Industrial Organization

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Industrial Organization This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: The Growing Importance of the Service Industries Volume Author/Editor: Victor R. Fuchs Volume Publisher: NBER Volume ISBN: 0-87014-410-3 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/fuch65-1 Publication Date: 1965 Chapter Title: Industrial Organization Chapter Author: Victor R. Fuchs Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c1699 Chapter pages in book: (p. 17 - 19) THE SERVICEINDUSTRIES 17 doctors can think more of their bank bal-egalitarian. High per capita income im- ances than of their patients. The sales-plies high average output per man. This man who must go through life with anis likely to mean very high output per artificial smile on his face while caringman in some industries (where capital little for his customers and less for whatcan be substituted for labor, and techno- he sells is often held in low regard. Butlogical change is rapid). Employment, at their best many service occupationstherefore, will probably be primarily in are extremely rewarding and the line be-those industries, such as personal serv- tween "work" and "leisure" activity isices, where output per man advances often difficult to draw. slowly. Our attitudes toward personal Some serviceoccupations,notablyservices are not immutable laws of na- those involving personal service, are notture; they can be changed. Such a change well regarded in this country. A study ofwould, I suspect, reduce unemployment why so many Americans consider per-and increase consumer satisfaction. sonal services to be degrading would be very useful. It may be a cultural lag, INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION rooted in the level of income and the dis- The shift of employment to the service tribution of income that prevailed insector carries with it important implica- this country and abroad in the eighteenthtions for industrial organization in the and nineteenth centuries. United States because the size of the When the average level of per capita"firm" and the nature of ownership and income in a country is low, the amountcontrol are typically different in the two of personal services rendered is probablysectors. a function of the distribution of income. Ingoods,with some notable ex- It is probably also related to social im-ceptions, such as agriculture and con- mobility and inequality of opportunity.struction, most of the output is account- In Europe, where there was more in-ed for by large profit-seeking corpora- equality and more immobility, there wastions. Ownership is frequently separate probably proportionately a much greaterfrom management, and significant mar- consumption of personal services. Theseket power held by a few firms in each services were rendered by the low-bornindustry is not uncommon. and the poor to the privileged classes and In the service sector, on the other the wealthy. Americans probably tendedhand, and again with some exceptions, to associate personal services with thisfirms are typically small, usually owner- inequality and noticed that there wasmanaged and often noncorporate. Fur- much less of it in the more democraticthermore, nonprofit operations both pub- United States. lic and private account for one-third of It can be argued, however, that therethe sector's employment. is nothing inherently degrading in per- Table JO summarizes some of the sonal services. In a country with a highavailable information concerning the dis- average level of income, one should ex-tribution of employment in different pect that a large amount of personalservice industries by size of employer. service will be consumed and that a largeThe size distribution in manufacturing number of people will find employmentis included for comparison. In wholesale in that way. This would be true even iftrade, retail trade, and selected services, the income distribution were completelyaccounting for more than 50 per cent of 18 THE SERVICE INDUSTRIES the service sector, half of the employ- Other things being equal, the shift to ment is in companies with fewer thanservices tends to increase the relative im- twenty workers. In finance, insurance,portance of small firms in the economy. and real estate, 40 per cent is in veryThere are, however, forces within many small firms. Another large fraction ofindustries that tend to increase the size service-sector employment is accountedof the average "firm." The pressure for for by self-employed professionals andconsolidation of school districts and other domestic servants, not shown in thelocal government units is a notable ex- table. They represent the extreme inample. Bank mergers is another. The net small size of employer. effect of these countertendencies is diffi- Private (i.e., non-governmental) hos-cult to predict. pitals are considerably larger than the TABLE 10 typical service firm; but even so, more than half the total employment of these PERCENTAGE DISTRIBUTION OF EMPLOYMENT BY SIZE OF FIRM OR EMPLOYER IN MANU- institutions is in hospitals with fewer FACTURING AND SELECTED SERVICE INDUS- than 500 employees. Similarly, only rela- TRIES tively few private schools or colleges could be classified as large. EMPLOYMENT SIZE Government, which is often referred to as a "huge bureaucracy," actually in- Fewer Fewer cludes many small employers. It is worth than20 than 500 noting that employment at the local level 1. Manufacturing (1958) 7 38 of government now exceeds that of state 2. Wholesale trade (1958) 47 93 3. Retail trade (1958) 56 78 and federal (civilian) government com- 4. Selected services (1958) 57 87 bined. One-half of this local employment 5. Finance, insurance, and real estate (1956) 41 67 is in governmental units with fewer than 6. Hospitals (non-governmen- 500 employees. tal, 1963) na. 52 7. Local government (1962).... n.a. 49 One statistic that epitomizes some of the trends already discussed is the per- Source: Rows 1—4, Bureau of the Census, Enterprise StaUs- tics: 1958 Fart I, General Report, p. 30 adjusted to include centage of the national income originat- self-employed proprietors by assuming that they are in firms with fewer than twenty employees; row 5, Betty C, Churchill, ing in business corporations. Ever since "Size of Business Firms," Survey of Current Business, Septem- ber, 1939, p.19, adjusted for self-employed proprietors as the development of the private corpora- rows 1—4; row 6, American Hospital Association, Hospiiais, Guide Issue, 1964, estimated from distributions by number of tion, its role in the economy has tended beds; row 7, Censusof Government.Compendium of Government to grow; but its relative importance ap- Employment, 1962, estimated in part. parently reached a peak about 1955, when corporations accounted for 55.8 per Industries in which small firms ac- count for the bulk of the output typically cent of total national income. Since then do not present industrial control prob- there has been a tendency for this frac-lems of the "trust-busting" variety. On tion to decline, and in 1963 the level wasthe other hand, the growth of such in- 53.8 per cent, approximately the same asdustries may increase the need to guard in 1948.19 against the restrictive practices of trade '9 Data on national income originating in cor-associations and professional organiza- porations and in the total economy are published tions. Small firms may pose another by the National Income Division of the Office of Business Economics in the Survey of Current Busi- problem for the economy because it is ness and associated publications. alleged that they do not allocate suffi- THE SERVICEINDIJSTRIES 19 cient resources to research and other ac-input of physical capital is small. In tivities with large external benefits. barber and beauty shops, for example, The growing importance of the non-labor and materials account for between profit sector will probably pose some dis-80 and 90 per cent of total cost. Another turbing questions about how to promotepoint to be noted is that in the largest efficiency and equity in such organiza-service industry, retail trade, an impor- tions (cf. the problems with Blue Cross).tant part of the capital input takes the When non-profit operations representform of inventories rather than the out- only a minor exception to an essentiallyput of the capital goods industries. private-enterprise economy, the problem In pointing out the relatively lower is not very serious. But if we ever reachcapital intensity of most service indus- the stage where non-profit operationstries, I am not attempting to revive a tend to dominate the economy, we prob-"stagnation" theory in any form. The ably will be faced with the need for radi-maintenance of high levels of employ- cally new instruments of regulation andment and a rapid rate of growth is logi- control. cally consistent with a decline in the rel- ative importance of physical capital in DEMAND POR PHYSICAL CAPITAL the economy. The important point is to There are some portions of the servicerecognize that, if such a decline occurs sector that use large quantities of phys-because of interindustry shifts, it may be ical capital. Real estate and the servicesa proper and useful adjustment to new provided by government roads and high-circumstances, with important implica- ways are notable examples. By and large,tions for relative profit levels in different however, goods industries tend to beindustries. While the national rate of more capital intensive than services. Insavings may be just as high as before, recent years (1960 through 1963) busi-other forms of investment, such as edu- ness expenditures for new plant andcation, that are not customarily included equipment in goods industries were ap-insavings-investment estimates may proximately three times as great as intake on increased importance. profit-seeking service industries; the com- parable ratio of output levels in the two BUSINESS CYCLES groups of industries was only 1.25 to It is generally believed that the service 1.00.
Recommended publications
  • The Oppressive Pressures of Globalization and Neoliberalism on Mexican Maquiladora Garment Workers
    Pursuit - The Journal of Undergraduate Research at The University of Tennessee Volume 9 Issue 1 Article 7 July 2019 The Oppressive Pressures of Globalization and Neoliberalism on Mexican Maquiladora Garment Workers Jenna Demeter The University of Tennessee, Knoxville, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://trace.tennessee.edu/pursuit Part of the Business Administration, Management, and Operations Commons, Business Law, Public Responsibility, and Ethics Commons, Economic History Commons, Gender and Sexuality Commons, Growth and Development Commons, Income Distribution Commons, Industrial Organization Commons, Inequality and Stratification Commons, International and Comparative Labor Relations Commons, International Economics Commons, International Relations Commons, International Trade Law Commons, Labor and Employment Law Commons, Labor Economics Commons, Latin American Studies Commons, Law and Economics Commons, Macroeconomics Commons, Political Economy Commons, Politics and Social Change Commons, Public Economics Commons, Regional Economics Commons, Rural Sociology Commons, Unions Commons, and the Work, Economy and Organizations Commons Recommended Citation Demeter, Jenna (2019) "The Oppressive Pressures of Globalization and Neoliberalism on Mexican Maquiladora Garment Workers," Pursuit - The Journal of Undergraduate Research at The University of Tennessee: Vol. 9 : Iss. 1 , Article 7. Available at: https://trace.tennessee.edu/pursuit/vol9/iss1/7 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by
    [Show full text]
  • Econ 8747: Industrial Organization Theory Fall 2018
    Econ 8747: Industrial Organization Theory Fall 2018 Professor Yongmin Chen Office: Econ 112 Class Time/Location: 9:30-10:45 AM. TTH; ECON 5 Office Hours: 3:30-5:00pm, TTH; 10:00-11:30am, Wednesday Course Description: Industrial organization studies the behavior of firms and markets under imperfect competition. The course will cover selected topics in industrial organization theory. Recommended textbooks include: (1) The Theory of Industrial Organization by Jean Tirole, MIT Press, and (2) Industrial Organization: Contemporary Theory and Practice by Pepall, Richards, and Norman. A good source for references is the Handbook of Industrial Organization, Vol. 1, 2, and 3. HIO3 (2007, Mark Armstrong and Robert Porter edits) surveys the major developments in IO since Tirole. Grading: Grades are based on homework and class participation (30%), presentation (30%), and a term paper (40%). You are encouraged to form study groups to discuss homework and lecture materials. Requirements for the term paper will be discussed later. The course materials are arranged by topics (the topics are listed below), and each topic is usually covered in several classes. Tirole remains the classic graduate IO textbook, and you are encouraged to read the entire book and work out the exercise problems there (even though we only cover a few parts of the book in the course). You will also be asked to write short reviews/discussions (each review/discussion is 2-3 pages long, double spaced). A tentative course schedule is attached. There can be changes to this schedule during the semester, which will be announced in class. You are responsible for updating course information according to announcements made in class.
    [Show full text]
  • Product Differentiation
    Product differentiation Industrial Organization Bernard Caillaud Master APE - Paris School of Economics September 22, 2016 Bernard Caillaud Product differentiation Motivation The Bertrand paradox relies on the fact buyers choose the cheap- est firm, even for very small price differences. In practice, some buyers may continue to buy from the most expensive firms because they have an intrinsic preference for the product sold by that firm: Notion of differentiation. Indeed, assuming an homogeneous product is not realistic: rarely exist two identical goods in this sense For objective reasons: products differ in their physical char- acteristics, in their design, ... For subjective reasons: even when physical differences are hard to see for consumers, branding may well make two prod- ucts appear differently in the consumers' eyes Bernard Caillaud Product differentiation Motivation Differentiation among products is above all a property of con- sumers' preferences: Taste for diversity Heterogeneity of consumers' taste But it has major consequences in terms of imperfectly competi- tive behavior: so, the analysis of differentiation allows for a richer discussion and comparison of price competition models vs quan- tity competition models. Also related to the practical question (for competition authori- ties) of market definition: set of goods highly substitutable among themselves and poorly substitutable with goods outside this set Bernard Caillaud Product differentiation Motivation Firms have in general an incentive to affect the degree of differ- entiation of their products compared to rivals'. Hence, differen- tiation is related to other aspects of firms’ strategies. Choice of products: firms choose how to differentiate from rivals, this impacts the type of products that they choose to offer and the diversity of products that consumers face.
    [Show full text]
  • History in the Study of Industrial Organization
    History in the Study of Industrial Organization David Genesove Hebrew University of Jerusalem and C.E.P.R. May 13 2016 Preliminary Draft *I am grateful for comments by discussants Konrad Stahl, Chaim Fershtman, John Sutton and Bob Feinberg, and others in presentations at the 2012 Nordic IO Conference, the IDC, Herzlya, the MAACI Summer Institute on Competition Policy, Israel IO Day and the 2015 EARIE Conference. I. Introduction In studying Industrial Organization, economists have at times turned to the past to illustrate and test its theories. This includes some of the seminal papers of the new empiricism (e.g., Porter, 1983). This readiness to cull from the historical record has neither been examined critically, nor accompanied by much of an attempt to follow the industrial organization of markets over time. This paper asks how history can help us understand markets, by posing the following dual questions: (a) what are the advantages and disadvantages of using old markets to illuminate our understanding of current ones, and (b) is a historical approach to the study of Industrial Organization possible and worth pursuing? We are talking about history in two different ways: as the past, and as an analytical approach. History as the past means using old markets in empirical work in the same way one uses contemporary markets, whether that is inductively learning about markets in the “theory-development role of applied econometrics” (Morgan, cited by Snooks, 1993), estimating parameters of interest, or “using historical episodes to test economic models for their generality” (Kindleberger, 1990, p. 3). History as an analytic approach means describing a sequence of events as a logical progression informed by economic theory but unencumbered by it, with room for personalities and errors, and perhaps emphasis on certain events with overwhelming importance.
    [Show full text]
  • Oligopolistic Competition
    Lecture 3: Oligopolistic competition EC 105. Industrial Organization Mattt Shum HSS, California Institute of Technology EC 105. Industrial Organization (Mattt Shum HSS,Lecture California 3: Oligopolistic Institute of competition Technology) 1 / 38 Oligopoly Models Oligopoly: interaction among small number of firms Conflict of interest: Each firm maximizes its own profits, but... Firm j's actions affect firm i's profits PC: firms are small, so no single firm’s actions affect other firms’ profits Monopoly: only one firm EC 105. Industrial Organization (Mattt Shum HSS,Lecture California 3: Oligopolistic Institute of competition Technology) 2 / 38 Oligopoly Models Oligopoly: interaction among small number of firms Conflict of interest: Each firm maximizes its own profits, but... Firm j's actions affect firm i's profits PC: firms are small, so no single firm’s actions affect other firms’ profits Monopoly: only one firm EC 105. Industrial Organization (Mattt Shum HSS,Lecture California 3: Oligopolistic Institute of competition Technology) 2 / 38 Oligopoly Models Oligopoly: interaction among small number of firms Conflict of interest: Each firm maximizes its own profits, but... Firm j's actions affect firm i's profits PC: firms are small, so no single firm’s actions affect other firms’ profits Monopoly: only one firm EC 105. Industrial Organization (Mattt Shum HSS,Lecture California 3: Oligopolistic Institute of competition Technology) 2 / 38 Oligopoly Models Oligopoly: interaction among small number of firms Conflict of interest: Each firm maximizes its own profits, but... Firm j's actions affect firm i's profits PC: firms are small, so no single firm’s actions affect other firms’ profits Monopoly: only one firm EC 105.
    [Show full text]
  • Industrial Organization - Outline
    Industrial Organization - Outline Marc M¨oller Department of Economics, Universit¨at Bern General Information Industrial Organisation is the study of strategic competition. The first part of the course considers monopoly pricing as a benchmark. The standard model of monopoly that was introduced in Microeconomics is extended to allow for multiple products and discriminatory pricing. The second and main part of the course considers oligopolistic markets for homogeneous products. We distinguish between price competition and quantity competition and discuss two major concerns of antitrust authorities; entry deterrence and collusion. The final part of the course considers more advanced topics such as differentiated product markets, vertical industry relations and advertising. The course covers the basic theoretical concepts and presents empirical evidence. The course is self–contained and requires knowledge of basic game theoretic con- cepts. Language is English. Books and Overviews • Cabral, L., Introduction to Industrial Organization, 2000, MIT Press. • Belleflamme, P. and M. Peitz, Industrial Organization: Markets and Strategies, 2010, Cambridge University Press. • Tirole, J., The Theory of Industrial Organization, 1989, MIT Press. Problem Sets Each topic contains a set of problems. These problems should be solved by students (preferably in groups) at home. They will be discussed in the practical sessions. 1 Evaluation The (written) exam at the end of the course contributes 100% to the final grade. The exam contains two sections: A multiple choice section with short questions about the basic concepts and results of the course and a section with long questions similar to the ones contained in the problem sets. Outline 0. Introduction What explains the large differences in car markups across European countries.
    [Show full text]
  • Economics 523: Industrial Organization II Fall 2012
    Economics 523: Industrial Organization II Fall 2012 Instructor: Tomas Sjöström, New Jersey Hall 301C, 932-7363, email: [email protected]. Time and Location: Tu, Th 4:30-5:50, Frelinghuysen Hall B1. O¢ ce Hours: Tu, Th 3:15 - 4:30, NJ Hall 301C Textbook: “Contract Theory”by P. Bolton and M. Dewatripont. Learning Goals and Assessment: The objective of this course is to familiarize the students with classic topics in Industrial Organization theory, and the most important contributions to these topics. At the end of the course, the students should have a su¢ cient understanding of this …eld to be able to produce their own independent research. There are no exams and no homework. Each student must write a term paper, present it in class, and to discuss (“referee”) another students’sterm paper. Course Outline PART A: Contracts A1. Mechanism Design B&D Ch 7 d’Aspremont, C. and L.A. Gérard-Varet (1979), “Incentives and Incomplete Information,” Journal of Public Economics, 11, 25–45 Maskin, E. and J. Riley (1984), “Optimal Auctions with Risk Averse Buyers” Econometrica, 52, 1473- 1518 Myerson, R. (1981), “Optimal Auction Design,”Mathematics of Operation Research, 6, 58-73. Myerson, R. (1988), “Mechanism Design,”in The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics http://www.kellogg.northwestern.edu/research/math/papers/796.pdf Myerson, R. and M. Satterthwaite (1983), “E¢ cient Mechanisms for Bilateral Trading,”Journal of Eco- nomic Theory, 29, 265–281. A2. Moral Hazard B&D Ch. 4 Ghatak, M., M. Morelli and T. Sjöström (2001), “Occupational Choice and Dynamic Incentives,”Review of Economic Studies, 68, 781-810.
    [Show full text]
  • Nine Lives of Neoliberalism
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Plehwe, Dieter (Ed.); Slobodian, Quinn (Ed.); Mirowski, Philip (Ed.) Book — Published Version Nine Lives of Neoliberalism Provided in Cooperation with: WZB Berlin Social Science Center Suggested Citation: Plehwe, Dieter (Ed.); Slobodian, Quinn (Ed.); Mirowski, Philip (Ed.) (2020) : Nine Lives of Neoliberalism, ISBN 978-1-78873-255-0, Verso, London, New York, NY, https://www.versobooks.com/books/3075-nine-lives-of-neoliberalism This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/215796 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative
    [Show full text]
  • Econ 712: Empirical Industrial Organization
    Fall 2018 Aviv Nevo 617 PCPSE [email protected] Econ 712: Empirical Industrial Organization The course provides a graduate-level introduction to the topics and methods of Empirical Industrial Organization (IO). It is designed to provide a broad introduction to topics and industries that current researchers are studying as well as to expose students to a wide variety of techniques. It will start the process of preparing economics Ph.D. students to conduct thesis research in the area, and may also be of interest to doctoral students in other fields. Lectures: Tuesday/Thursday 1:30-3:00, 101 PCPSE Office Hours: By appointment TA: Joao Granja de Almeida ([email protected]) Textbooks: There is no textbook for this course. For coverage of theoretical principles (that I will rely on, but not cover in any detail) see: J. Tirole, The Theory of Industrial Organization, MIT, 1988. (Tirole). For a broader coverage of empirical and public policy issues, you should also read: D. Carlton and J. Perloff, Modern Industrial Organization, 4th ed., Pearson, 2005. K. Viscusi, J. Vernon and J. Harrington, Economics of Regulation and Antitrust, 4th ed., MIT, 2005. You also might want to read several of the surveys in: R. Schmalensee and R. Willig, eds., Handbook of Industrial Organization, Volumes 1 and 2 North-Holland, 1989. (HIO). M. Armstrong and R. Poter, eds., Handbook of Industrial Organization, Volume 3, North- Holland, 2007. The two chapters from the Handbook of Econometrics, in the first section below, are probably the closest thing to a textbook for the material I will cover.
    [Show full text]
  • Agricultural Economics Collection Development Policy
    University of Nebraska - Lincoln DigitalCommons@University of Nebraska - Lincoln Collection Development Policies -- UNL Libraries Libraries at University of Nebraska-Lincoln 12-2009 Agricultural Economics Collection Development Policy Rebecca Bernthal University of Nebraska at Lincoln, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.unl.edu/librarycolldev Part of the Library and Information Science Commons Bernthal, Rebecca, "Agricultural Economics Collection Development Policy" (2009). Collection Development Policies -- UNL Libraries. 3. https://digitalcommons.unl.edu/librarycolldev/3 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Libraries at University of Nebraska-Lincoln at DigitalCommons@University of Nebraska - Lincoln. It has been accepted for inclusion in Collection Development Policies -- UNL Libraries by an authorized administrator of DigitalCommons@University of Nebraska - Lincoln. Agricultural Economics CD Policy 2009 Agricultural Economics Collection Development Policy University Libraries, University of Nebraska-Lincoln Rebecca Bernthal, Liaison Librarian, December, 2009 Approved: CDC, January 6, 2010 I. GENERAL ACADEMIC PROGRAM INFORMATION The Agricultural Economics Department is part of the Institute of Agriculture and Natural Resources (IANR) and the College of Agriculture and Natural Resources (CASNR). The faculty has appointments in the College of Agricultural Sciences and Natural Resources (CASNR), the Agricultural Research Division (ARD), and/or the Cooperative Extension Division (CED). The Department was established in 1909 as the Department of Agronomy and Farm Management. In 1911 it was renamed as the Department of Farm Management and then in 1919 became the Department of Rural Economics. Since 1949 the Department has been known as the Department of Agricultural Economics. By 1920 the Department offered 13 courses for undergraduates and graduate students.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 2 the Knowledge Economy
    Chapter 2 The knowledge economy These days, keeping your nose to the grindstone is a big, short-sighted mistake (Stewart, 1997, p xvii). Though invisible and difficult to measure, knowledge and human expertise are starting to be seen for what they are: the source of value creation (Lank, 1997, p 406). 2.1 Introduction What has become valuable in the work environment of the present belongs to what is known as the knowledge economy, the knowledge era, the knowledge age, the information age, the new economy and the new world. For the purpose of this study, the phrase knowledge economy will be used to include all of these terms. The general interest in the knowledge economy and its associated management philosophies, knowledge management, learning organizations and intellectual capital management, did not start as a whim. It came about as a direct result of the general evolution in the way in which work is valued. The shift from an agricultural economy to an industrial economy (and their associated work value systems) is at present relatively easy to recognize and understand. What is not yet as clear to most, is the impact of the shift from the industrial to the knowledge focused economy. There is, however, little doubt that the implication will be more intense and have a larger impact than that of any previous evolutionary step. The knowledge economy, which is described in some detail in section 2.2, is typified by an oversupply of information. It is ironic that the concern with information overload is also contributing to the fact that individuals are swamped by information and that managers are unable to assimilate and use information that they require to run their businesses efficiently (Davenport and Prusak, 1997, p 134; Quintas, Lefrere and Jones, 1997, p 386).
    [Show full text]
  • Making Industrial Policy Work for Growth, Jobs and Development
    Salazar- Xirinachs Nübler Kozul- José M. Salazar-Xirinachs Wright Irmgard Nübler Richard Kozul-Wright No country has made the arduous journey from widespread rural poverty to post-industrial wealth without employing targeted and selective government policies to modify its economic structure and boost its economic dynamism. TRANSFORMING Building on a description and assessment of the contributions of different economic traditions (neoclassical, structural, institutional and evolutionary economics) to the analysis of policies in support of structural transformation and the generation of productive jobs, this book argues that industrial policy ECONOMIES goes beyond targeting preferred economic activities, sectors and technolo- gies. It also includes the challenge of accelerating learning and the creation of productive capabilities. This perspective encourages a broad and integrated Making industrial policy work approach to industrial policy. Only a coherent set of investment, trade, tech- nology, education and training policies supported by macroeconomic, financial for growth, jobs and development and labour market policies can adequately respond to the myriad challenges of learning and structural transformation faced by countries aiming at achieving development objectives. The book contains analyses of national and sectoral experiences in Costa Rica, the Republic of Korea, India, Brazil, China, South Africa, sub-Saharan Africa and the United States. Practical lessons and fundamental principles for in- dustrial policy design and implementation
    [Show full text]