathie Claret Partner – Paris Alliance appealed this finding to the General Court which rejected the appeal, Anita Esslinger upholding the Commission’s decision that liability should be on a joint and Partner – London several basis between parent and subsidiary. Following this rejection, Alliance further appealed the decision of the General Court to the CJEU. Luigi Zumbo Partner – Milan* The CJEU’s judgment affirms its continuing desire for parents and their subsidiary companies to be found jointly and severally liable. The CJEU affirmed the dictum from Case C97/08 Akzo Nobel NV and others v Commission that where a parent company owns the entire share capital of another company, there is a rebuttable presumption that the parent exercises decisive influence over the behaviour and actions of that subsidiary, and therefore, should be jointly and severally liable for its actions. The CJEU stated however, that the presumption can be used in conjunction with evidence to establish such influence. The rebuttable presumption was not necessarily used exclusively to establish whether influence was present between parent and subsidiary. It was and remains possible to judge the relationship both in the context of a rebuttable presumption, but also to allow Bryan Cave's and assess further evidence that the influence exists. alerts/bulletins/briefings are available online. This Client Bulletin is published for the clients and friends of Bryan Cave LLP. Information contained herein is not to be considered as legal advice. This Client Bulletin may be construed as an advertisement or solicitation. Bryan Cave LLP. All Rights Reserved. *Affiliated Firm. Bryan Cave LLP America | Europe | Asia www.bryancave.com The relevance of this appeal to companies and future cartel decisions is that it allows the Commission flexibility to use evidence of influence by parent companies. It could be seen as a further evidential hurdle for defendants to overcome as in these cases they won’t simply be trying to rebut the presumption of influence, but may have to actively disprove or counter evidence introduced by the Commission that the parent held a decisive influence over its subsidiary. Company group compliance with competition law, no matter how small and distant the subsidiary, should therefore remain a priority for parent companies following this decision. Bundeskartellamt fines company for price fixing in selective distribution system I. The case In a recent decision relating to vertical price fixing practices, the Bundeskartellamt condemned a selective distribution system which violated competition law by enforcing adherence to recommended prices. On 31 July 2013, the Federal Cartel Office (Bundeskartellamt) imposed fines of approximately EUR 6.5 million on the German company WALA Heilmittel GmbH (“WALA”) because of vertical price fixing practices which included selective distribution contracts which depended on the distributors’ adherence to recommended prices. The Bundeskartellamt held that the company had put undue pressure on retailers for years, obliging them to comply with WALA’s recommended prices for its natural cosmetic products sold under the brand “Dr. Hauschka”. According to the Bundeskartellamt, ever since 2003, WALA had systematically based its distribution system on strict adherence to stipulated end consumer prices and put unreasonable pressure on retailers to prevent them from undercutting the recommended prices by threatening to deny or actually denying the supply of products. In 2007, the company introduced a “selective distribution system” which allowed supply only to selected distributors meeting certain criteria. The conclusion and continuation of the contracts with the authorised distributors was made subject to the distributors' adherence to the recommended prices. The contracts also included clauses restricting internet sales. Furthermore, the investigation uncovered evidence that the company had engaged in illegal agreements on end consumer prices for its products with several specialised retailers which are active throughout Germany. A negotiated settlement was reached between WALA and the Bundeskartellamt, and the German regulator’s investigation was terminated. WALA undertook to phrase and structure its future contracts in such a way as to ensure that (i) the contracts cannot be abused to support price fixing schemes, (ii) distributors will be treated equally and (iii) internet sales will not be restricted. II. Legal Background and Preventive Measures This case shows that the Bundeskartellamt is increasingly vigilant over anti-competitive restrictions in vertical agreements. 2 Bryan Cave LLP America | Europe | Asia www.bryancave.com Under the German Act Against Restraints of Competition (GWB) and the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (TFEU), agreements which have as their object or effect the prevention, restriction or distortion of competition, are prohibited. However, both the GWB and the TFEU allow some exemptions. The “Vertical Block Exemption Regulation” (Commission Regulation (EU) No. 330/2010 of 20 April 2010) exempts restrictions in all vertical agreements which are concluded between companies that have certain limited market power unless they are hardcore or excluded restrictions. One of these hard-core restrictions stipulates that vertical agreements which, directly or indirectly, in isolation or in combination with other factors under the control of the parties, have as their object the restriction of the buyer's ability to determine its sale price, cannot benefit from the Vertical Block Exemption. By the above decision, the Bundeskartellamt has shown that all benefits of the block exemption, including the preferential treatment of selective distribution systems, are removed if competition is restricted by way of a hardcore restriction such as resale price maintenance. When establishing a distribution system, direct, as well as indirect practices to maintain a minimum or fixed resale price are prohibited and must be avoided. This includes threatening to deny the supply of products as well as reducing incentives for companies such as making the grant of rebates or reimbursement of promotional costs by the supplier subject to the observance of a given price level to try to circumvent competition law. Ryanair condemned by the Court of Milan for abuse of a dominant position; a possible application of the “Essential facility doctrine”? The Court of Milan, in Decision No. 7825/2013 of 4th June 2013, held that Ryanair abused its dominant position by refusing to grant access to its database and booking procedures to an online travel agency (“OTA”). The Court ordered Ryanair to restore access to its database as a result of the judgment. OTAs act as an intermediary between air transport companies (like Ryanair) and consumers so that the latter is able to compare fares between airlines on the OTAs’ websites. Ryanair did not allow OTAs to access its website in order to gather relevant information about booking procedures and fares. Ryanair thus de facto would prevent consumers from comparing their fares to others whilst booking through OTAs. The Court of Milan found this conduct would violate Article 102 of TFEU and Article 3 of Italian Antitrust Law No. 287 of 1990 since it would impede OTAs access to the market of online booking to the detriment of consumers. In particular, it seems likely that the Court of Milan bore in mind the case-law of the European Courts on the so-called “Refusal to supply/Essential facilities doctrine”. In essence, the European Courts (among others: Case T-201/04 Microsoft v Commission [2007] ECR II-3601 at paras 332-3) held that the “refusal to supply” (information or product) is anti- competitive when the following conditions are met: 3 Bryan Cave LLP America | Europe | Asia www.bryancave.com a) the refusal relates to a product or service indispensable to the exercise of a particular activity on a neighbouring market; b) the refusal is of such kind as to exclude any effective competition on that neighbouring market; c) the refusal prevents the appearance of a new product for which there is potential consumer demand; and d) the refusal is not objectively justified. In the present case, there are two different markets: the air transport market and the online booking market. By Ryanair’s denial of access to OTAs, the OTAs run the risk of becoming
Recommended publications
  • Competition Law
    COMPETITION LAW SIBERGRAMME 2/2012 ISSN 1606-9986 21 August 2012 Senior Editor ROBERT LEGH Head of the Competition Law Unit of Bowman Gilfillan Inc, Johannesburg This issue by LAUREN RICHARDS and KHOFOLO KRUGER Candidate Attorneys: Bowman Gilfillan Inc Siber Ink Published by Siber Ink CC, B2A Westlake Square, Westlake Drive, Westlake 7945. © Siber Ink CC, Bowman Gilfillan Inc This Sibergramme may not be copied or forwarded without permission from Siber Ink CC Subscriptions: [email protected] or fax (+27) 086-242-3206 To view Competition Tribunal judgments, see: http://www.comptrib.co.za/ Page 2 ISSN 1606-9986 COMPETITION LAW SG 2/2012 IN THIS ISSUE: ESSENTIAL MATTERS: A COMPARATIVE ASSESSMENT OF DIFFERENT APPROACHES TO THE ESSENTIAL FACILITIES DOCTRINE............................. 2 Introduction..............................................................................................................................2 South Africa .............................................................................................................................3 The United States (US).............................................................................................................10 The European Union (EU).......................................................................................................13 Comparison of the US and EU positions .................................................................................15 Conclusion ...............................................................................................................................17
    [Show full text]
  • Ruling Within Reason: a Reprieve for Resale Price Maintenance
    Agenda Advancing economics in business Ruling within reason: a reprieve for resale price maintenance As a result of the US Supreme Court’s recent overturning of the long-standing 1911 Dr Miles decision, which deemed minimum resale price maintenance unlawful per se, this practice is to be judged under the ‘rule of reason’ in the USA, as has been the case with other vertical restraints. Is it therefore time to change the European approach to vertical price fixing? In its June 2007 judgement in Leegin Creative Leather purposes of applying Article 81(1) to demonstrate Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc, the US Supreme Court ruled any actual effects on the market.5 that resale price maintenance (RPM) should be judged under the ‘rule of reason’.1 The Leegin ruling overturned In line with the Commission’s approach, in the UK the long-standing 1911 Dr Miles precedent, which held minimum RPM is considered a hard-core practice that that it is per se unlawful under Section 1 of the Sherman ‘almost inevitably’ infringes Article 81 or the Chapter I Act for firms to fix the minimum retail price at which prohibition under the Competition Act 1998.6 Indeed, the retailers may sell goods or services on.2 Office of Fair Trading (OFT) has brought a number of high-profile vertical price fixing cases in recent years, as The outcome of the Leegin case has relieved those who discussed below. support the view that, although under certain circumstances minimum RPM may result in sub-optimal In light of the Leegin judgement, is this the time for market outcomes, this risk is not sufficient to make the European competition policy to move towards an effects- practice illegal per se.
    [Show full text]
  • Resale Price Maintenance and Minimum
    Presenting a live 90-minute webinar with interactive Q&A Resale Price Maintenance and Minimum Advertised Pricing: Structuring to Minimize Antitrust Scrutiny State, Federal, and International Treatment of RPM Agreements and MAP Policies THURSDAY, FEBRUARY 28, 2019 1pm Eastern | 12pm Central | 11am Mountain | 10am Pacific Today’s faculty features: Michael A. Lindsay, Partner, Dorsey & Whitney LLP, Minneapolis William L. Monts, III, Partner, Hogan Lovells US, Washington, D.C. The audio portion of the conference may be accessed via the telephone or by using your computer's speakers. Please refer to the instructions emailed to registrants for additional information. If you have any questions, please contact Customer Service at 1-800-926-7926 ext. 1. Tips for Optimal Quality FOR LIVE EVENT ONLY Sound Quality If you are listening via your computer speakers, please note that the quality of your sound will vary depending on the speed and quality of your internet connection. If the sound quality is not satisfactory, you may listen via the phone: dial 1-866-961-8499 and enter your PIN when prompted. Otherwise, please send us a chat or e-mail [email protected] immediately so we can address the problem. If you dialed in and have any difficulties during the call, press *0 for assistance. Viewing Quality To maximize your screen, press the F11 key on your keyboard. To exit full screen, press the F11 key again. Continuing Education Credits FOR LIVE EVENT ONLY In order for us to process your continuing education credit, you must confirm your participation in this webinar by completing and submitting the Attendance Affirmation/Evaluation after the webinar.
    [Show full text]
  • Resale Price Maintenance After Monsanto: a Doctrine Still at War with Itself*
    RESALE PRICE MAINTENANCE AFTER MONSANTO: A DOCTRINE STILL AT WAR WITH ITSELF* TERRY CALVANI** AND ANDREW G. BERG*** In this article, two enforcement officials at the Federal Trade Com- mission reexamine resale price maintenance in light of the Supreme Court's recent decision in Monsanto Co. v. Spray-Rite Service Corp. Commissioner Calvani and Mr. Berg consider both antitrust law and economic policy in their review of the history of resale price mainte- nance; they point out the chronic inconsistencies to which this antitrust regime has been subject, and identify these same inconsistenciesat work in Monsanto. The authorsset forth three theses with respect to Mon- santo: first, that the Court intimated a willingness to reconsiderat some future time the per se standardof illegalityfor resale price maintenance; second, that the Court recognized the continuing vitality of the Colgate doctrine, which had been seriously questionedin recent years; and, third, that the Monsanto Court unsuccessfully attempted to delineate a work- able evidentiary standard applicable to communications between sellers and resellers when it is alleged that such communications constitute an illegal contract, combination, or consiracy under section one of the Sherman Act. The authorssuggest that, taken together, these elements in Monsanto display a doctrine at war with itself The authorsconclude by examining the possible implications of the Monsanto decisionfor the future direction of the law of resale price maintenance. Typically, antitrust issues do not generate widespread public inter- est; there is, however, a considerable amount of such interest in resale price maintenance,' as evidenced by numerous articles on the subject in newspapers and periodicals of general circulation.2 This high level of © 1984 Terry Calvani & Andrew G.
    [Show full text]
  • Resale Price Maintenance: Economic Theories and Empirical Evidence
    "RESALE PRICE MAINTENANCE: ECONOMIC THEORIES AND EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE Thomas R. Overstreet, Jr. Bureau of Economics Staff Report to the Federal Trade Commission November 1983 RESALF. PRICE INTF.NANCE: ECONO IC THEORIES AND PIRICAL EVIDENCE Thomas R. Overstreet, Jr. Bureau of Economics Staff Report to the Federal Trade Commiss ion November 1983 . FEDERAL TRDE COM~ISSION -f. JAMES C. ~ILLER, III, Chairman MICHAEL PERTSCHUK, Commissioner PATRICIA P. BAILEY, Commissioner GEORGE W. DOUGLAS, Commissioner TERRY CALVANI, Commi S5 ioner BUREAU OF ECONO~ICS WENDY GRA~, Director RONALD S. BOND, Deputy Director for Operations and Research RICHARD HIGGINS, Deputy Director for Consumer Protection and Regulatory Analysis JOHN L. PETE , Associate Director for Special Projects DAVID T. SCHEFF N, Deputy Director for Competition and Anti trust PAUL PAUTLER, Assistant to Deputy Director for Competition and Antitrust JOHN E. CALFEE, Special Assistant to the Director JAMES A. HURDLE, Special Assistant to . the Director THOMAS WALTON, Special Assistant to the Director KEITH B. ANDERSON, Assistant Director of Regulatory Analysis JAMES M. FERGUSON, Assistant Director for Antitrust PAULINE IPPOLITO, Assistant Director for Industry Analysis WILLIAM F. LONG, ~anager for Line of Business PHILIP NELSON, Assistant Director for Competition Analysis PAUL H. RUBIN, Assistant Director for Consumer Protection This report has been prepared by an individual member of the professional staff of the FTC Bureau of Economics. It rsfle cts solely the views of the author, and is not intended to represent the position of the Federal Trade Commission, or necessarily the views of any individual Commissioner. -ii - fI. ACKNOWLEDGMENTS I would like to thank former FTC Commissioner David A.
    [Show full text]
  • Manufacturer Cartels and Resale Price Maintenance
    DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS JOHANNES KEPLER UNIVERSITY OF LINZ Manufacturer Cartels and Resale Price Maintenance by Matthias HUNOLD Johannes MUTHERS Working Paper No. 2006 March 2020 Johannes Kepler University of Linz Department of Economics Altenberger Strasse 69 A-4040 Linz - Auhof, Austria www.econ.jku.at [email protected] Manufacturer Cartels and Resale Price Maintenance Matthias Hunold∗ and Johannes Muthers† February 2021 Abstract In a model with manufacturer and retailer competition, we show that RPM facilitates manufacturer cartels when retailers have an outside option to selling the manufacturer’s product. Because retailers have an effective outside option, the manufacturer can only ensure contract acceptance by leaving a sufficient margin to the retailers. This restricts the wholesale price level even when manufacturers collude. In this context, collusion can only become profitable for manufacturers if they use resale price maintenance. We thus provide a novel theory of harm for resale price maintenance when manufacturers collude and illustrate the fit of this theory in competition policy cases. JEL classification: D43, K21, K42, L41, L42, L81. Keywords: resale price maintenance, collusion, retailing. ∗We thank participants at the 2020 annual meeting of the Verein für Socialpolitik as well as seminar participants at the University of Siegen, and in particular Hanna Hottenrott, Sebastian Kessing, Dieter Pennerstorfer, Frank Schlütter and Nicolas Schutz for valuable comments and suggestions. Corresponding author. University of Siegen, Unteres Schloß 3, 57068 Siegen, Germany; e-mail: [email protected]. †Johannes Kepler University Linz, Altenberger Straße 69, 4040 Linz, Austria; e-mail: jo- [email protected] 1 1 Introduction Resale price maintenance (RPM) has been used by colluding manufacturers of beer, gummi bears, chocolate, and coffee.1 The case reports contain indications that RPM indeed helped to make manufacturer collusion successful.
    [Show full text]
  • The Resale Price Maintenance Two-Step
    COMMERCIAL LITIGATION Controlling Retail Prices The Resale Price Maintenance By Pat Pascarella, Anne Swoboda Cruz, Two-Step and Stephanie Rzepka Until anti-Leegin states permit companies simply to enter into pro- competitive resale price agreements, properly implemented and monitored policies can In 2007, the U.S. Supreme Court abolished the per se rule provide a fair amount against minimum resale price agreements and held that of price discipline, and they were to be judged instead under the more lenient rule pose marginal risk. of reason standard. Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877, 877 (2007). ance has placed manufacturers competing But 10 years later, the combined effect in nationwide markets in the unenviable of a disconnect between Leegin and cer- position of weighing the benefits of ratio- tain states’ laws and a lack of dispositive nalizing their retail distribution channels court decisions providing substantive guid- against unpredictable litigation risks. ■ Pat Pascarella is the chair the Tucker Ellis’ Antitrust Group. Before joining Tucker Ellis, he served with the U.S. Department of Justice, Antitrust Division in Washington D.C. and as chief in-house antitrust counsel to a Fortune-10 company. Anne Swoboda Cruz, a partner in Tucker Ellis’ Los Angeles office, is a trial attorney specializing in commercial litigation and antitrust. Ms. Cruz also is an active member of DRI, including the DRI Women in the Law Com- mittee. Stephanie Rzepka is an associate in Tucker Ellis’ Houston office. She represents businesses in antitrust, class action, and complex commercial litigation before state and federal courts and antitrust enforcement agencies.
    [Show full text]
  • A Decision-Theoretic Rule of Reason for Minimum Resale Price Maintenance Thom Lambert University of Missouri School of Law, [email protected]
    University of Missouri School of Law Scholarship Repository Faculty Publications 2010 A Decision-Theoretic Rule of Reason for Minimum Resale Price Maintenance Thom Lambert University of Missouri School of Law, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarship.law.missouri.edu/facpubs Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons, Courts Commons, and the Litigation Commons Recommended Citation Thomas A. Lambert, A Decision-Theoretic Rule of Reason for Minimum Resale Price Maintenance, 55 Antitrust Bull. 172 (2010) This Article is brought to you for free and open access by University of Missouri School of Law Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Publications by an authorized administrator of University of Missouri School of Law Scholarship Repository. THE ANTITRUST BULLETIN: Vol. 55, No. 1/Spring 2010 : 167 A decision-theoreticrule of reason for minimum resale price maintenance BY THOMAS A. LAMBERT* In holding that minimum resale price maintenance (RPM) is not per se illegal but should instead be evaluated under the rule of reason, the Leegin Court directed lower courts to craft a structured liability analysis that will separate pro- from anticompetitive instances of the practice. Thus far, courts, regulators, and commentators have proposed four types of approaches for evaluating instances of RPM: (1) approaches focused on the effects on consumer prices; (2) approaches focused on the identity of the party initiating the RPM (i.e., manufacturer or dealer(s)); (3) approaches focused on whether the product at issue is sold along with dealer services that are susceptible to free-riding; and (4) an approach, favored by the Federal Trade Commission, that mechanically applies factors the Leegin Court deemed to be relevant to the liability question.
    [Show full text]
  • Greg Shaffer, Theories of Harm from Resale Price Maintenance
    Theories of Harm from Resale Price Maintenance Greg Sha¤er University of Rochester FTC Hearings on Resale Price Maintenance February 19, 2009 Introduction Resale price maintenance is a practice in which an upstream …rm (manufacturer) restricts the price at which a downstream …rm (retailer) can resell its product. It has been used by …rms with market power and without market power, in markets where competition is vigorous, and in markets where competition is not so vigorous. RPM can take di¤erent forms. It can be a price ‡oor (min RPM), a price ceiling (max RPM), or a …xed price (…xed-price RPM). Introduction Resale price maintenance is a practice in which an upstream …rm (manufacturer) restricts the price at which a downstream …rm (retailer) can resell its product. It has been used by …rms with market power and without market power, in markets where competition is vigorous, and in markets where competition is not so vigorous. RPM can take di¤erent forms. It can be a price ‡oor (min RPM), a price ceiling (max RPM), or a …xed price (…xed-price RPM). Introduction RPM must be analyzed in the market context in which it occurs. In the past, when it was legal, RPM was commonly observed on products such as aspirin, pens, pencils, toothpaste, …ne china, soap, cigars, baby powder, deodorant, shaving cream, milk, electronic equipment, skiing equipment, hearing aids, refrigerators, and toasters. Introduction My assignment Discuss strategic theories of harm Leave RPM cartel theories to others Leave e¢ ciency rationales to others Strategic Theories of Harm Mitigating the E¤ects of Bargaining/Opportunism Manufacturer Retailer Retailer Mitigating the E¤ects of Bargaining/Opportunism Suppose an upstream …rm with market power sells to competing downstream …rms who also have market power.
    [Show full text]
  • Retail Price Maintenance
    Resale Price Maintenance: A Competitive Assessment Federal Trade Commission Workshop on Resale Price Maintenance Panel on Anticompetitive Effects Warren S. Grimes Professor, Southwestern Law School February 19, 2009 If one sat in on a marketing class at any reputable business school, the business reason for imposing resale price maintenance (RPM)1 would likely be described in straightforward fashion. A brand seller imposes RPM for one fundamental reason – it helps the seller win and retain retailers that will carry and promote the product. It does this by guaranteeing the retailer a high margin. That’s it. Of course, not all brand sellers will find it advantageous to impose RPM. An efficient, low cost producer can compete on favorable terms without RPM. If consumers widely recognize the superiority of a brand – an example might be Procter & Gamble’s Tide -- that seller too will likely see no need to employ RPM – retailers will want to carry the strong brand to attract customers. Under these circumstances, the brand seller will probably resist retailer pressure to impose RPM because it will prefer to take advantage of the vigorous intrabrand competition among retailers, bringing down the end price to consumers and increasing overall sales.2 The brand seller most likely to find RPM attractive is one who is selling a mid to high- priced brand whose inherent superiority is not readily evident to consumers. For such a manufacturer, RPM can give retailers a needed incentive not only to stock the brand but to actively promote it. Still, a competitive assessment of RPM is not complete without recognizing that even the brand seller with a relatively weak and relatively high priced brand has alternatives to RPM for widening distribution and sales.
    [Show full text]
  • Resale Price Maintenance Ten Years After Leegin
    Resale Price Maintenance Ten Years After Leegin June 28, 2017 Overview of Resale Price Maintenance (RPM) • What is Resale Price Maintenance? – A supplier and its distributor/retailer agree on the price (or a minimum price) to be charged by the retailer for the resale of the supplier’s products • Some common business rationales for suppliers to seek a floor under resale prices – Incentivize retailers to list or display products purchase shelf space via guaranteed margins – Prevent free-riding – Assure retailers that inventory will not be devalued – Incentivize retailers to invest in promotional / sales efforts – Protect brand value / consumer perceptions of product 2 Legal Framework under U.S. Federal Law • Section 1 of the Sherman Antitrust Act – “Every contract, combination . or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce . is declared to be illegal . .” • Two elements of a violation – Agreement between two or more persons – Unreasonable restraint of trade • Early Supreme Court Cases – Dr. Miles Medical Co. v. John D. Park & Sons Co. (1911) – United States v. Colgate & Co. (1919) • Modern antitrust revolution – Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania(1977) – State Oil v. Khan (1997) – “The primary purpose of the antitrust laws is to protect interbrand competition.” 3 The Leegin Decision • Overturned Dr. Miles and its per se rule against resale price maintenance – The Court reviewed the potential procompetitive uses of resale price maintenance – In light of those potential procompetitive uses, a per se rule is inappropriate – Resale price maintenance should be evaluated under the rule of reason • Difficult (or impossible) to establish a violation in the absence of market power • Caution in some unusual circumstances – Cat’s paw – Supplier with market power – RPM utilized in connection with horizontal agreement At the time, Leegin was viewed as a decision that would have a far-reaching impact on U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • Unit 18 Reading Materials
    ANTITRUST LAW Unit 18: Unilateral Refusals to Deal Fall 2014 Yale Law School Dale Collins Table of Contents Seminal cases United States v. Colgate & Co., 250 U.S. 300 (1919) ........................................... 4 Lorain Journal Co. v. United States, 342 U.S. 143 (1951)................................... 11 United States v. Parke, Davis & Co., 362 U.S. 29 (1960) ................................... 16 Official Airline Guides, Inc. v. FTC, 630 F.2d 920 (2d Cir. 1980) ..................... 23 Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp., 472 U.S. 585 (1985) ......... 30 Verizon Commc’ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398 (2004) (excerpts) ..................................................................... 41 iPad Antitrust Litigation In re Apple iPod iTunes Antitrust Litig., No. 4:05-cv-00037 (N.D. Cal. filed Jan. 26, 2010) Order Granting in Part and Denying in Part Defendant’s Motion for Summary Judgment; Denying As Premature Plaintiffs’ Motion for Class Certification (May 19, 2011) ................................................... 51 Order Denying: (1) Defendant's Combined Motion for Summary Judgment and Daubert Motion; (2) Plaintiffs' Dauber Motion; and (3) Plaintiffs'motion To Strike Expert Report (Sept. 26, 2014) ................... 67 DOJ Section 2 Report Unilateral, Unconditional Refusals to Deal with Rivals, in U.S. Dep’t of Justice, Competition and Monopoly: Single-Firm Conduct under Section 2 of the Sherman Act (issued by the Bush administration on Sept. 11, 2008; withdrawn by the Obama administration
    [Show full text]