Scale Economies, Product Differentiation, and Monopolistic Competition

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Scale Economies, Product Differentiation, and Monopolistic Competition Scale Economies, Product Differentiation, and Monopolistic Competition By Kiminori Matsuyama (Permanently) Work in Progress Last Updated: March 17, 2009; 11:34:51 PM Page 1 of 129 Overview • Introduction • Endogenous Technologies in Competitive Models with External Economies of Scale • Competitive Models with Internal Economies of Scale • Monopolistic Competitive Models with Internal Economies of Scale 9 Tradeable Differentiated Goods: Gains from Product Variety and Intra-Industry Trade 9 Nontradeable Differentiated Goods: Agglomeration Effects, 9 Costly Trade in Differentiated Goods: Home Market Effect and Economic Geography. • Extensions; Firm Heterogeneity, Multi-Product, Variable Mark-Up etc. (Unfinished) • Bibliography Page 2 of 129 Introduction • Competitive, CRS models of trade stress gains from trade between dissimilar countries. Yet, a bulk of trade is done between similar countries. Aside from those with non- homothetic preferences, models with CRS do not sit well with this observation. • IRS implies that even (inherently) identical countries can gain from trade, by each specializing in different activities. • Agglomeration is one of the most salient features of the economic landscape. Yet, it is difficult to explain in a world with CRS, where every country has access to the same technologies. • Of course, the Ricardian theory allows for technological differences across regions and countries. • Aside from the geography and climate, however, it is difficult to think of technology differences to be exogenous factors. And if we are to endogenize technology in order to understand how the technological differences across countries emerge and persist, we must confront the problem of how to incorporate IRS in general equilibrium framework. Page 3 of 129 Part IV look at various ways of introducing IRS in general equilibrium framework. • External Economies of Scale, where each producer faces CRS but externalities generate IRS at sectoral or economy levels. This is also a useful way of endogenizing technologies within the competitive framework. • Internal Economies of Scale within the competitive framework. • Internal Economies of Scale within the Monopolistically Competitive framework, where different firms produce Differentiated Products. Within this framework, we consider models with differentiated products that are 9 Costlessly Tradeable to see the Gains from Trade due to Increased Product Variety,and Intra-Industry Trade 9 Nontradeable to see Agglomeration Effects 9 Subject to the Iceberg Trade Costs to see the Home Market Effect and Economic Geography. • We also review some recent works that relax some restrictive features of the basic monopolistic competition models (firm heterogeneity, multi-product, and variable mark-up, etc.) Page 4 of 129 Endogenous Technologies: External Economies & Increasing Returns External economies are a simple way of introducing sector-wide or economy-wide increasing returns without departing from the competitive framework. Here, I follow mostly Helpman and Krugman (1985; Ch.3). Let us modify the neoclassical production functions as follows: j Production Function of a sector-j firm: x j = F (v j ;ξ j ), j which maps the firm’s input, vj to its output, xj. Holding ξj constant, F (•;ξ j ) satisfies all the standard properties of neoclassical productions, including the linear homogeneity. j Since F (•;ξ j ) is linear homogeneous, we may define: Unit Cost Function of a sector-j firm: C j (w;ξ ) ≡ Min wa F j (a ;ξ ) ≥ 1 j a j { j j j } Unit Input Function of a sector-j firm: a (w;ξ ) ≡ Arg min wa F j (a ;ξ ) ≥ 1 j j a j { j j j } Page 5 of 129 An element, ξj, captures the external effects; they are: • representing all sorts of factors that affect productivity of sector-j, such as knowledge and experiences, the shared inputs, etc. • endogenous, determined in equilibrium, depending on the actions taken by the others. • beyond the control of each (infinitesimal) firm, hence exogenous from the point of view of each firm. j λ j j Example: Let ξj = Xj = ∑xj be the total output andF (v j ;ξ j ) = (ξ j ) F (v j ), 0 < λj < 1. Then, j λ j j X j = Σx j = F (Σv j ;ξ j ) = (X j ) F (V j ), where Vj = ∑vj. 1 j 1−λ Or X j = []F (V j ) j , which has the homogeneity of degree, 1/(1–λj) > 1. Thus, external economies generate sector-level increasing returns. Yet, the assumption that each firm takes ξj as exogenous enables us to stay within the competitive framework. Page 6 of 129 What factors enter ξj is an important assumption. One may consider a variety of alternatives. That is, ξj may contain factors that are • Country-specific and sector-specific, such as the total output or employment in the country’s sector-j, such as Xj. (The most common assumption) • Sector-specific but not country-specific; German and Japanese automakers migh learn a lot from each other, while German furniture makers might not learn much from German automakers. • Country-specific but not sector-specific; Japanese consumer electronics industries and automakers might learn from each other. • Region (bigger than a country)-specific; Europeans might learn more from each other. • Region (smaller than a country)-specific; Urban externalities might be restricted to a particular metropolitan area. etc. Note that these geographical and sectoral scopes are assumed. This could be a major drawback of this approach, as the scope external effects might depend on the environment. For example, government restrictions on trade or factor flows might change the extent to which these external effects are country-specific. Page 7 of 129 Autarky Equilibrium: In vector notation, (P=C): p A = C(w A;ξ A ) = w A A(w A;ξ A ) (RC): A(w A,ξ A )X A = V A A A A A A A A A A (DC): X = [e p ( p )/ e( p )]( p X ) = [ep ( p )/ e( p )](w V ) Integrated Equilibrium (IE): (P=C): p I = C(wI ;ξ I ) = wI A(wI ;ξ I ) (RC): A(wI ,ξ I )X I = V I I I I I I I I I I (DC): X = [e p ( p )/ e( p )]( p X ) = [ep ( p )/ e( p )](w V ) Can we replicate the IE when factors become immobile? The answer depends critically on the scope of external effects. Page 8 of 129 Global External Economies of Scale: When the external effects are entirely global in geographical scope (e.g., Japanese and German engineers can still learn from each other, even though they cannot relocate across borders), the answer is YES, under the same condition in Part 3. O* I I a1(w ;ξ )x*1 I I I a2(w ;ξ )x 2 V* I I a2(w ;ξ )x*2 I V 2 = V2 + V*2 I I a2(w ;ξ )x2 E V I I a2(w ;ξ ) a (wI;ξI)xI I I 1 1 a1(w ;ξ )x1 I I a1(w ;ξ ) O I V 1 = V1 + V*1 Page 9 of 129 National External Economies of Scale: What if the external effects are national in geographical scope? To keep things simple, suppose that they are sector-specific. To achieve the same level of productivity as in IE, it is necessary to concentrate each line of productions that are subject to externalities in one country. Let Nc = # of CRS sectors; NI = N − Nc = # of IRS sectors due to external effects. Example: M = Nc = 2; N = 3. Only j = 3 is subject to country-specific external economies of scale. O* • To replicate IE, assign Sector-3 to I I I Home (Foreign) inside the Green a3(w ;ξ )x 3 (Blue) Parallelogram. •E • Outside of these parallelograms, IE I •E V 2 cannot be replicated. I I • Factor proportion similarity does not a2(w )x 2 I a3(w;ξ ) I •E ensure FPE, let alone IE. a2(w ) (See the Red Dot, E) I I a1(w )x 1 I a1(w ) O I V 1 Page 10 of 129 Example: M = Nc = 2; N = 3. Only j = 2 is subject to country-specific external economies of scale. O* • To replicate IE, assign Sector-2 to a (wI)xI Home (Foreign) inside the Green 3 3 (Blue) Parallelogram. •E • In the overlapping area, sector-2 may I V 2 be assigned to either country. (See I I I a (w) •E a (w ;ξ )x the Red Dot E.) 3 2 2 I I • Outside of these parallelograms, IE a2(w ;ξ ) •E I I cannot be replicated. a1(w )x 1 I a1(w ) O I Notes: V 1 • We may hope for replicating IE when Nc =N − NI ≥ M, the condition ensuring the IE set has the full dimensionality in the factor space. • Patterns of trade may be indeterminate even when the IE can be replicated (as depicted by the Red dot, E). But, the factor content of trade is uniquely determined. • There may be multiple equilibriums, only a few of which replicates IE. Other equilibriums that fail to replicate IE, even though some of them might achieve FPE. • If national external economies are not sector-specific, there will be additional constraints, as a set of sectors may have to be located in the same country. Page 11 of 129 Example: M = Nc = 1; N = 2. Let j = 1 be the IRS sector and j =2 be the CRS sector. Integrated Equilibrium (IE): I 1 I I I 2 I (P=C): p1 = C (w ; X1 ), p2 = C (w ) I 1 I I 2 I (RC): L = C (1, X1 )X1 + C (1)X 2 2 I I I I (DC): C (1)X 2 = α2( p )(w L ). 1 I I 2 I Let L(1) ≡ C (1, X1 )X1 , L(2) ≡ C (1)X 2 .
Recommended publications
  • Urban Concentration: the Role of Increasing Returns and Transport Costs
    i'445o Urban Concentration: The Role of Increasing Retums and Transport Costs Public Disclosure Authorized Paul Krugman Very largeurban centersare a conspicuousfeature of many developingeconomies, yet the subject of the size distribution of cities (as opposed to such issuesas rural-urban migration) has been neglected by development economists. This article argues that some important insights into urban concentration, especially the tendency of some developing countris to have very large primate cdties, can be derived from recent approachesto economic geography.Three approachesare comparedrthe well-estab- Public Disclosure Authorized lished neoclassica urban systems theory, which emphasizes the tradeoff between agglomerationeconomies and diseconomies of city size; the new economic geogra- phy, which attempts to derive agglomeration effects from the interactions among market size, transportation costs, and increasingreturns at the firm level; and a nihilistic view that cities emerge owt of a randon processin which there are roughly constant returns to city size. The arttcle suggeststhat Washingtonconsensus policies of reducedgovernment intervention and trade opening may tend to reducethe size of primate cties or at least slow their relativegrowth. Over the past severalyears there has been a broad revivalof interestin issues Public Disclosure Authorized of regional and urban development. This revivalhas taken two main direc- dions. T'he first has focused on theoretical models of urbanization and uneven regional growth, many of them grounded in the approaches to imperfect competition and increasing returns originally developed in the "new trade" and anew growth" theories. The second, a new wave of empirical work, explores urban and regional growth patterns for clues to the nature of external economies, macro- economic adjustment, and other aspects of the aggregate economy.
    [Show full text]
  • TRANSACTION COST LIMITS to ECONOMIES of SCALE Cotton M
    DO RATE AND VOLUME MATTER? TRANSACTION COST LIMITS TO ECONOMIES OF SCALE Cotton M. Lindsay & Michael T. Maloney Department of Economics Clemson University In the traditional treatment, economies of scale are attributed to a hodgepodge of sources. A typical list might include Adam Smith's famous "division of labour," economies of large machines, the integration of processes, massed reserves, and standardization. The list can be partly systematized because, when considered in detail, these various economies are themselves the result of various other more basic and occasionally overlapping principles. For example, both economies of massed reserves and economies of standardi- zation are to a certain extent the product of the statistical “law of large numbers.” However, even this analysis fails to strike to the heart of the matter because the technological factors however described that reduce costs with scale do not in themselves imply that large firms can produce at lower cost than small firms. The possible presence of such technological scale economies does not give us adequate knowledge to predict the structure of industry. These forces of nature may combine to make it cheaper to get things done in big chunks. However, this potential will be economically important only in the presence of transactions costs. Firms can specialize their production processes and hire out the jobs that require large scale. Realistically all firms hire out some portion of the production process regard- less of their size. General Motors ships many of its automobiles by rail, but does not own a railroad for this purpose. Anaconda uses a great deal of fuel oil in its production of copper, but it does not own oil wells or refineries.
    [Show full text]
  • The Role of Industrial and Post-Industrial Cities in Economic Development
    Joint Center for Housing Studies Harvard University The Role of Industrial and Post-Industrial Cities in Economic Development John R. Meyer W00-1 April 2000 John R. Meyer is James W. Harpel Professor of Capital Formation and Economic Growth, Emeritus and chairman of the faculty committee of the Joint Center for Housing Studies. by John R. Meyer. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including notice, is given to the source. Draft paper prepared for the World Bank Urban Development Division's research project entitled "Revisiting Development - Urban Perspectives." Any opinions expressed are those of the author and not those of the Joint Center for Housing Studies of Harvard University or of any of the persons or organizations providing support to the Joint Center for Housing Studies, nor of the World Bank Urban Development Division. The Role of Industrial and Post-Industrial Cities in Economic Development by John R. Meyer Once upon a time the location of towns and cities, at least superficially, seemed to be largely determined by the preferences of kings, princes, bishops, generals and other political and military leaders of society. A site’s defensibility or its capabilities for imposing military or administrative control over surrounding countryside were often of paramount importance. As one historian summed up the conventional wisdom: “Cities...were to be found...wherever agriculture produced sufficient surplus to sustain a population of rulers, soldiers, craftsmen and other nonfood producers.”1 The key to successful urbanization, in short, wasn’t so much what the city could do for the countryside as what the countryside could do for the city.2 This traditional view of early cities, while perhaps correct in its essentials, is also almost surely too limited.3 Cities were never just parasitic; most have always added at least some economic value.
    [Show full text]
  • Cost Concepts the Cost Function
    (Largely) Review: Cost concepts The Cost Function • Cost function C(q): minimum cost of producing a given quantity q • C(q) = F + V C(q), where { Fixed costs F : cost incurred regardless of output amount. Avoidable vs. sunk: crucial for determining shut-down decisions for the firm. { Variable costs V C(q); vary with the amount produced. C(q) { Average cost AC(q) = q @C(q) { Marginal cost MC(q) = @q V C(q) F { AV C(q) = q ; AF C(q) = q ; AC(q) = AV C(q) + AF C(q). Example • C(q) = 125 + 5q + 5q2 • AC(q) = • MC(q) = • AF C(q) = 125=q • AV C(q) = 5 + 5q q AC(q) MC(q) 1 135 15 • 3 61.67 35 5 55 55 7 57.86 75 9 63.89 95 • AC rises if MC exceeds it, and falls if MC is below it. Implies that MC intersects AC at the minimum of AC. Short-run vs. long-run costs: • Short run: production technology given • Long run: can adapt production technology to market conditions • Long-run AC curve cannot exceed short-run AC curve: its the lower envelope Example: \The division of labor is limited by the extent of the market" (Adam Smith) • Division of labor requires high fixed costs (for example, assembly line requires high setup costs). • Firm adopts division of labor only when scale of production (market demand) is high enough. • Graph: Price-taking firm has \choice" between two production technologies. Opportunity cost The opportunity cost of a product is the value of the best forgone alternative use of the resources employed in making it.
    [Show full text]
  • Report No. 2020-06 Economies of Scale in Community Banks
    Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Staff Studies Report No. 2020-06 Economies of Scale in Community Banks December 2020 Staff Studies Staff www.fdic.gov/cfr • @FDICgov • #FDICCFR • #FDICResearch Economies of Scale in Community Banks Stefan Jacewitz, Troy Kravitz, and George Shoukry December 2020 Abstract: Using financial and supervisory data from the past 20 years, we show that scale economies in community banks with less than $10 billion in assets emerged during the run-up to the 2008 financial crisis due to declines in interest expenses and provisions for losses on loans and leases at larger banks. The financial crisis temporarily interrupted this trend and costs increased industry-wide, but a generally more cost-efficient industry re-emerged, returning in recent years to pre-crisis trends. We estimate that from 2000 to 2019, the cost-minimizing size of a bank’s loan portfolio rose from approximately $350 million to $3.3 billion. Though descriptive, our results suggest efficiency gains accrue early as a bank grows from $10 million in loans to $3.3 billion, with 90 percent of the potential efficiency gains occurring by $300 million. JEL classification: G21, G28, L00. The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the official positions of the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation or the United States. FDIC Staff Studies can be cited without additional permission. The authors wish to thank Noam Weintraub for research assistance and seminar participants for helpful comments. Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, [email protected], 550 17th St. NW, Washington, DC 20429 Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, [email protected], 550 17th St.
    [Show full text]
  • The Role of Government in China's Long
    ECONOMIC RESEARCH FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS WORKING PAPER SERIES The Visible Hand: The Role of Government in China’s Long-Awaited Industrial Revolution Authors George E. Fortier, and Yi Wen Working Paper Number 2016-016A Creation Date August 2016 Citable Link https://doi.org/10.20955/wp.2016.016 Fortier, G.E., Wen, Y., 2016; The Visible Hand: The Role of Government in China’s Suggested Citation Long-Awaited Industrial Revolution, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper 2016-016. URL https://doi.org/10.20955/wp.2016.016 Published In Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review Publisher Link https://doi.org/10.1080/14765284.2019.1582224 Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Research Division, P.O. Box 442, St. Louis, MO 63166 The views expressed in this paper are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Federal Reserve System, the Board of Governors, or the regional Federal Reserve Banks. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Papers are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comment. The Visible Hand: The Role of Government in China’s Long-Awaited Industrial Revolution Yi Wen and George E. Fortier China is undergoing its long-awaited industrial revolution. There is no shortage of commentary and opinion on this dramatic period, but few have attempted to provide a coherent, in-depth, political- economic framework that explains the fundamental mechanisms behind China’s rapid industrializa- tion. This article reviews the New Stage Theory of economic development put forth by Wen (2016a). It illuminates the critical sequence of developmental stages since the reforms enacted by Deng Xiaoping in 1978: namely, small-scale commercialized agricultural production, proto-industrialization in the countryside, a formal industrial revolution based on mass production of labor-intensive light consumer goods, a sustainable “industrial trinity” boom in energy/motive power/infrastructure, and a second industrial revolution involving the mass production of heavy industrial goods.
    [Show full text]
  • External Economies and International Trade Redux∗
    EXTERNAL ECONOMIES AND INTERNATIONAL TRADE REDUX∗ GENE M. GROSSMAN AND ESTEBAN ROSSI-HANSBERG We study a world with national external economies of scale at the industry level. In contrast to the standard treatment with perfect competition and two industries, we assume Bertrand competition in a continuum of industries. With Bertrand competition, each firm can internalize the externalities from production by setting a price below those set by others. This out-of-equilibrium threat elimi- nates many of the “pathologies” of the standard treatment. There typically exists a unique equilibrium with trade guided by “natural” comparative advantage. And, when a country has CES preferences and any finite elasticity of substitution be- tween goods, gains from trade are ensured. I. INTRODUCTION External economies hold a central—albeit somewhat uncomfortable—place in the theory of international trade. Since Marshall (1890, 1930 [1879]) at least, economists have known that increasing returns can be an independent cause of trade and that the advantages that derive from large-scale production need not be confined within the boundaries of a firm. Marshallian exter- nalities arise when knowledge and other public inputs associated with a firm’s output spill over to the benefit of other industry par- ticipants. After Marshall’s initial explication of the idea, a lengthy debate ensued on whether an industry with external economies of scale could logically be modeled as perfectly competitive.1 Even af- ter the matter was finally resolved in the affirmative by Chipman (1970), trade economists continued to bemoan the “bewildering variety of equilibria [that provide] a taxonomy rather than a clear set of insights” (Krugman, 1995, p.
    [Show full text]
  • The Role of Government in Chinas Long-Awaited Industrial Revolution
    The Visible Hand: The Role of Government in China’s Long-Awaited Industrial Revolution Yi Wen and George E. Fortier China is undergoing its long-awaited industrial revolution. There is no shortage of commentary and opinion on this dramatic period, but few have attempted to provide a coherent, in-depth, political- economic framework that explains the fundamental mechanisms behind China’s rapid industrializa- tion. This article reviews the New Stage Theory of economic development put forth by Wen (2016a). It illuminates the critical sequence of developmental stages since the reforms enacted by Deng Xiaoping in 1978: namely, small-scale commercialized agricultural production, proto-industrialization in the countryside, a formal industrial revolution based on mass production of labor-intensive light consumer goods, a sustainable “industrial trinity” boom in energy/motive power/infrastructure, and a second industrial revolution involving the mass production of heavy industrial goods. This developmental sequence follows essentially the same pattern as Great Britain’s Industrial Revolution, despite sharp differences in political and institutional conditions. One of the key conclusions exemplified by China’s economic rise is that the extent of industrialization is limited by the extent of the market. One of the key strategies behind the creation and nurturing of a continually growing market in China is based on this premise: The free market is a public good that is very costly for nations to create and support. Market creation requires a powerful “mercantilist” state and the correct sequence of developmental stages; China has been successfully accomplishing its industrialization through these stages, backed by measured, targeted reforms and direct participation from its central and local governments.
    [Show full text]
  • The Adoption of Mechanization, Labour Productivity and Household Income: Evidence from Rice Production in Thailand
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Srisompun, Orawan; Athipanyakul, Thanaporn; Somporn Isvilanonda Working Paper The adoption of mechanization, labour productivity and household income: Evidence from rice production in Thailand TVSEP Working Paper, No. WP-016 Provided in Cooperation with: TVSEP - Thailand Vietnam Socio Economic Panel, Leibniz Universität Hannover Suggested Citation: Srisompun, Orawan; Athipanyakul, Thanaporn; Somporn Isvilanonda (2019) : The adoption of mechanization, labour productivity and household income: Evidence from rice production in Thailand, TVSEP Working Paper, No. WP-016, Leibniz Universität Hannover, Thailand Vietnam Socio Economic Panel (TVSEP), Hannover This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/208384 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen
    [Show full text]
  • Industrialisation Unlocking the Efficiency and Agility of the Swiss Banking Industry
    Industrialisation Unlocking the efficiency and agility of the Swiss banking industry August 2016 Contents 1. Introduction and key findings 01 2. Swiss banking: pressures continue 03 3. Industrialisation as response 06 4. Banks’ industrialisation plans 10 5. Our perspective: A call for action 22 Bibliography 29 Appendix 30 Authors & contributors 31 Acknowledgment We would like to thank all participating executives for their support in completing the survey and sharing their expertise in the interviews with us. Industrialisation | Unlocking the efficiency and agility of the Swiss banking industry 1. Introduction and key findings Since the financial crisis the Swiss Banking industry has been under tremendous pressure. An unfavourable economic climate, rising expectations of empowered customers, increased regulatory focus and intense on- and offshore competition have reduced the revenue margins as a percentage of assets under management of Swiss banks by 21 per cent between 2010 and 2015. Combined with the emergence of FinTech entrants and disruptive technologies, these trends are creating an urgent need for innovation, and also to cut costs and improve agility in order to fund and execute new business models. In recent years many banks have limited themselves to taking only tactical cost reduction measures. We believe it is now time to improve agility and efficiency by industrialising how banks operate. The objective of industrialisation is to eliminate redundancies, re-engineer the value chain, automate and standardise processes wherever possible, while providing transparency about the profit of activities. In collaboration with the Hochschule Luzern, Institut für Finanzdienstleistungen (IFZ), we have conducted an online survey and personal interviews with executives from Swiss banks on their current levels of industrialisation and their industrialisation strategies for the next five years.
    [Show full text]
  • Transportation Costs
    Transportation Costs Moshe Ben-Akiva 1.201 / 11.545 / ESD.210 Transportation Systems Analysis: Demand & Economics Fall 2008 Review: Theory of the Firm ● Basic Concepts ● Production functions – Isoquants – Rate of technical substitution ● Maximizing production and minimizing costs – Dual views to the same problem ● Average and marginal costs 2 Outline ● Long-Run vs. Short-Run Costs ● Economies of Scale, Scope and Density ● Methods for estimating costs 3 Long-Run Cost ● All inputs can vary to get the optimal cost ● Because of time delays and high costs of changing transportation infrastructure, this may be a rather idealized concept in many systems 4 Short-Run Cost ● Some inputs (Z) are fixed (machinery, infrastructure) and some (X) are variable (labor, material) = + C(q) WZ Z WX X (W , q, Z ) ∂ ∂ W X X (W , q, Z ) WZ Z MC (q) = = 0 ∂q ∂q 5 Long-Run Cost vs. Short-Run Cost ●Long-run cost function is identical to the lower envelope of short- run cost functions AC AC4 AC3 AC2 AC1 LAC q 6 Outline ● Long-Run vs. Short-Run Costs ● Economies of Scale, Scope and Density ● Methods for estimating costs 7 Economies of Scale C(q+Δq) < C(q) + C(Δq) cost AC MC < AC MC q ● Economies of scale are not constant. A firm may have economies of scale when it is small, but diseconomies of scale when it is large. 8 Example: Cobb-Douglas Production Function Are there economies of scale in the production? Production function approach: – K – capital a b c – L – labor q = αK L F – F – fuel Economies of scale: a+b+c > 1 Constant return to scale: a+b+c = 1 Diseconomies of scale: a+b+c < 1 9 Example (cont) Long-run cost function approach – The firm minimizes expenses at any level of production = + + – Production expense: E WK K WL L WF F WK - unit price of capital (e.g.
    [Show full text]
  • Profit Maximization & Economies of Scale
    Presentation #8: Profit Maximization & Economies of Scale 3 Minute Video on Calculating Profit Maximization 3 minute Video on Economies of Scale Q: If every unit can be sold for $10. Which unit maximizes profit? A: FOUR Q: Why should you should never produce 5 units? A: It costs you more to make the 5th unit (and 6th, 7th, 8th, etc…) than you make selling it Marginal Price Cost $12 Marginal $10 Revenue $8 $6 1 2 3 4 5 Quantity Short-Run Profit Maximization Q: What is the goal of every business? A: To Maximize Profit!!!!!! To maximum profit firms must make the right amount of output Firms should continue to produce until the additional revenue (MR) from each new output is greater than or equals the additional cost (MC). Example: Assume the price is still $10 (MR = $10) Should you produce… if the additional cost of another unit is $5 (MC=$5) 10 > 5…YES if the additional cost of another unit is $9 (MC=$9) 10 > 9…YES if the additional cost of another unit is $11 (MC=$11) 10 < 11…NO Profit Maximizing Rule: MR = MC Short Run Profit Maximization Review Marginal Revenue (MR) = Marginal Cost (MC) = amount received selling one more unit cost of making one more unit Profit Maximization Graph Maximize profit where MR = MC Explained in 5 minutes by Khan Academy Assume a firm can sell any quantity produced at $10 per unit Firm sets quantity of output where MC = MR & produces that quantity to maximize profit. D = MR WHY? $10 -------------------------------- Economic Profit ------------------------------------ Since MC is rising company will “break even” on the last unit sold.
    [Show full text]