CHARLES W. BISCHOFF Yale University

Business Investment in the : A Comparison of Models

THE INVESTMENT BOOM THAT PERSISTED throughout the late nineteen- sixties is now over. Whether private spending for fixed capital, after allow- ance for rising prices, will increase at all in 1971 is an open question at this point. This paper attempts to supply an answer and to look a bit further ahead, into 1972 and early 1973. In order to do this, a variety of different models is presented and pro- jected into the future. This is necessary because to date no consensus has de- veloped among economists about the determinants of investment (here taken as private expenditures on nonresidential fixed capital-plant and equipment) or about the magnitude and timing of the effects of mone- tary and fiscal policies on this aggregate. As Arthur Okun has pointed out: The best example I can offer [of a purely scientific,nonideological controversy among economists]is the disagreementamong studentsof businessinvestment regardingthe relative importance of internal cash flow, the cost of external capital, and the growth of final demandas determiningfactors.' This paper also extends the preliminary attempt to explain the behavior of investment spending in 1969-70 that I reported on a year ago.2 Many models of investment behavior have been advanced, but only a few

1. Arthur M. Okun, The Political Economy of Prosperity (Brookings Institution, 1970), p. 19. 2. CharlesW. Bischoff, "Plant and EquipmentSpending in 1969 and 1970," Brook- ings Paperson EconomicActivity (1:1970), pp. 127-33.

13 14 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1971 researchershave attemptedto comparethem systematically.3The workre- portedhere is confinedto a veryhigh degreeof aggregation,which severely limits the possibilityof sharpdiscrimination between models. I can hope only to highlightthe rangeof disagreementand perhapsmore important, to suggestthe extentto whichit leads to differentpolicy prescriptions. This paper presentsempirical characterizations of a numberof points of view andreports (a) how well they explainthe investmentexperience of the post- Koreanera, with particularemphasis on 1969 and 1970;(b) the extent to whichthe modelsdiffer with respect to the way monetaryand fiscal policies affectinvestment, and the extentto whichthese differences are essential and economicallyimportant; and (c) whatthe modelshave to say aboutcapital spendingprospects over the next two or threeyears, given severalalterna- tive scenariosfor the path of the economyas a whole.

The Models

Five differentsets of equationsexplaining investment behavior are pre- sentedand applied in this paper.This selectionis representativeof fivetheo- reticalpositions on the demandfor fixedcapital goods. In each case I have separatedinvestment in equipmentfrom investment in nonresidentialstruc- tures,primarily because the tax policiesapplied to these two types of asset have divergedgreatly in the past few years.Other factors differentially af- fectingplant spendingand equipmentspending, such as the pricedeflators for the respectiveaggregates, have also moved very differently.4Except in one case, however,the form of the equationis the samefor both plant and equipment. 3. Prominentstudies involving systematiccomparisons include Dale W. Jorgenson, JeraldHunter, and M. Ishag Nadiri, "A Comparisonof AlternativeEconometric Models of QuarterlyInvestment Behavior," Econometrica, Vol. 38 (), pp. 187-212; Jorgensonand Calvin D. Siebert,"A Comparisonof AlternativeTheories of Corporate InvestmentBehavior," American Economic Review, Vol. 58 (September1968), pp, 681- 712; and Edwin Kuh, CapitalStock Growth:A Micro-econometricApproach (Amster- dam: North-Holland, 1963). 4. The price deflators for any given quarter are taken as predetermined,implying that, at least for the currentperiod and for the rangeof demandslikely to be encountered, supply is infinitelyelastic at the given price. With this proviso, all of the equations can be treated as proper demand equations. In the simulations of the future, these prices are based on price forecasts from a complete econometric model, in which the prices dependprimarily on unit labor costs or wages and on price indexesfor the economy as a whole, but also partiallyon the share of investmentin total output, with a distributed lag starting two quartersback. CharlesW. Bischoff 15 For threeof the equations,two from one model and one from another,I presentan alternativeversion, which incorporates capital gains, a factornot includedin the standardequations. The three additionalequations bring the total to thirteen.Although I mentionvarious economists in discussing the rationalebehind each of the equations,I must emphasizethat the pre- cise formalspecification of the equationsis solely my responsibility.

THE GENERALIZED ACCELERATOR MODEL The most venerablemodel, with antecedentsgoing back at least to J. M. Clark,5is basedgenerally on the accelerationprinciple, which postulates a linearrelationship between net investmentand changes in output.As modi- fied and generalizedby, amongothers, Chenery, Koyck, Eisner,and Hick- man, the model has developedas a generaldistributed lag relationship involvingboth changesin and level of output, along with the level of the existingcapacity or capital stock.6In one of a numberof formulations fallingwithin this class,a firmforms expectations about its futureoutput on the basisof the past output(or sales)of the firmitself, the industryto which it belongs,or both. It then makesplans to adjustits capitalstock toward the level that would be an optimumfor producingthe plannedoutput, if this outputwere to representa long-runequilibrium. If the adjustmentin any given periodis not complete,this can be rationalizedin terms of the additionalcosts that the firmwould incur if it tried to make a very rapid adjustment,and in terms of uncertaintythat futuredemand will prove to justify the plans.7 5. J. Maurice Clark, "BusinessAcceleration and the Law of Demand: A Technical Factor in Economic Cycles," Journalof Political Economy,Vol. 25 (March 1917), pp. 217-35. The antecedentsgo back even earlier.See C. F. Bickerdike,"A Non-Monetary Cause of Fluctuationsin Employment,"Economic Journal, Vol. 24 (September1914), pp. 357-70. 6. Hollis B. Chenery,"Overcapacity and the AccelerationPrinciple," Econometrica, Vol. 20 (January1952), pp. 1-28; L. M. Koyck, DistributedLags andInvestment Analysis (Amsterdam:North-Holland, 1954); Eisner's work on this subject,going back to 1952,is extended and summarizedin Robert Eisner, "A PermanentIncome Theory for Invest- ment: Some EmpiricalExplorations," American Economic Review, Vol. 57 (), pp. 363-90; Bert G. Hickman, IMvestment Demand and U.S. Economic Growthl(Brook- ings Institution, 1965). 7. The formalconsideration of these adjustmentcosts, as well as the costs of adjusting other factors of production, leads to extremelycomplicated theoreticalformulations, and to equations that look quite differentfrom the one I am presenting.The addition of the problemof uncertaintymakes the theoreticalformulations still more formidable. All of the equations in this paper are intended to approximatemodels of investment behaviorthat have actuallybeen applied,and thus I have not consideredthe theoretically 16 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 1:1971 The idea of a partialadjustment process is commonto all of the models presented,and will not be repeatedas each model is introduced.The dis- tinguishingfeature of the acceleratormodel is that the determinationof the plannedcapital stock is based only on output, and not on such factorsas the cost of capital, the price of investmentgoods relativeto wages, and variousfeatures of the tax system.This pure dependenceon output may resultfrom technological rigidities that permit only one capital-outputratio for each product.On the otherhand, the modelmay performwell relative to other models, not becauseof such technologicalrigidities, but because the othermodels are deficientin specifyingthe preciseway in whichother factorsdetermine the optimumcapital-output ratio. The model is completedby the assumptionthat replacementinvestment is proportionalto existingcapital stock, or plannedoutput, or some func- tion of the two. The demandsof the individualfirms are summed to obtain demandat the industryor economy-widelevel. Differencesin the capital- output ratio among firms or industrieswill introducethe possibilityof aggregationerror. Althoughfew economistswould consider them complete representations of the investmentprocess, models of this sort have been tested againsta greatervariety of data than have any of the othersunder discussion, and they have generallyperformed well. Many forecastersuse this model as at least one elementin theirpredictive equations, but theyusually modify it by addingother variables,including interest rates, cash flows, and variables designedto incorporatethe effectsof tax policies. The mathematicalstatement of the generalizedaccelerator model that I shall use is shown as equations(1) and (2) in Table 1.

THE CASH FLOW MODEL A varietyof theoreticalconsiderations have been presentedfor focusing on profitsor cash flow as a determinantof businessinvestment. Current and past profitsmay be thoughtof as a good proxyfor futureprofit expec- tations, which in turn determineinvestment.8 Given the changes in tax superior but practicallycumbersome models currentlyunder development.The most cogent discussionof the importance,as well as the difficulty,of theoreticalresearch in this area is in Marc Nerlove, "On Lags in Economic Behavior" (the Second Henry SchultzMemorial Lecture, presented to the Second World Congressof the Econometric Society, Cambridge,England, September8-14, 1970; processed). 8. See, for example,the developmentof such an equationin Model I of LawrenceR. Klein, EconomicFluctuations in the UnitedStates, 1921-1941 (Wiley, 1950). CharlesW. Bischoff 17 Table1. InvestmentEquations of Five EconometricModels GeneralizedAccelerator Model n (1) IE,t = bo + E biQt-l + bn+lKE,t-1 + Ut. i=1 (2) SubstituteS for E in the two placesit appearsin equation(1). CashFlow Model n (3) IEt = bo + E bj(F/q.)t-j + bn+lKE,e- + Ut (4) SubstituteS for E in the three places it appearsin equation(3). SecuritiesValue Model

(5) IE,t [bo + E bi(V/qK)t-] KE,t- + Ut. (6) SubstituteS for E in the two placesit appearsin equation(5). StandardNeoclassical Model n = + (7) IE.t bo + E bi(pQ/cE)I-i + bn+lKE,tKU,. (8) SubstituteS for E in the three places it appearsin equation(7). FederalReserve-MIT-Penn Model n (9) 'E,t = bo + E j(p1c.)t-i_lQt-i

n i=l + E b2JiP1C.E)t-i-1 Qt-i-l + bn+,KEa-

(10) I = bo + E bi[(p/cs)05Qt-] + bn+lKS,t-1 + Ut. i=1 Alternates (11) Substitutealternate formulation of c into equation(7). (12) Substitutealternate formulation of c into equation(8). (13) Substitutealternate formulation of c into equation(10). Definitionof Symbols b = all coefficients c = rentalprice of capital,defined, for equipment,as

qE(dE + r)(I kE - WZE)/(1 - W). For equation(9), the formula for c allows for price expectations, accordingto the followingformula: qE(dE + r -/p)(l - kE - wzE)/(1 - w). 18 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1971 Table 1 (Continued) For equations(1 1)-(1 3), the alternateformulation allows for capital gainsdue to rises in the pricesof investmentgoods; the formulais as above, exceptthat 4E/qE replacesp3/p. d = rate of physicaldepreciation of capitalgoods E = used as a subscriptto referto equipment F = sum of corporateprofits after taxes plus corporatecapital consump- tion allowances = expendituresfor equipment,constant prices IS= expendituresfor structures,constant prices i = subscript indicating time K = net capitalstock k = effective rate of tax credit n = number of periods p = output price deflator Q = grossvalue addedof the privatebusiness sector q = investment price deflator r = rate of discountused to value returnfrom futurecapital services S = used as a subscriptto referto structures t = subscript indicating time u = seriallycorrelated disturbance representing effect of other, omitted factorsinfluencing investment V = marketvalue of equitiesplus corporatebonds w = corporate income tax rate z = discountedvalue of allowabledepreciation deductions on a dollar's worth of new investment(including, where appropriate, the require- ment that tax creditsbe subtractedfrom the depreciationbase) Notes on Statistical Estimation In all equations,the parametern is determinedby experimentation. With the exceptionof equation(9), all equationsare estimatedwith the Almon polynomialdistributed lag technique,using a third-degreepoly- nomial with no restrictions.For equation(9), however,the weightshave been restrictedto taper off to zero in period t - n - 1. The disturbances,ut, from these equationsare assumedto be generated by a first-orderautoregressive process, and the following techniquesare used in makingthe estimatesreported in Table2. Consideran equationof the generalform, n Yt= bo + , ii + Ut. i=1 CharlesW. Bischoff 19 Table 1 (Continued) Formally,the assumptionof a first-orderautoregressive process implies that Ut = pUt-i + et, where p is a numberbetween +1 and -1. If each of the variables,et, is normallyand identicallydistributed with zero meanand constant variance, independentof all the X variables,and without serialcorrelation, and if Yi is considerednonstochastic, the techniqueis justified.Consistent and asymptoticallyefficient estimates of p and of the coefficientsbo, bl, . . ., bn, may be obtainedby minimizingthe sum of squaredresiduals in the equa- tion n Yt- pYt- = bo(I - p) + -(Xit -pXi,t-1) + et. This is convenientlydone by trying a varietyof values of p between -1 and + 1, formingthe "generalizeddifferences" of all the variablesfor each trial value, and then using ordinaryleast squaresestimation methods. The values of the Durbin-Watson(DW) statisticreported in Table 2 referto the residualsfrom the transformedequations, et; if this statisticis veryfar from 2.0 it is reasonableto concludethat the assumptionof a first- orderautoregressive process in the originalerrors is too simple.The next alternativemight be to assumea second-orderprocess. It shouldbe noted, however,that with equationslike the ones in this paper,all of whichhave lagged endogenousvariables on the right-handside, even a value of the DW statisticclose to 2.0 does not necessarilyindicate that the transforma- tion has removedall of the serialcorrelation. treatmentof depreciation,profits plus depreciationmight provide a better measure.Other theories have emphasized cash flow (profitsafter taxes plus depreciation)as a sourceof funds,arguing that, in the presenceof risk and imperfectcapital markets, the cost of fundsto the firmrises sharplywhen internalfunds are exhausted.9As with output,profits or cash flow may be introducedas one of severalelements, but even equationsbased on cash flow alone have been found useful for forecastinginvestment a few quar- ters ahead. The specificformulation I will test is based on cash flow gross of divi- dends. Whereasmost of the other models under discussionare basically 9. This view is developed in James S. Duesenberry,Buisiness Cycles and Economic Growth (McGraw-Hill,1958). Duesenberry stresses cash flow net of dividends(retained earnings plus depreciation)as a source of funds. This is one of several importantele- ments in the theoreticalmodel he develops. 20 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1971 theories of real (price-deflated)investment, the cash flow model is most naturallystated in termsof currentdollars. In orderto be able to compare this model with the others,which predict investment in constantdollars, I havedivided cash flow by the priceindex for the investmentaggregate being explained.The mathematicalform of the equationis givenas equations(3) and (4) in Table 1.

THE SECURITIES VALUE MODEL Severaltheories focus on the marketvalue of a firmas a determinantof its investment.James Tobin has arguedthat if managersseek to maximize the marketvalue of their corporations,they will add to their fixedcapital goods wheneverthe marginaladdition to the firm'smarket value exceeds the cost of the goods.10There are several difficulties in applyingsuch a the- ory. First, no informationis availableon the marginaleffects on market valuationof increasedspending for capitalgoods. Instead,one can try to measurethe averageratio of the marketvalue of existingphysical capital- as determinedin the stock andbond markets-to its reproductioncost, and hopethat the marginaland averageratios generally move together. Second, it is difficultto sort out the marketvaluation of physicalcapital from that of the rest of a firm'sassets. In a crudeempirical approximation to this theory,I havesimply used the ratio of the marketvalue of all existingcorporations to the net stock of plant and equipmentof the privatesector (valued at currentreproduction prices).Since this ratio is a scale-freenumber, I have multipliedit by the stock of the asset in questionat the end of the previousperiod. Inclusion of this stock also allows for replacement.This model is similarto one de- velopedby YehudaGrunfeld,11 though his rationale,which emphasizes the role of firmmarket value as a measureof expectedfuture profits, is some- 10. One place where this theory is summarizedis William C. Brainardand James Tobin, "Pitfallsin FinancialModel Building,"American Economic Association, Papers andProceedingsof the EightiethAnnual Meeting, 1967 (AmericanEconomic Review, Vol. 58, ),pp. 99-122. The guidingprinciple of the securitiesvalue model is stated on pp. 103-04: "One of the basic theoreticalpropositions motivating the model is that the marketvaluation of equities,relative to the replacementcost of the physicalassets they represent,is the major determinantof new investment.Investment is stimulatedwhen capital is valued more highly in the marketthan it costs to produceit, and discouraged when its valuationis less than its replacementcost." 11. Yehuda Grunfeld, "The Determinantsof CorporateInvestment," in Arnold C. Harberger(ed.), TheDemand for DurableGoods (University of ChicagoPress, 1960),pp. 211-66. CharlesW. Bischoff 21 whatdifferent. The modelis statedmathematically in equations(5) and (6) of Table 1.

THE STANDARD NEOCLASSICAL MODEL Dale Jorgenson,in a largebody of workwith variouscolleagues, has de- velopedand appliedseveral closely related models of investmentbehavior basedon his versionof the neoclassicaltheory of optimalcapital accumula- tion.12The term derivesfrom the focus on the classicaleconomic theory emphasizingthe relativeprices of factorsof productionas a determinantof optimal factor proportions.Several of the other theoriesrepresented by modelsdiscussed in this papercould just as well be calledneoclassical, but Jorgenson'sparticular version has been appliedin so manycases that it has becomethe standardagainst which all of the othersare measured. In the Jorgensonmodel, as in the acceleratormodel, each firm is assumed to be adjustingtowards a "desired"stock of capital.In contrastwith the ac- celeratormodel, the neoclassicalmodel assumesthat the desiredstock de- pends not only on plannedoutput but also on the ratio of outputprice to the implicitrental price of the servicesof capitalgoods. Jorgensonalso as- sumesthat the productionpossibilities facing each firm are governedby a Cobb-Douglasproduction function. Given this and severaladditional as- sumptions,the "desired"capital stock K* may be shownto equal(apQ)/c, wherep is the price deflatorfor output,c is the rentalprice of the services of capital goods, and a is the elasticityof capital stock in the production function. The formulafor c, shownin Table 1, andthe particularempirical specifi- cation I use of the statisticalseries that go into calculationof c are derived fromJorgenson's work with RobertE. Hall.13 Thebasic equations for the standardneoclassical (SNC) model are shown 12. The theory underlyingthis model is stated most fully in Dale W. Jorgenson,"The Theory of InvestmentBehavior," in Robert Ferber (ed.), Determinantsof Investment Behavior,A Conferenceof the Universities-NationalBureau Committeefor Economic Research (ColumbiaUniversity Press for the National Bureau of Economic Research, 1967). Jorgenson'svoluminous empirical work with this model begins with "Capital Theory and InvestmentBehavior," American Economic Review, Vol. 53 (May 1963), pp. 247-59. 13. Robert E. Hall and Dale W. Jorgenson,"Tax Policy and InvestmentBehavior," AmericanEconomic Review, Vol. 57 (June 1967), pp. 391-414. Hall and Jorgenson, "Applicationof the Theory of OptimumCapital Accumulation,"in Gary Fromm (ed.), Tax Incentivesand CapitalSpending (Brookings Institution, 1971). 22 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 1:1971 as equations(7) and (8) in Table 1. Equations(11) and (12) reflectan alter- nativeformulation, which has been appliedby Jorgensonand Siebert,that takes into account capital gains due to rises in the price of investment goods.14In a periodof rapidinflation, especially for construction,expected pricechange is likely to be important;the amountof buildingundertaken now becauseit will be moreexpensive later is likelyto be significant.There are, however,difficulties in representingempirically the rate of changein pricesof investmentgoods, sinceit is the expectedrate of pricechange that is relevant.15

THE FMP MODEL A somewhatdifferent version of the neoclassicalmodel is used in the FederalReserve-MIT-Pennsylvania econometric model (hereafter referred to as the FMP model.)16The originalinvestment functions for this model weremy own work(with a largeassist from Franco Modigliani and Albert Ando). Ando, Modigliani,Robert Rasche, and StephenJ. Turnovskyhave subsequentlyderived a more generaltheory for the equipmentequation.17 The equationsused here are a slightlysimplified version of those usedin the model;the principaldifference is thathere I predictequipment expenditures directlyin a singlerelationship instead of firstpredicting equipment orders and then predictingexpenditures on the basis of orders,as the model does. In contrastto the other models presentedhere, the FMP model treats equipmentand constructionasymmetrically. Instead of adjustingtoward a desiredstock of equipment,firms are assumedto adjusttoward a desired level of productivecapacity, and they respondto a changein outputprices 14. Dale W. Jorgensonand Calvin D. Siebert, "OptimalCapital Accumulationand Corporate Investment Behavior,"Journal of Political Economy,Vol. 76 (November/ ), pp. 1123-51. 15. Following Jorgensonand Siebert, I have used (qt -qt-4)/[0.5(qt + qt-4)], but a number of other formulationsare at least as plausible. I have, however, retained the Hall and Jorgensontreatment of depreciationfor tax purposes, which is theoretically preferableto that of Jorgensonand Siebert. 16. No single referenceto the complete, final version of this model yet exists. The fullest discussion of the investment sector is contained in Albert Ando and Franco Modigliani, "Econometric Analysis of Stabilization Policies," American Economic Association,Papers andProceedings of the Eighty-firstAnnual Meeting, 1968 (American EconomicReview, Vol. 59, ),pp. 296-314. For the theoreticalderivation of the equipmentequation see Charles W. Bischoff, "The Effect of AlternativeLag Distribu- tions," in Fromm (ed.), Tax Incentivesand CapitalSpending. 17. See theirpaper, "On the Role of Expectationsof PriceChanges and Technological Change in an InvestmentFunction" (; processed). CharlesW. Bischoff 23 relativeto the rentalprice of capitalby changingthe capitalintensity not of the entirestock but only of new net or replacementcapacity put into place. This model is derivedfrom an assumptionabout technology:Factor pro- portionsare assumedto be variableonly up to the point that new capacity is put into place.18 The conceptualform of the equationis: I = (p/c)*[Q - (1 -d)Q-l]t* where(p/c)* representsplanned capital intensity,(Q - Q1)* represents plannednet additionsto capacity,and (dQ_1)*represents replacement. The statisticalspecification of this relationship,shown in equation(9) of Table 1, incorporatestwo separatelag distributions,which allow the dy- namicimpact of changesin the relativeprices, interest rates, and tax pol- iciescaptured in thep/c termto varysubstantially from the dynamicimpact of the outputterms. Essentially, the impactof outputhere is similarto that in the acceleratormodel: A rise in outputsets off a temporaryboom in in- vestmentwhich then tapers off. No such temporaryboom occurs in re- sponseto a changein any of the variablescaptured in the p/c term. Thismodel also differsfrom the Hall-Jorgensonmodel in its treatmentof the variablesdetermining c, the rentalprice of capitalservices. The formula for c is the sameas that in equations(7) and (8), but r, the cost of capital,is takento be a functionof the corporatebond yield,the dividend-priceratio, and the expectedrate of changeof outputprices.19 The weightsin this func- tion arederived approximately from previous estimation of this equation.20 The equationfor nonresidentialconstruction is much closer to the one used in the standardneoclassical model. Apart from the method of com- putingthe cost of capital,the only differenceis that the priceelasticity of demandfor structuresis set at 0.5 insteadof unity.21The structuresequa- tion is (10) in Table 1. 18. A simplifiedexample of the theoreticaldifferences between the accelerator,stan- dard neoclassical,and FMP equipmentequations is found in AppendixA. 19. The theoreticaldevelopment of this formula is discussed in Ando, Modigliani, Rasche, and Turnovsky,"On the Role of Expectations." 20. See AppendixB for details on the formulation.In judging the explanatorypower of the equationboth duringand beyond the sampleperiod, this earliernonlinear estima- tion must be taken into account. 21. As for the equipment equation, the weights underlying r and also the price elasticityrepresent previous nonlinear estimates. Tests of a model similar to the equip- ment equation did not prove successful; the implication is that structuresare more flexible than equipment,and that capital intensity can be varied both before and after structuresare put into place. 24 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1971 As in the case of the standardneoclassical equations, the considerationof capital gainsleads to an alternativeformula for the rentalprice of capital services.This providesan alternativeFMP equationfor structures,shown as equation(13) in Table 1. I have used the same formulafor the rate of changeof the investmentprice deflatordescribed in footnote 15.

Performanceand Implications of the Models

The parametersof the five models have been estimatedusing quarterly data, seasonallyadjusted at annualrates, with a sampleperiod encompass- ing the sixty-fourquarters from 1953through 1968. For the thirteenequa- tions, summarystatistics are providedin Table 2. Becausethe residuals- differencesbetween actual and predictedvalues-of successivequarters are stronglycorrelated with one another,a special estimationtechnique has been used (see Table 1). As indicatedin the rho column of Table 2, nearlyall of the equations showhigh positive serial correlation of the residualsfor successivequarters. Thus, with the possibleexception of the FMP equipmentequation,22 the excellentfits have been achievedvery largelyby feedingthe last period's errorback into the equation. In the most extremecase, the equipmentequation for the securitiesvalue model has been estimatedusing first differencesof all the variables.Of course,this kind of estimationis not new or unusual,but projectionsusing a first-differenceequation require knowledge of the level of the variablein the previousperiod. If the actualvalue for thatperiod is not known,then an estimatedvalue must be used. This meansthat the total errorfor an esti- mate overtwo periodswill consistof the sum of the errorin the firstperiod plus the errorin the estimatedchange for the second period. This accumulationof errorswill not be seriousif the errorsof consecutive periods tend to cancel each other out. On the average,the sum of dis- turbancese shouldapproximate zero (see note to Table 1). But the further the projectionis carriedbeyond the last observedvalue of the dependent variable,the larger the varianceof the sumof consecutiveerrors will become. 22. In this case, the lack of apparent serial correlationin the (estimated)residuals does not disprovethe assumptionof considerableserial correlationin the (true but un- observed)errors. Instead, I believe it may reflectthe substantialamount of experimenta- tion that went into the developmentof this equation.In other words, the estimateof rho for equation (9) is probablybiased downwards. Charles W. Bischoff 25 Table 2. Summary Statistics for Five InvestmentModels Number Standard Coefficient Durbin- of terms errorof of autocor- Watson in Almon estimate relation" statistic lago Model K2 SEE&,b p DW n Equipmentexpenditures Generalizedaccelerator 0.9901 957 0.706 1.86 23 Cash flow 0.9924 841 0.585 1.71 23 Securitiesvalue 0.9874 1,016 1.000 1.98 13 Standardneoclassical 0.9893 995 0.801 1.74 13 Standardneoclassical (alternate) 0.9869 1,099 0.864 1.70 15 FederalReserve-MIT- Penn 0.9931 800 0.251 2.06 21

Constructionexpenditures Generalizedaccelerator 0.9611 553 0.849 2.15 23 Cash flow 0.9664 515 0.646 2.09 23 Securitiesvalue 0.9630 540 0.930 2.37 13 Standardneoclassical 0.9613 551 0.774 2.02 23 Standardneoclassical (alternate) 0.9579 576 0.885 2.07 15 FederalReserve-MIT- Penn 0.9733 459 0.663 2.41 17 FederalReserve-MIT- Penn (alternate) 0.9633 537 0.814 2.21 19 Source: Derived by author. See text for description of models. a. The "corrected" R2 and standard error of estimate are computed using more than the normal correc- tion factor to allow for biases due to (a) the "data mining" involved in choosing the best length of lag, n, and because p is estimated; (b) seasonal adjustment of the data; and (c) the fact that several parametersused in deriving the FMP model-parameters affecting the rental variable and the price elasticity of demand-are approximated on the basis of experience gained in previous nonlinear estimation. For these reasons, five ex- tra degrees of freedom were subtracted for the generalized accelerator, cash flow, standard neoclassical, and securities value models; nine subtracted for the FMP equipment equation; and eight for the FMP construc- tion equation. These bias adjustments are at best crude approximations. SEE refers to the square root of the estimated variance of e (not u) in the note to Table 1. TR2refers to 1 - Variance estimated for e Variance estimated for Y b. Millions of 1958 dollars. c. See notes, Table 1.

It mightbe expected,then, that whenthey are projectedseveral quarters into the future,without the knowledgeof errorsfrom previousquarters to providea correctionfactor, these equations will not performas well as they did duringthe sampleperiod. Since one of the goals of this paperis to pro- vide estimatesup to ten quartersinto the future,this is not a particularly good omen. 26 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 1:1971

ANALYSIS OF ESTIMATED PARTIAL RESPONSE PATTERNS In orderto understandwhat the estimatedequations imply about the responsesof investmentto each of its determinants,I have carriedout a numberof experiments.In eachexperiment one laggedexplanatory variable is changedby a small amount,while all othervariables are held constant, and the responseof investmentin succeedingquarters is traced.These are calledpartial responses, because if all of the variableswere allowed to move freely, the total responsein each period might well be either larger or smaller.Table 3 showsthe partialresponses to a $1 billion rise in output (andthe associatedestimated rise in cashflow and securityvalue) in the ten basic equations,period by period. For equipment,the short-runresponse patterns fall into threecategories and so do the long-runmagnitudes. According to both the generalizedac- celeratorand FMP equations,a changein outputinduces a large,tempo- raryinvestment boom, as capital(or capacity)is adjustedto its new desired level. This temporarypeak responsereflects the traditionalaccelerator ef- fect. In both cases the peak responsecomes about six quartersafter the change,and is more than twice the long-runresponse. Similar accelerator effectsare evidentin the generalizedaccelerator, SNC, and FMP construc- tion equations;and for construction,the temporarypeak responsesare even relativelylarger, more than three times the size of the long-runre- sponse.The peak effectscome a bit later in the SNC and FMP equations (elevenand ten quartersafter the change,respectively, compared with six quartersfor the generalizedaccelerator equation). The SNC equipmentequation also shows an accelerator-typeresponse, but it is muchweaker and slowerthan the responsein the FMP equipment equation.The reasonfor this, in my opinion,is as follows:I believethat the SNC equipmentequation is basicallymisspecified, in so far as it assumes that the response of investmentspending to a change in relativeprices (wages,interest rates, the investmentdeflator, tax credits,and so on) is the same as the responseto a changein output.This assumptionis an essential partof the model(see AppendixA), but it maybe empiricallyinvalid. If the assumptionof identicalresponse patterns is invalid,the SNC equipment equationfails to distinguishan explosiveresponse to outputfrom a gradual responseto relativeprices. Thus, when the responsepattern is statistically estimatedfor a periodin whichthere is substantialvariation in both output and relativeprices, the patternis reallya mixture,or average,of two dis- (UrA~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~4

'CI00r ] ON t 4 fr...00 4

:- '-i Oo og - '-- 0

CN 0 o o 00 e2m o ( .00 m~~~~~~e C1 cno ,, (N tn

- E -4 (ON - C1 oo 0 n 0oOC- t- - o

'0

CIA O mC ~ 00t~o n v U) O~0 20 - Cl - 02 0

0 - ' --4' 1 ?Giw & Y 00000 000020 -EL oo 0 "4 - Clen S443 n O 3t- 3tr 0, I..~~~~~~42 4 ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~~0 8 m ?$~~0 t0 in 00 CN l-. CcE

- t ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~00 0 ?~~~~~~00L > 00 c N I ,c> c

;. 0

o ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~02- 000 0- ,I-4 -e4 0SfC24 0240r

$-4 C,~'4 -

d 0 000 000 O

Cd -4~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~4 h~~~~~~~~ 0 ~~~~~~~~~~~~

4. .) 41 / 422444

,4 od o E04 ~~~~00 ~~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ 4A0 2 20

0.* u u (Z) Cd Cd 0~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~2~~~~~~0 28 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 1:1971 tinct responses.The estimateswould tend to show a smallerand less rapid responseto outputthan in fact occurs,but a largerand quickerresponse to relativeprices than actuallytakes place. The contrastbetween the short-runelasticities of equipmentspending with respectto outputand relativeprices, when the estimatedlag distribu- tions for the two effectsare allowedto differ,is illustratedin Table 4. It comparesthe short-and long-run responses for the two types of investment determinantsin the SNC and FMP models.As the theoreticalanalysis sug- gests, the short-runeffects of changesin relativeprices in the FMP equip- ment equation are dramaticallysmaller than the long-runeffects. In the FMP constructionequation the responsesto relativeprices are exactlyhalf of the responsesto outputin the long run, becauseof my a priori assump- tion that the long-runelasticity of constructionwith respectto p/c is one- half. The key point illustratedby Table4 is that all of the estimatedelastic- ities for the two SNC equationslie betweenthe output and relativeprice elasticitiesfor the correspondingFMP equations.This is what would be expectedif the two types of effectswere being confounded.

Table 4. Estimated Short- and Long-Run Elasticities of Capital Expendituresin SNC and FMP Models Equipmentequations Constructionequations

SNC SNC outputor FMP outputor FMP relative FMP relative relative FMP relative Quarters price output price price output price after elasticity elasticity elasticity elasticity elasticity elasticity change Q or p/c Q p/c Q or p/c Q p/c 0 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 O.000 0.000 1 0.419 1.535 0.000 0.439 0.559 0.280 2 0.658 1.691 0.152 0.856 1.219 0.610 3 0.778 1.796 0.272 1.239 1.909 0.955 4 0.832 1.855 0.367 1.591 2.567 1.284 5 0.858 1.875 0.441 1.899 3.147 1.573 6 0.884 1.862 0.497 2.149 3.636 1.818 7 0.930 1.822 0.539 2.350 3.998 2.000 8 1.000 1.761 0.569 2.505 4.238 2.119 9 1.094 1.683 0.593 2.608 4.359 2.179 10 1.203 1.593 0.610 2.658 4.362 2.181 Long run 0.757 0.902 0.902 0.843 0.991 0.496 Source: Author's estimates. These elasticities are calculated using 1970:3 values of Q and p/c, and 1970:3 initial conditions. CharlesW. Bischoff 29 The second type of responsepattern shown in Table 3 is the one indi- cated for the cash flow equations.Here too the investmentresponse tem- porarilyexceeds its long-runvalue. The overshootingis relativelymoderate, however,and the peaks come relativelylate (for the equipmentequation, not for five years;for the constructionequation, after eleven quarters). As was mentioned earlier,there are several theoreticaljustifications for a model of investmentbased on profit-typevariables. If the preferredtheo- reticalargument is that cash flow variablesdetermine a "desired"capital stock (as in the acceleratortheory), the observedovershooting of invest- ment in responseto incrementalcash flow can be interpretedin the same way that it has been interpretedin the output-basedmodels. The thirdtype of responsepattern indicated in Table3 is the responseof investmentto a change in the market value of outstandingbonds and equities.These responses start out slowlybut buildup to a ratherhigh level, especiallyafter the firstyear. No constantlong-run responses can be com- putedfor theseequations, since they haveneither a staticequilibrium nor a stabledynamic equilibrium along a pathcharacterized by a constantrate of growth.This lack of equilibriumproperties raises severe doubts about the value of the equationsin any long-termprojection, but the short-runre- sults are neverthelessof some interest.The responseof equipmentinvest- ment to a changein marketvalue is still increasingafter ten quarterswhile the constructionresponse peaks after nine quarters.Because the lag distri- butionscontain large responses in the secondand third years after a change, predictionsfrom this modelshow currentinvestment responding sluggishly at firstand very powerfully later to a changein marketvalue of outstanding securities. In additionto output,a numberof fiscal and monetarypolicy variables are includedby the SNC and FMP equationsin the termsrepresenting the rentalprice of capitalservices. Table 4 givesthe short-and long-run partial responseof investmentto changesin p/c, expressedas a percentageof the investmentthat would otherwisetake place. The effect of any particular fiscal or monetaryvariable also dependson how much it changesp/c. In Table5 I havelisted the long-runpartial elasticities of investmentspending with respectto a numberof possible policy variables.To determinethe approximateshort-run response of investmentto any variableaffecting p/c one need only multiplythe long-runpercentage shown in Table 5 by the ratio of the short-and long-runresponses shown in Table4. Thus,Table 5 shows that, accordingto equation(9), a 10 percentfall in the industrial 30 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1971 Table5. EstimatedLong-Run Partial Elasticities of CapitalExpenditures in SNC andFMP Models Equipmentequation Constructionequation Variable SNC FMP SNC FMP Output 0.757 0.902 0.843 0.991 Price of output 0.757 0.902 0.843 0.496 Price of investmentgoods -0.757 -0.902 -0.843 -0.496 Bond yield 0.000 -0.360 0.000 0.000 Rate of expectedprice change 0.000 0.161 0.000 0.000 "Real" bond yield 0.000 -0.198 0.000 0.000 Dividend yield 0.000 -0.164 0.000 -0.346 Corporatetax rate 0.114 -0.392 0.138 -0.226 Depreciationlife of asset -0.139 -0.169 n.c. n.c. Rate of tax credit 0.061 0.068 n.c. n.c. Source: Author's estimates. All elasticity calculations are made using 1970:4 values of all relative prices, except in the case of the tax credit, for which an effective rate of 5 percent was assumed, although no credit was in effect at that time. Values for other monetary and fiscal variables were: bond yield 0.0822; rate of expected price change 0.0453; real bond yield 0.0369; dividend yield 0.0337; corporate tax rate 0.48; de- preciation life for equipment 13.1; depreciation life for structures 22.8. n.c. Not computed. corporatebond yield (corresponding in 1970:4to a drop of 82 basis points) eventuallyincreases investment in equipmentby about 3.60 percent(since the elasticityin the long run is - 0.360). Table4 showsthat the declinein the bond yield will produceno increasein expendituresuntil two quarters afterthe changeand then will stimulateequipment spending by about0.61 percent(3.60 times0.152 dividedby 0.902)in the secondquarter, 1.09 per- cent (3.60 times 0.272 dividedby 0.902) in the thirdquarter, and so forth. The eventualincrease will be approximately3.60 percent,provided the expectedrate of changeof outputprices remains constant so that the entire decreaseshows up as a decreasein the "real"interest rate. If the expected rate of changeof outputprices declines by a similaramount, there will be no long-runeffect of the decreasein the bond yield. The FMP equationsuse marketyields on bondsand equities to determine the discountrate used by firmsto evaluateinvestment projects. As Table5 shows, most of the elasticitiesof p/c with respectto these yields are sub- stantial.23It is truethat these elasticitieshave not been directlyestimated in this paper, and this raises some doubt about the validity of the specific numericalvalues.24 23. The exception is the bond yield in the structuresequation. In free estimation its coefficientran up against the constraintthat it could not be negative. 24. For instances in which the responses have been freely estimated, see Ando and CharlesW. Bischoff 31 In contrast,however, the discountrate in the SNC equationsis a con- stantbefore taxes; businessmen are assumedto aim alwaysfor a 20 percent pretaxreturn; their target rate of returnafter taxes thus declineswhen the tax rate rises.This explainsthe "wrong"signs on the corporatetax rate for both SNC equations.The partialeffect of a tax risein loweringthe required after-taxdiscount rate swampsall othereffects of the tax rate on p/c. The FMP equations, however, show substantialnegative partial impacts of higherprofits taxes on investment.

Extrapolationof the Equationsto 1969 and 1970

As a test of the abilityof the equationsto predictbeyond the samplepe- riod, I have extrapolatedall except the securitiesvalue equations eight quartersbeyond the last samplepoint, with no errorcorrections. In addi- tion, the laggedcapital stock variables in eachequation are generatedfrom the past predictions.The resultsof this extrapolationor "dynamicsimula- tion" are shown in Table 6. Thistest of trackingability in 1969and 1970produces mixed results. The root-mean-squareerrors are generally larger than the standarderrors of es- timateduring the sample.25In viewof the serialcorrelation, as notedabove, this is to be expected.The peak in 1969:4 is correctlyprojected by threeof the equipmentequations, from the FMP, generalizedaccelerator, and SNC models.The simulationusing the FMP equipmentequation does extremely well for five quarters,then movesdownward in 1970more sharplythan the actualseries.26 In additionto mirroringthe downwardmovement of busi- ness output after 1969:3, this movementreflects the delayedeffect of the 1969removal of the 7 percentinvestment tax crediton equipmentexpendi- others, "On the Role of Expectations,"for equipment,and Charles W. Bischoff, "In- vestmentBehavior: A Model of NonresidentialConstruction in the ,"in American Economic Association, Papers and Proceedingsof the Eighty-SecondAnnual Meeting,1969 (AmericanEconomic Review, Vol. 60, ),pp. 10-17, for construc- tion. 25. The-root-mean-squareerrors are computedon the basis of eight observationsfor construction,but only seven for equipment,because equipment spending was artificially depressedin 1970:4 by the automobilestrike. 26. The good performanceis partly illusory, since Ando, Modigliani, Rasche, and Turnovsky, while fitting their equations only through 1968, did examine their effects on preliminarypredictions in 1969 and 1970. uS~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~c O ON (7 ON N NI

W) mBBbc(^N t 0 ) 0 ON ON OC)Il ON e t q W)I n W) vn W) tn W)tn c cq

~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~e <; k t t- > O~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~00 0^N^^^^t

t) ^ > o cz o W o ^ st o o oo Z; m c en m C'S

m~~~~~~~~~~~Wtn m - mcmc mc cq m N cq N eq >

Q~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~O zj 0 0 00 t ~~~~~~~~~~~4tn 'n :1 cXm eq e ^Xttbv. ^ I d I $ N N N mo~~~VI on k tn m wN c N cq oq oq o NN

Cd w Q wY*m ~~~~~~~~~~en:c 0 en t- VI N ON sq m F o XmNobXo .E Y s 8 m m m m m m m m N N N N N N ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~NON c- ~C' ~ o 3 : ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~nl O

= Ui i a o~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~Cs| SEa

A i .~~~~~wi (,Q *$D . . Charles W. Bischoff 33 tures.27In quantitativeterms the drop in output is the most important determinantof the declinein predictedvalues, and the generalizedaccelera- tor equation,which depends only on outputand is the second-bestpredic- tive equation,also reflectsthe decline. For construction,the standardneoclassical and generalizedaccelerator equationsprovide the best extrapolations.The SNC equation,except for a predictionof the 1969:3 peak that is one quartertoo early, catchesthe movementof the actualseries extremely well. The acceleratorequation also tracksconstruction quite well in the projectionperiod. The performanceof the two cash flow equations,in contrastto that of the threemodels in which outputplays a majorrole, is definitelyinferior. This is unexpectedbecause these two equationsprovided the second-best explanationin the sampleperiod for both equipmentand structures.Both of the cash flow equationsunderpredict badly throughout1969-70. The lowerprojections from these equations are a resultof the factthat the share of corporateprofits in outputhas been unusuallylow recently.28In trying to distinguishbetween output-based and profit-basedinvestment theories, researchersin the past have beenplagued by the veryclose relationshipbe- tween profits and sales. The profit share was exceptionallydepressed in 1969-70,even when the declinein outputis takeninto account.These years providea situationin whichthe correlationis broken,and in this one in- stance,the resultsdo not seem to supportthe profit-basedmodel. To completethe discussionof the resultsin Table6, the three"alternate" equations,which build expectationsof capitalgains into the rentalprice of investmentgoods, must be considered.The estimatedstandard errors for these threeequations shown in Table2 are largerthan the standarderrors

27. I assumethat the depressingeffect of the tax creditremoval essentially started not when it was announcedbut only when it was passed. In making this assumptionI have heededthe argumentof Saul Hymans, made in responseto an earlierdraft of this paper, that the tax credit parametercannot be set precipitatelyto zero startingin the second quarter of 1969. Although the administration'sintention to seek permanentrepeal of the tax credit was announcedApril 21, 1969, and the repeal was eventuallymade retro- active for all equipmentordered after April 18, it was not passed until . There was a large bulge in orders in the months between announcementand passage, which affectedexpenditures into 1970. A previous temporaryrepeal had affected only equipmentordered more than a month after announcement.By only graduallyreducing the credit parameterto zero, following the lead of Hymans, I have taken account of business skepticismabout the passage and effectivedate of the repeal. 28. See ArthurM. Okun and George L. Perry, "Notes and Numbers on the Profits Squeeze,"Brookings Papers on EconomicActivity (3:1970), pp. 466-72. 34 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1971 for the correspondingequations that ignorecapital gains. For the dynamic simulationsof the 1969-70period shown in Table 6, these equationsalso produceresults inferior to those from their counterpartequations. In all simulationsthese three equationsgenerally overpredict investment; this is especiallynoticeable for the alternateSNC equipmentequation, which pro- duces extremelybuoyant predictions. It is somewhatfrustrating that these equationsdo not seemto perform,because, in theoryat least, capitalgains shouldnot be ignored.It is likelythat the specificationused is too naiveand does not capturewhatever expectations are reallyheld aboutthe degreeto which expectedfuture increases in pricesmake currentinvestment more desirable. The securitiesvalue equations, in contrastto the others,have been simu- lated for 1969-70in first-differencedform. This is appropriatebecause the equipmentequation was estimatedusing first differences and the construc- tion equation,with an autocorrelationcoefficient of 0.930,was estimatedon data that werevery close to beingfirst differenced. The resultsare given in Table7. Both securitiesvalue equations generally overpredict, with the esti- mated peaks coming one quarterlate. The root-mean-squareerrors and

Table 7. Simulation of Securities Value Equations in First-DifferencedForm, 1969-70 Billions of 1958 dollars, seasonallyadjusted annual rate Equipmentexpenditures Constructionexpenditures

Yearand quarter Actual Predicted Actual Predicted 1969:1 55.4 58.7 23.8 24.8 2 57.0 60.3 23.1 25.8 3 57.3 61.1 24.6& 26.4 4 57.8& 60.9 24.3 26.5a 1970:1 56.5 61.2& 24.4 26.2 2 56.7 61.1 23.5 25.6 3 56.9 58.7 22.6 24.4 4 54.5 56.0b 21.8 22.7 Mean errore ... -3.5 ... -1.8 Root-mean-square errord ... 3.6 ... 1.9 Sources: Same as Table 6. a. Peak. b. No correction for the effect of the automobile strike was made. For equipment this observation was excluded from the calculation of mean error and root-mean-squareerror, which are based only on the first seven observations. c. Average of actual minus predicted values. d. Square root of average squared errors. CharlesW. Bischoff 35 mean errors(in absolutesize) exceedthose of nearlyall other equations. The overpredictionsreflect the laggedeffects of high valuesof the ratio of marketvalue to the reproductioncost of capitalin 1968,and the substantial lag of four to five quartersbefore the 1969downturn of equityvalues sig- nificantlyinfluences the predictions.It is of interest,however, that the errors come close to cancelingout over the eight quarters,and by 1970:4 the simulatedvalues are closerto the actualvalues than they are at any other point in the predictionperiod. The generalconclusion from these tests is that the three output-based models-FMP, SNC, and accelerator-performthe best, thoughno one of these is clearlysuperior to the othertwo. The partialresponse patterns discussed earlier provide some clue to the differingprojections for 1969and 1970.The declinein equipmentspending during1970 projected by the accelerator,SNC, and FMP equationsis ba- sicallya responseto the declineof outputfrom its 1969:3peak. The small- est declinein equipmentspending from 1969:4to 1970:4-$1.2 billion(an- nualrate, 1958prices)-is projectedby the SNC equation.It is composedof a smalland delayedresponse to the dropin outputand a negativeresponse to the removalof the investmenttax credit.The acceleratorequation pro- jects a decreaseof $2.5 billion, all due to the outputdecline; the projected drop in investmentis largerthan that of the SNC equationbecause the acceleratorequation has larger output multipliersin the short run. The FMP equationpredicts the largestdecline by far-$4.5 billion-since its responseto outputis fully as big as that fromthe acceleratorequation, and it givessome weight to the removalof the tax creditand the rise in interest rates. Thesethree equations all projectdeclines in constructionspending, again in largepart as a responseto the drop in output.The acceleratorequation ignoresthe pricerises for constructionand thus projectsonly a very small drop.Even though the FMP equationhas a priceelasticity of only one-half, it still gives the most bearishpicture of construction-a $4.6 billion de- creasefrom the 1969:1 peak-because the yield on equitiesrose 30 percent between1969:2 and 1970:2. This influencealone would reduceconstruc- tion investmentby about 15 percentwithin a year. The SNC equation, despiteits high priceelasticity, produces a projectionthat is almoston the nose. The cash flow equationsalso projectdeclines for constant-dollarspend- ing startingfrom peaksin 1969:3 for equipmentand 1968:4 for construc- 36 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1971 tion. Thesedeclines mirror the fall in cashflow that beganafter the 1969:2 peak. In addition,rapidly rising construction prices depress the constant- dollar estimatesof constructionspending even beforecash fow beginsto fall. The movementsprojected by the securitiesvalue equationsreflect first the rise in equity and bond values that took place between 1967:4 and 1969:2 and then, with a lag, the declinethat continueduntil the troughin 1970:2. The long lags reflectthe responsepatterns shown in Table 3.

Assumptionsunderlying Projections

Four types of assumptionsand adjustmentsmust be specifiedbefore the equationscan be usedto projectfuture investment. First, the path of over- all economicactivity must be projected.That projectionis not the resultof my own workwith a completeeconometric model. Instead,I have made a numberof assumptionsabout the pathsof output,cash flow, and the value of securitiesthat seem reasonableto me, and then extrapolatedthe equa- tions based on these assumptions. Second,the equationsmust be adjustedto take accountof the temporary distortionof investmentin autos and trucks,and of the level of output,in late 1970because of a strikeat GeneralMotors. Third,on January11, 1971,President Nixon announcedhis intentionto put into effect a new policy with regardto depreciationof all equipment purchasedafter January 1, 1971.As of this writing,the new ruleshave not yet been formallypromulgated, but some assumptionmust be made about the outcomeof this proposaland aboutchanges in cashflow andthe cost of capitalthat mightresult. Finally,the equationsrequire adjustment to take accountof the persis- tence of errorsthat affectedthe resultsin 1969 and 1970.

GENERAL ECONOMIC PATH The standardset of assumptionsabout futureeconomic activity corre- spondsapproximately to the "consensusforecast" for the nextten quarters. Real outputgrows slowly throughout 1971, although there is a big increase in outputin 1971:1 due to recoveryfrom the strikeat GeneralMotors, and outputin 1971:3 is depressedbecause of the effectsof an assumedsixty-day CharlesW. Bischoff 37 steel strike.The growthrate acceleratesin 1972 and 1973.These assump- tions correspondto a gross nationalproduct in currentprices of $1,046 billion in 1971and $1,137billion in 1972,or $743billion and $780billion, respectively,in 1958prices. Inflationis assumedto continue,though at a decreasingrate. The de- flator for gross national product rises 3.9 percentbetween 1970:4 and 1971:4,and 3.1 percentbetween 1971:4 and 1972:4.Tax ratesand govern- ment spendingare projectedat the officiallyplanned levels, and monetary policy is assumedto hold bond yields approximatelyat their 1971:1 levels (this correspondsto about5 percentannual growth in the narrowlydefined money supply).Thus real interestrates on bonds increaseslightly as the rate of inflation(and the expectedrate of inflation)gradually decreases. Corporatecash flow is assumedto grow rapidlyin responseto the re- coveryand to the influenceof liberalizeddepreciation policies, as specified below. From the strike-depressedlevel of cash flow in 1970:4, a rise of 40 percentis projectedby 1973:2. The currentstock marketrecovery is assumedto continue, with Stan- dard and Poor's index of the pricesof 500 commonstocks risingfrom its March1971 level of around100 to an averageof 116 in 1973:2(1941-43 = 10). This would representa 46 percent increasefrom the 79.2 low of 1970:2;it maybe comparedwith the 45 percentincrease in equityvalues in the nine-quarterperiod 1966:3-1968:4,the 62 percentrise in the fourteen quarters1962:2-1965:4, and the 74 percentrise in the ten quarters1953 :4- 1956:2.A 54 percentrise overthe 1970:2low is projectedfor the aggregate marketvalue of corporatebonds. The rates of increasein the pricedeflators for equipmentand construc- tion expendituresare assumed to declinegradually from their currenthigh rates;the assumptionsabout these deflatorsdiffer slightly from projection to projection,as they dependpartly on the strengthof the demandfor the capitalgoods in question. Generallyspeaking, these assumptionsare consistentwith one another. They havebeen derived,with some adjustments,from the two most recent forecastsmade by MichaelK. Evanswith the forecastingmodel of Chase EconometricAssociates, Inc.29

29. I am gratefulto Dr. Evans for supplyingthe forecasts and grantingpermission to use them, and for making suggestions on how to adjust his variable definitionsto correspondwith mine. I have assumed a slightly tighter monetary policy than he has assumed. 38 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 1:1971

STRIKE ADJUSTMENT A set of adjustmentsis requiredin light of the automobilestrike of late 1970and the possiblesteel strike of 1971,both to smooththe assumedpath of output and to correctfor the delay in deliveriesof equipment,particu- larly trucks. The rationalebehind the outputadjustment is as follows:The auto strike should have virtuallyno effect on the futureinvestment plans of General Motors.Most of the effectson outputare viewedas transitory;this applies to both the depressedlevels of the last half of 1970 and to the stimulated levelsof the firsthalf of 1971,when previously unsatisfied customers sought accommodation.Thus, the output numbersthat influenceGM's expecta- tion of futureoutput, on whichplanned capital stock or capacityis based, shouldhave the valuesthey would have assumedhad therebeen no strike. Though the preciseeffect of the sixty-eight-daystrike, extendingfrom September15 to November23, 1970, is not known, it appearsthat gross auto productin constantdollars, seasonally adjusted at annualrates, was depressedby about $12 billionin 1970:4.30 Recoveryfrom the strike,even if not all lost sales aremade up, shouldinflate the annualrate of real busi- ness gross productby about $5 billion in each of the firsttwo quartersof 1971. To removethe effectsof the strikeI have adjustedoutput by these amounts. Similaradjustments have been made to remove the projected effect of a steel strike. This adjustmentreduces the errorin 1970:4for all equationsthat include output, and substantiallyincreases projected investment spending in early 1971. Similaradjustments to the cash flow and securitiesvalue time series might be appropriate.However, it can be arguedthat the disturbancesto cash flow, though transitory,do constrainin a very real way the money availablefor investment,dividends, or otheruses. As for the stock market, it is virtuallyimpossible to determinehow muchdifference the strikemade. To the extentthat investorsdiscounted the strikeas a temporaryaberra- tion, there shouldbe little effect. > The second adjustmentis made for the equipmentexpenditures, espe- ciallyon trucks,that had to be postponedas a resultof the GeneralMotors work stoppage.In addition,most investmentby GeneralMotors was ap-

30. The seasonallyadjusted numbers published by the Office of BusinessEconomics show little or no effect in 1970:3. Charles W. Bischoff 39 parentlydelayed during the strike.I assumethat all desiredpurchases in 1970:3 could be made out of dealerinventories, but that $2 billion in real investmentwas postponedin 1970:4.31This was allowedfor by subtracting $2 billionfrom the interceptof all equipmentequations in 1970:4and add- ing $1 billionin eachof the firsttwo quartersof 1971(assuming that half of the postponedinvestment took place in each of these two quarters).

THE NEW DEPRECIATION REGULATIONS I have assumedthat the new depreciationregulations will take effectand that no furtherchanges in tax laws will be made. The new regulationsin- volve threechanges, all of whichhave the effectof permittingfirms to take depreciationfor tax purposesearlier than had previouslybeen allowed:(1) institutionof a newdepreciation method, called the assetdepreciation range (ADR) system,which would allow firmsto use tax lifetimesfor equipment that, in most cases, are 20 percentshorter than those previouslyin effect; (2) repealof the reserveratio test, whichimplied that sooneror laterfirms would have to provethat the lifetimesthey assumedfor tax purposeswere not very differentfrom the economiclifetimes in actualpractice; and (3) underthe modifiedfirst-year convention, permission to firmsto treat any equipmentthey havepurchased less than six monthsbefore the end of their fiscal years as if they had held it for fully six months, and equipmentbe- tween six months and a year old as if it were fully a year old. If, for example,a firm whose fiscal year correspondedto the calendar yearpurchased a machinefor $1,000in the secondquarter, it could deduct in that year, underthe old rules, only one-halfof the ordinaryfirst year's depreciationallowance. A machinewith a ten-yearlifetime for tax purposes, eligible for the double-declining-balancedepreciation method, would be eligiblefor a $100deduction (half of the ordinarydeduction for the firstfull year),and thus the firmwould pay $48 less taxesfor that year,based on the normalcorporate rate. Underthe newrules, the firmwill be ableto deducta full year'sdeprecia- tion, andin additionthe machinewill now generallyhave an assumedeight- yearservice lifetime (regardless of the actualuseful lifetime). The full year's deductionwill thus rise to $250, and the tax savingwill be $120. Of course, for any one machinelater deductionswill be smaller,and

31. I base this estimateon oral commentsby Alan Greenspanand MichaelK. Evans. 40 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1971 thus the reductionsare in essenceonly interest-freeloans fromthe govern- ment. But such "loans"are no less valuablethan others,and the FMP and SNC models take this into accountby includingthe presentdiscounted value of future depreciationdeductions as a factor in the rental cost of equipment.As long as investmentrises over time, the incrementsto corpo- rate cash flow resultingfrom the additionaltax savings in the first few yearson new equipmentwill exceedthe oppositeeffect resulting from lower deductionslater on for any givenpiece of equipment. I have estimatedthat, underthe new policy, the reductionin Treasury revenueswill be $1.6 billion in 1971and approximately$3 billion in 1973. These estimatedreductions (shown in detail in Table 10) are somewhat smallerthan those reportedby the TreasuryDepartment, because I have assumedthat, at least initially,not all firmswill take advantageof the tax savings.32Using a 48 percenttax rate,I havecalculated the effectsassuming full adoptionof the new rulesand 20 percentshorter lifetimes for all equip- ment, and have then reducedthese estimatesby 20 percent.33

ADJUSTMENTFOR 1970 ERRORS Adjustmentsmust also be made for incorrectpredictions of the models, stemmingfrom sourcesother than the auto strike,in the quartersimmedi- ately precedingthe projectionperiod. From a numberof methodsof ad- justment,34I have chosenprojection of the variablesin the first-differenced 32. Other policies that permit accelerateddepreciation of capital goods have not been fully adopted by businessfirms, even many years after their implementation.One exampleis the accelerateddepreciation methods made availablein 1954.Allan H. Young has concludedthat from 1960 to 1966 only 79 percentof the assets purchasedby manu- facturerswere depreciated under the new methods,and that otherbusiness purchasers ap- plied the methods to only 56 percentof their purchasesof equipmentand 64 percentof their purchasesof structures.Allan H. Young, "AlternativeEstimates of CorporateDe- preciationand Profits: Part I," Survey of CurrentBusiness, Vol. 48 (), pp. 17-28. 33. Not all corporationsare taxed at this rate, and not all investmentis carriedout by corporations;these facts also call for reducedestimates. 34. I have also consideredthe techniqueof autoregressiveadjustment in making the projections.That approachuses the first-orderautoregressive process built into the esti- mation procedureas a means of adjustingfor the last observederror. It allows that error to die out graduallyin a patternof geometricdecay. The projectionsfor 1971 based on this method are ratherclose to those using the first-differencetechnique. In addition, I consideredwhether a reasonableadjustment could be madeon the basis of informedjudg- ment and examinationof the 1969-70 residuals.The adjustmentsalready described for the auto strike incorporateas much a priori informationas I am willing to use at this CharlesW. Bischoff 41 form. It is consistent with the theory that, at least in the short run, the effects of past errors do not die out, and it has been used extensively by practicing forecasters. The advantages have been summarized by Daniel Suits. Three of his reasons for using this method apply in this case: . . . In short-runanalysis and forecasting,the present position is known, and ceterisparibus will continue.The importantquestion is what change from that position will result from projectedchanges in other factors.... The use of first differencesminimizes the effect of slowly moving variablessuch as population, tastes, technicalchange, etc., without explicitlyintroducing them into the anal- ysis.... Finally,use of firstdifferences minimizes the complicationsproduced by data revision.... Revisions usually alter the level at which variablesare mea- sured,rather than their year-to-yearvariation.35 It can be shown that the use of first differences is mathematically equiva- lent to adjusting the intercept of the equation so that it fits perfectly in 1970:4, and then making all projections with this altered equation. In ap- plying this method I have retained the strike adjustments described earlier.

The 1971-73 Outlookfor Fixed Investment

The ten basic equations have been projected for the ten quarters from 1971: 1 through 1973:2, on the basis of the first-differencestechnique. These projections use assumptions about the time paths of the determinants of investment that have been outlined above and that are described in greater detail in Appendix C.36The projections are listed in Table 8 and plotted in time. However, the recent and continuing boom in the investment of such regulated industriesas electric utilities and communicationsprovides an alternativebasis for ad- justing the intercept. I have made severalsets of simulationsusing judgmental intercept adjustments based on such information.In generalthese simulationsare similarto the first-differencedpro- jections; they tend to be somewhat lower because the judgmentaladjustments do not raise the estimatesquite as much as the interceptadjustment for the 1970:4 errors. 35. Daniel B. Suits, "Forecastingand Analysis with an EconometricModel," Ameri- can EconomicReview, Vol. 52 (March 1962),pp. 104-32. Quote is from p. 112. 36. The three alternateequations, which take capital gains on investmentgoods into account, have also been extrapolated,but the resultsare totally implausible,as projected expendituresin real terms first swing rapidly upward and then plunge equally rapidly. This is a result of a sQmewhatunstable response to the initial price expectationterms, which push the projectedrental value toward zero. A more sophisticatedtreatment of capital gains expectationsmight well remedy this defect. 42 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1971 Table 8. First-DifferencedProjections of Capital Investment, Using Specified Assumptions,Five Models, 1971-73 Billions of 1958 dollars, seasonallyadjusted at annualrates; numbersin parenthesesare percentagechanges from previousperiod Federal Year Securities Standard Reserve-MIT- and half Accelerator Cashflow value neoclassical Penn Equipmentexpenditures 1971 First 56.3 (+1) 56.4 (+1) 53.3 (-4) 56.6 (+2) 56.9 (+2) Second 54.7 (-3) 55.2 (-2) 56.2 (+5) 55.3 (-2) 58.8 (+3) 1972 First 55.7 (+2) 55.4 ( 0) 61.0 (+9) 55.1( 0) 62.7 (+7) Second 58.2 (+4) 57.2 (+3) 64.6 (+6) 55.0 ( 0) 66.5 (+6) 1973 First 61.1 (+5) 59.8 (+5) 67.7 (+5) 55.4 (+1) 69.7 (+5) Constructionexpeniditures 1971 First 21.6 (-2) 21.2 (-4) 19.0 (-14) 20.6 (-7) 20.6 (-7) Second 21.6 ( 0) 20.8 (-2) 17.2 (-9) 19.1 (-7) 20.2 (-2) 1972 First 21.9 (+1) 20.6 (-1) 17.8 (+3) 17.9 (-6) 20.4 (+1) Second 22.8 (+4) 20.8 (+1) 19.2 (+8) 17.2 (-4) 21.3 (+4) 1973 First 24.1 (+6) 21.4 (+3) 20.4 (+6) 17.5 (+2) 22.0 (+3) Total 1971 First 77.9 ( 0) 77.6 ( 0) 72.3 (-7) 77.2 (-1) 77.5 (-1) Second 76.3 (-2) 76.0 (-2) 73.4 (+2) 74.4 (-4) 79.0 (+2) 1972 First 77.6 (+2) 76.0 ( 0) 78.8 (+7) 73.0 (-2) 83.1 (+5) Second 81.0 (+4) 78.0 (+3) 83.8 (+6) 72.2 (-1) 87.8 (+5) 1973 First 85.2 (+5) 81.2 (+4) 88.1 (+5) 72.9 (+1) 91.7 (+4) Source: Same as Figure 1.

Figure 1.37 It is strikingthat four of the five equations(the exceptionis the securitiesvalue equation,with its long lags) projectalmost exactly the same path for equipmentspending in 1971:1 and 1971:2 (see Figure 1). After this point the paths diverge,although the acceleratorand cash flow projectionsmove together,as do the FMP and securitiesvalue projections. It is also strikingthat, whateverthe level, these four equationsall projecta 10 percentrise (annualrate) in equipmentspending in the firsthalf of 1973 comparedwith the last half of 1972.The exceptionis the SNC equation, which projectsan almost completelyflat path of real investmentfrom the secondhalf of 1971to the firsthalf of 1973.As before,it is the weaknessof the acceleratoreffect in this equation,as well as the low long-runoutput multiplier,that accountsfor the pessimisticview. 37. Proje,ctedlevels as well as percentagechanges are shown in Table 8. If the invest- ment data for 1970 are subsequentlyrevised, the levels of all projectedvariables should be revised by an equal amount. Charles W. Bischoff 43 Figure 1. Capital Expenditures,Actual, 1969-70, Projected, 1971-73

Billions of 1958 dollars,seasonally adjusted anlnual rate

70

/.' 65 FMP /

/ Securities Equipmentexpenditures / value

60/

/ Accelerator,*.e

55

50

25

20 Constructionexpenditures . > _,'

15

f I I I I 0 1- 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973

Note: All projections are made using first differences. Sources: 1969-70-Survey of CurrentBusiness, Vol. 50 (), p. 17, and Vol. 51 (March 1971), p. 9; 1971-73-author's estimates. 44 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1971 The cashflow equationfor equipmentyields a path similarto that based on the acceleratorequation. But that resultcomes about only becausethe cash flow intercepthas been adjustedupward by $10.3billion to offset its underpredictionin 1970:4.Even with this boost the projectionshows stag- nation betweenthe firsthalf of 1971 and the firsthalf of 1972. The differencebetween the acceleratorand FMP projectionsis accounted for by (1) the slightlyhigher output multipliersin the FMP equation;(2) the effectof the new depreciationrules, which adds $3.0billion to the FMP projectionby 1973:2; (3) a decreasein the nominalindustrial bond yield froma high of 8.48percent in 1970:3to an assumedlevel of 7.37 percentin 1972 and 1973;38 and (4) a decreasein the industrialdividend yield from 0.0337in 1970:4(and an earlierhigh of 0.0392)to an assumedlow of 0.0287 in 1972:1 (the effect is dampedby an assumedrecovery of the dividend yield to 0.0316 in 1973:2). If anything,I feel I have been conservativein assumingno furtherdrop in corporatebond yieldsbelow levels prevailingin March 1971.Also, the projectedeffect of the new depreciationrules may be conservativein so far as it assumesonly 80 percentadoption. The conclusionis that the projec- tion of nearly$70 billionby FMP for the firsthalf of 1973is not an unrea- sonablyhigh one. Nevertheless,I am a bit unhappyabout the unexplained interceptadjustment of $3.15billion that underliesthis figure.I believethat at least some of this representstransitory errors, and my "best guess"for equipmentspending at that stagewould be about $68 billion, halfwaybe- tween the first-differencedand unadjustedprojections. The securitiesvalue projection, which bounces back quicklyfrom an un- reasonablelow in the firsthalf of 1971,reinforces my conclusion.However, given the inevitableuncertainty about a stock marketforecast so far in advance,the numbersprojected from this equation must be considered highly speculative. As Figure1 shows,the projectionsfor constructiondiffer widely. The ac- celeratorprojections are the most optimistic.The SNC projectionsseem clearlytoo pessimistic,as are the projectionsfor 1971 from the securities value equation.This leavesthe cash flow and FMP projections,which are

38. It should be noted, however, that the "real" interest rate falls much less from 0.0417 (that is, 0.0848 minus 0.0431) in 1970:3 to 0.0404 (or 0.0737 minus 0.0333) in 1973.2, as the rate of inflation declines. There is, however, a large temporarystimulus, because the rate of inflation declines only gradually. CharlesW. Bischoff 45 close togetherbut seem a bit low. I am convincedthat the price of con- structiondoes have some negativeeffect, but not as much as is impliedby the equationswith unitaryprice elasticities(SNC, securitiesvalue, cash flow). My best guessfor the path of constructionspending is betweenthe acceleratorand FMP paths, implyingan annualrate of about $23 billion (1958 prices)for early 1973. Some of the implicationsof the projectionsfor outlaysin currentdollars arereported in Table9. Thesenumbers are all basedon the two FMP equa- tions, as projectedin first-differencedform. As indicatedabove, I feel the equipmentprojections may be a bit high, especiallyfor the latter part of the period, while the constructionprojections seem too low. With these caveats,these equationsgive the resultsthat, to me, seemthe most reason- able and the most likely to be realized.The 1971 outlook is for current- dollarexpenditures of $106.4billion, a rise of 3.7 percentabove 1970,with the level in 1958prices at $78.2billion, a 1.3 percentdecline.

Table 9. Actual Investment, 1969-70, and First-DifferencedProjections, 1971-73, FMP Model Total nonresidential Equipment Construction fixed private expenditures expenditures investment

Percent Percent Percent Year Amount increase Amount increase Amount increase Billionsof 1958 dollars 1969 56.9 24.0 80.8 1970 56.1 -1.4 23.1 -3.8 79.2 -2.0 1971 57.8 +3.0 20.4 -11.7 78.2 -1.3 1972 64.6 +11.8 20.9 +2.4 85.5 +9.3 1973 (first half)a 69.7 +11.1 22.0 +7.8 91.7 +10.2 Billionsof currentdollars 1969 65.5 33.8 99.3 1970 67.4 +2.9 35.2 +4.1 102.6 +3.3 1971 72.3 +7.3 34.2 -2.8 106.4 +3.7 1972 83.5 +15.5 37.2 +8.8 120.7 +13.4 1973 (first half)" 91.3 +13.3 40.9 +13.8 132.2 +13.5 Sources: 1969-70 values, Survey of CurrentBusiness, Vol. 51 (March 1971), p. 9; 1971-73 values, author's estimates. Details may not add to totals because of rounding. a. Seasonally adjusfed at annual rates. Percent increase shown is for 1973 first half over 1972 first half. 46 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 1:1971

Some Variationson the Projections

In orderto exploremore fully the implicationsof the modelsfor the in- vestmentoutlook in the next few years,I havemade severalsupplementary calculations.One identifiesthe differencesin investmentspending between projectionsthat includeand those that excludethe new depreciationpoli- cies. The secondsimulation shows the additionalinvestment that wouldbe forthcomingon the basis of a more bullishoverall economic outlook con- sistentwith the administration'sforecast of GNP for 1971at $1,065billion. The thirdsimulation considers the effectof differentassumptions about the path of the stock marketon the investmentprojections of the securities value model.

DEPRECIATION Table 10 recordsthe differencesin projectedinvestment that may result from the new depreciationpolicies. Since the effects are includedin the projectionsreviewed above, the investmentamounts shown in the table may be regardedeither as the contributionof the new regulationsto pro- spectiveinvestment or as the loss of investmentthat would come about if the regulationsare not put into effect.Since both equipmentand construc- tion expendituresare affectedby cash flow, the calculatedeffects use both cash flow equations.For the SNC and FMP models, only equipmentex- pendituresare influenced.The acceleratorequation is omitted; it would showzero impact by assumption.The SNC equationprojects a veryprompt and large impact, exceedingthe direct revenueloss to the Treasuryby 1971:3.The FMP and cash flow equationsshow smallerand more gradual responses.Nonetheless, by the end of 1972, the directimpacts come very close to the revenuelosses for the cash flow equations,and exceedthe reve- nue losses for the FMP equation.These impactsfor FMP and cash flow thus also imply a big "bangfor a buck" althoughonly after a substantial lag. The impactsare labeled "direct" because they do not includethe secon- dary,induced effects that wouldwork through changes in incomes,interest rates, and so on, resultingfrom the initial additionalinvestment. Such effectscould be appraisedonly by using a completeeconometric model. The qualitativecharacter of some of the secondary,complete model ef- fects can, however, be identified.The increasesin equipmentspending N 00 N ON 'ro- c*e i

t N C'-4 '4

0 ~~ t ^W000

o R N 000 '- 0

N~~~O 00t U m 0

*2n> 00 00 00 oc >oei ei 0 er en~

C) 0~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~Cl o ei '-W 0'-

;^ N~~ 00N 00 N t~~~~~~~~~~~~0 00 W) ONm

m O 00X^ X t M

0

'-4 000 0 0 2 C);- 0~~~~~~~~~~~

G i l X 8 , W~~~~~~~~~C8 - 00 ~~~~~~0

- 0 k~~~~~~~~~~~~~~0O C a . S a a . ;; H . r a = l~~~~~~~~~~~~~~C 48 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1971 should be partiallyoffset by substitutionaway from structures,although the multiplier-acceleratoreffects should guaranteethat, on balance, con- structionof nonresidentialbuildings will rise.Housing should, at least rela- tively, be hurt. It does makea difference,however, which one of the modelsmost closely reproducesreality. I findsomewhat comforting the fact that, for this policy, the computedeffects do not differby muchmore than 50 percentby the end of the projectionperiod. I do thinkthe short-runeffects computed from the SNC model are too large. The cash flow equationsmust be considered conservative,and also suspect because the equations performedpoorly when projectedin 1969 and 1970.I would thereforeselect the resultof the FMP equationas the most reliableprojection.

ALTERNATIVE 'GOVERNMENT ECONOMIC FORECAST' An alternativeset of simulationshas been made, using the widely dis- cussed governmentforecast underlying the President'sbudget projection, in which the current-dollarGNP rises to $1,065 billion in 1971. The as- sumptionsfor these projectionsare also derivedfrom a simulationof the ChaseEconometrics model. The model attainsthe highergrowth path as a resultof increasesin the interceptsof the automobile,inventory, and hous- ing demand equations.These adjustmentscorrespond to exogenous in- creasesin demand, and since the adjustedequations are used through- out the simulationperiod, output is higherin 1972 and 1973 as well. The precisenature of the "governmentforecast" assumptions is recordedin AppendixC. Table 11 givesthe resultsof the projectionsbased on these assumptions. For 1971, the variousmodels indicateimpacts of $1.0 billion for the ac- celeratormodel, $0.7 billion for cash flow, $0.4 billion for SNC, and $1.4 billion for FMP (all in real terms).Clearly the realizationof this forecast will depend on the strengthof exogenousspending in other sectors; the impetuswill not come from investment.In 1972, however,higher growth leads to largereffects. The FMP equationindicates an additionof $3.7 bil- lion in 1972if, somehow,the 1971 growthtarget is realized.

ALTERNATIVE STOCK MARKET PROJECTIONS Two alternativepaths for the stockmarket are assumed and their impacts are calculatedusing the securitiesvalue equations.In the "bearish"set of CharlesW. Bischoff 49 Table 11. Additional InvestmentProjected under "Government Forecast" Assumptions,Four Models, 1971-73 Billions of 1958 dollars, seasonally adjustedat annual rates Year Federal and Standard Reserve- half Accelerator Cashflow neoclassical MIT-Penn Equipmentexpenditures 1971 First 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.5 Second 1.3 1.0 0.6 2.0 1972 First 2.2 1.6 0.9 2.8 Second 2.6 1.6 0.9 3.0 1973 First 2.4 1.2 0.9 2.8 Constructionexpenditures 1971 First 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 Second 0.5 0.2 0.2 0.3 1972 First 0.9 0.5 0.4 0.6 Second 1.0 0.5 0.5 0.8 1973 First 0.9 0.4 0.5 0.7 Sources: Author's estimates. See Appendix C for "government forecast" assumptions.

assumptions,no increaseat all occurs in equity values over the next ten quarters(of course,the marketcould actually decline). In the otheralterna- tive, a rise of nearly63 percentin equityvalues is assumedbetween 1970:2 and 1973:2. Thisrate of increaseis exceededonly in the greatestbull market in postwarhistory, the boom between1953:4 and 1956:2. The alternativestock marketprojections lead to the resultsin Table 12. The most bullish assumedpath pushes equipmentspending projected by the securitiesvalue equationup to a level higherthan that in any other projection,though construction spending is still projectedat a lower level than is impliedby the acceleratorequation. If the marketwere in fact to rise this much,the ratio of securitiesvalue to reproductioncost of capital would be pushedfrom its low of 0.910 in 1970:2 to 1.182in 1973:2. The uncertaintyabout these projectionsmust be emphasized.It is clear that the markethas alreadybounced back strongly.The ratio of market valuesto replacementcosts has risenfrom a low of 0.910 in 1970:2to 0.961 in 1970:4, and, accordingto my preliminaryfigures, 1.050 in 1971:1. The "standard"projection raises this ratio to 1.104by 1973:2, while in a mar- ket with no increasesthe ratio would declineto 0.994. On the high path it would be 1.182in 1973:2. The path impliedby the high projectionwould 50 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 1:1971 Table12. Projectionsof InvestmentSpending for Alternative Paths of the Stock Market,Securities Value Model, 1971-73 Billions of 1958 dollars, seasonallyadjusted at annual rates Movementin 500-stockindexa

Remainsat Rises to 116 Rises to 128 Yearand half 100 in 1973:2 in 1973:2 Equipmentexpenditures 1971 First 53.3 53.3 53.3 Second 56.2 56.2 56.5 1972 First 59.5 61.0 62.0 Second 61.8 64.6 68.0 1973 First 62.0 67.7 73.4 Constructionexpenditures 1971 First 19.0 19.0 19.0 Second 17.2 17.2 17.2 1972 First 17.6 17.8 18.0 Second 18.5 19.2 20.0 1973 First 18.8 20.4 22.1 Sources: Author's estimates. a. Standard and Poor Corporation's combined index of 500 stocks (1941-43 = 10).

requirean additionalrise in the ratio of equityvalues to replacementcosts that is roughlyas largeas the reboundthat has alreadytaken place.

Conclusion

This paperhas attemptedto peekinto the futurea bit fartherahead than would be possibleusing only anticipatorydata or leadingindicators of in- vestmentsuch as appropriations,orders, or buildingcontracts. I haveintro- duceda varietyof models,some of whichmust be adjudgedless than total successes.I have emphasizeda rangeof uncertainty.On balance,however, I feel that the FMP equationsare most reliablefor projectingthe outlook, with the acceleratorprojection providing the most plausible alternative to it. Thereis enoughdiversity in the projectionsto encouragethe hope that new data will facilitatediscrimination among the models. All of the projectionsare predicatedon the implementationof new de- preciationrules, although, at the time this is written,these rulesare not yet formallyeffective. Further delay or uncertaintyabout the legal effectof the new rules could considerablydampen the outlook. In any case, neither CharlesW. Bischoff 51 theseregulations nor reinstatementof the investmenttax credit,which has been suggested,could be expectedto have largeimmediate effects, though both apparentlywould have substantiallong-run impacts, unless the acceleratoris acceptedas the best representationof investmentbehavior. The year 1971will be anotheryear of stagnationfor businessfixed invest- ment.Nonetheless, a reboundin 1972and 1973is projectedby mostmodels, and in the FMP and securitiesvalue models,the magnitudeand speed of the rise could be said to characterizeat least a "boomlet."Although none of the modelsshows investment as a dynamicsector leading the prospective recovery,it is not likelyto dragfar behind the rest of the economy.Accord- ing to the more optimisticprojections-which, I feel, are also the ones most apt to be realized-if real output grows significantlyas a result of strengthin other sectors,substantial gains in real investmentare likely to follow.

APPENDIX A

DynamicInvestment Responses in ThreeModels

To TRACE THE DYNAMIC RESPONSEthrough the accelerator,standard neoclassical,and putty-clay models, consider an industryproducing a single homogeneousproduct, say, shoes. Supposethat this industryis monopo- lized by a single company,the Achilles FootwearCompany,' that shoes are an absolutenecessity, and that demandis 50 millionpairs per year,re- gardlessof price. Nevertheless,Achilles sells its shoes at marginalcost, becauseit fearsentry by competitors.

Fixed Proportions-AcceleratorModel

Supposethat in orderto produce5,000 pairs of shoesper year,the single availabletechnology requires one machine,which may be rentedfrom the Ajax Shoe MachineryCompany for $10,000per year, and five man-years of

1. The industrymight just as well be competitive,but then there is a question of how firm size is determined. 52 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1971 labor, whichmay be hiredat a wage of $8,000per man-year.Each pair of shoes also requires10 cents' worth of leather.Thus, shoes sell for $10.10 per pair. Now, supposethat the machinesare built to last forever,but that never- theless10 percent of thembreak down permanently each year (sabotaged by a disgruntledworker, or neglectedby a carelessmaintenance man, for ex- ample)and that thesebreakdowns are equally likely regardless of the age of the machine (a nonessentialbut simplifyingassumption). Given 10,000 machines-each costing Ajax $50,000-of which 1,000 break down each year, gross investmentper year for the shoe machineryindustry is $50 million. What will be the responseif, in a given year, demandincreases to 60 millionpairs, requiring 2,000 more machines? If the firmsthat supplyAjax withequipment manage to tripletheir output, gross investment for the year in questionwill riseto 3,000machines, or $150million. In each subsequent year, the usual 10 percentof all machinesbreak down, and thus gross in- vestmentsettles down to a new level of 1,200machines, or $60 million per year. This is the familiaracceleration principle in action.

Ex Ante VariableProportions-Putty-Clay Model

Supposethat insteadof a singletechnology, there are a varietyof waysto make shoes; here are data per machinefor three methods, all of which produce5,000 pairsper year:

Cost per new machine Rental Workers $40,000 $ 8,000 5.275 50,000 10,000 5.000 60,000 12,000 4.775

With eitherthe $40,000or $60,000machine, and one-man-yearwages of $8,000, the cost of shoes is $10.14.Thus, the $50,000machine is used at this wage. If wagesrise to $10,000per year,the cost of shoes producedon the $50,000machine rises to $12.10per pair, while the cost of those pro- ducedon the $60,000machine rises only to $12.05.To avoidjunking all of its old machines,Ajax lowersthe rentalon its $50,000machines to $9,750, CharlesW. Bischoff 53 and writes off its losses, but it ordersonly $60,000 machinesto replace thosethat breakdown. With continuing breakdowns of 1,000machines per year,gross investment in the industryrises to, and stays at, $60 millionper year. If the wage did not change,but demandincreased in the way assumed earlier,the investmentresponse in this modelwould be exactlythe sameas that in the acceleratormodel. The differencelies only in the responseto a changein relativeprices-in this case the wage of man-yearsrelative to the rentalon machines.The responseto a changein the interestrate (whichis a factor underlyingthe rental price chargedby Ajax and which I have implicitlyassumed is 10 percent)would follow the same dynamicpattern. Also, the responsewould be the same if Achilles ownedthe machinesin- stead of rentingthem. This type of model is known popularlyas the "putty-clay"model, be- cause factor proportionsare variable-like putty-before machinesare built, purchased,and bolted down, but are fixed-like clay-once they are in place.

FreelyVariable Factor Proportions-Standard Neoclassical Model

Now supposethat the $50,000machines can, at a cost of $10,000,be made identicalto the $60,000machines, even afterthey are bolted down. Then, in the year of the wage change,instead of loweringthe rent on old machines,Ajax would simplyorder 10,000 adaption kits. This wouldcount as grossinvestment, and thus the investmentaggregate would rise to $150 million for one year, then settle back down to $60 million per year. The effectsof a changein demandare the sameas in the acceleratormodel, and the investmentresponse in this modelis thusidentical for changesin output and changesin relativeprices. The standardneoclassical model essentially assumesthat somethinglike this can occur, althoughthe exampleis over- simplified. To sum up the exercise:In all threemodels the responseto a changein outputis the same.The reactionto a changein wages(or, in more general models,to interestrates, tax credits,and othervariables) is quite different. In the acceleratormodel thereis no response.In the standardneoclassical model, the reactionis identicalto the responseto an equivalentchange in output.In the putty-claymodel, however,the responseto relativeprices is 54 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 1:1971 much different.In particular,it shouldbe noted that the level of gross in- vestmentin the transitionto the moreexpensive machines never overshoots its new long-runlevel.

APPENDIX B

Statistical Notes

THE CAPITALSTOCKS included in eachof the equationswere derived as fol- lows: First, benchmarksfor the net stocks of equipmentand structuresat the end of 1946and 1965were taken from the U.S. Officeof BusinessEco- nomics,OBE Capital Goods Study,in the Surveyof CurrentBusiness, Vol- ume 49 (February1969), pages 23 and 26. Thesewere 118.7and 227.8(bil- lions of 1958dollars) for structuresand 75.8 and204.0 for equipment.Then the systemsof equationsgiven by

Kt = 0.25It + (1 -d)Kt-1, where Kt = net capitalstock at the end of the period t I, = gross investmentin period t, and d' = quarterlydepreciation rate, weresolved for the valuesof d' that builtthe stocksup fromthe 1946levels to the 1965 levels, using quarterlytime series on investmentin structures and equipment.The solved values of d' were approximately0.0152 and 0.0386.Yearly depreciation rates d werederived from the valuesof d' using the formula d = 1 - (1 - d')4. These were 0.0593 and 0.1457. In specifyingthe Hall-Jorgensonstandard neoclassical model, I have adoptedtheir specificationswherever possible. The values of d are mine, ratherthan theirs. I havenot includedRobert A. Gordon'sdata on govern- ment-owned capital used in private production, nor have I adopted Gordon'sprice deflator for nonresidentialconstruction, because the num- berswere not availableon a quarterlybasis. Following Hall and Jorgen- son, I have (1) used 0.20(1 - w) as the after-taxdiscount rate; (2) rep- resenteddepreciation patterns after 1954 by the sum-of-the-years-digits formula;and (3) used 0.0587(a weightedaverage of their rates for manu- CharlesW. Bischoff 55 facturingand nonmanufacturing)for the effectiverate of the investment tax credit. For the FMP modelthe discountrate is

[2(RCBI - PX) + 1RDPI](1 - 0.2w) for equipmentand 2RDPI(l - 0.2w) for structures.RCBI is Moody's industrialcorporate bond yield. PX is the expectedrate of price change derivedin Ando, Modigliani,Rasche, and Turnovsky;it is a geometrically decliningthirteen-quarter lag on past changesof the deflatorfor private output, with nonlinear threshold effects. RDPI is Moody's industrial dividend-priceratio. The discountedvalue of the depreciationdeduction, z, is computed as 0.524zsyd+ 0.476zsl, for equipment,after 1954, and 0.534zsyd+ 0.466zsl,for structures;zsyd is the presentvalue for sum-of- the-years-digitsdepreciation and zsl is the presentvalue for straight-line depreciation.I have used 0.045 for the effectiverate of the tax credit on equipment. Rough estimatesof the marketvalue of all nonfinancialcorporations were derivedfrom a series,supplied by JamesTobin, in whichnet nonfinancial interestpayments were divided by the interestrate on new corporateissues and nonfinancialdividend payments were dividedby Moody's composite dividend-priceratio.

APPENDIX C

Assumptionsand Data Sources

THE FOLLOWINGARE THE BASIC assumptions for the projections. 1. Real businessgross product is assumedto rise $14 billion in 1971:1, under the influenceof recoveryfrom the automobilestrike, and to rise about0.9 percentper quarterfor the next four quarters,except for the ef- fects of a sixty-daysteel strike in 1971:3. For the rest of 1972,the riseis as- sumed to average1.6 percentper quarter,with a slight slowing of real growthin early 1973.This projectionis consistentwith a 1971 gross na- tional productof $1,046billion in currentdollars, or $743 billion in con- stant (1958)dollars. 2. The rate of increaseof the price deflatorfor businessgross product is 56 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1971 assumedto declinegradually from 1.1 percentper quarterin early 1971to 0.9 percentper quarterin early1973. 3. The cashflow of domestic corporations(profits after taxes plus capital consumptionallowances) is assumedto grow from $94.2billion in 1970:3 and a slightlylower level in 1970:4 to $128.2billion in 1973:2, consistent with the recoveryof output and the increasein depreciationdeductions underthe new governmentpolicy.' 4. Consistentwith the profits and depreciationassumptions, the divi- dendsof nonfinancialcorporations are assumed to risefrom $21.8billion in 1970:3 and a slightlylower level in 1970:4 to $27.4 billion in 1973:2. 5. The market value of the equities of nonfinancial corporations is as- sumedto rise 22.6 percentbetween 1971:1 and 1973:2. This is consistent with a rise of the Standardand Poor Corporation'scombined index of 500 stocksfrom a close of 100.31on March31, 1971,to 116.0in 1973:2(1941- 43 = 10). 6. Assumptions4 and 5 imply a path for Moody's compositedividend yield, determinedby dividingdividends by valueof equitiesof nonfinancial corporations;the yielddeclines to 0.0326 in 1972:1 andthen rises gradually to 0.0355 in 1973:2. The Moody's industrialdividend yield is assumedto move approximately35 basis points below the compositeyield. 7. The net interestpayments of nonfinancialcorporations are assumed to rise from $14.5 billion in 1970:4 to $17.4 billion in 1973:2. 8. The yield on new issues of corporate bonds is assumed to fall from 0.0875 in 1970:4 to 0.0765 in 1971:1 and to remainstable at that level. Moody's composite corporate bond yield is assumed to decline from 0.0854 in 1970:4to 0.0787in 1971:1 and then to move graduallytowards 0.0765. Moody's industrialbond yield is assumed to decline from 0.0822 in 1970:4 towardsa stable level of 0.0737, remaining3.75 percentbelow the com- positeyield. 9. Assumptions7 and 8 implya path for the marketvalue of thebonds of nonfinancialcorporations, evaluated by dividingnet interestpayments by the yield on corporatenew issues,which entails a rise from $166 billionin 1970:4 to $192 billion in 1971:1 and then to $227 billion in 1973:2. 10. The price deflator for producers' durable equipment is assumed to rise, but at a graduallydecreasing rate, from 1.223 in 1970:4 to approx- imately1.313 in 1973:2,varying about this path in any givensimulation in

1. All quarterlyflows mentioned are at annual rates. CharlesW. Bischoff 57 accordancewith the degreeof inflationinduced by the projecteddemand for capitalgoods. 11. The price deflatorfor nonresidentialconstruction is assumed to rise at a graduallydecreasing rate from 1.591in 1970:4to 1.865in 1973:2, varying aboutthis pathin any givensimulation in accordancewith the degreeof in- flationinduced by the projecteddemand for capitalgoods. Assumptions3, 4, and7, concerningcorporate profits, depreciation, divi- dends, and interestpayments have been checkedfor consistencywith the outputassumptions using equations adapted from the forecastingmodel of ChaseEconometric Associates, Inc., madeavailable with the permissionof MichaelK. Evans.Assumptions 10 and 11, concerningthe price deflators for capitalgoods, are derivedfrom the two most recentbasic solutions of that model, and the formulasused for varyingthese pricesin individual simulationsare derivedfrom the equationsfrom that model. The sources for this basic solutionare two unpublishedreleases of ChaseEconometric Associates, Inc., "Forecastsof February22, 1971" and "Forecastsof , 1971."The source for the model equationsis an unpublished notebook, "Macro-EconomicModel," providedby Dr. Evans.

Assumptionsfor "GovernmentForecast" Projections

These simulationsassume paths of business gross product, corporate cash flows, and price deflatorsfor businessgross product, equipment, and nonresidentialconstruction that are consistentwith achievementof the government"target" of a $1,065 billion (currentdollars) gross national productin 1971.Exogenous upward adjustments sufficient to attainthe tar- get aremade in equationsfor automobilepurchases, inventory investment, andresidential construction. The sourceis the release,"Forecasts of Febru- ary 22, 1971,"mentioned above.

Sourcesof Data

Historicaldata for the variableslisted under1, 2, 3, 4, 7, 10, and 11 are found in U.S. Department of Commerce, The National Income and Product Accounts of the United States, 1929-1965; Statistical Tables (1966); Survey of CurrentBusiness, Volumes 48 (),50 (July 1970),and 51 (Feb- 58 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 1:1971 ruary 1971).Real businessgross productis found in Table 1.8, line 3, of National Income and Product Accounts and in the corresponding tables in Surveyof CurrentBusiness. The implicitprice deflatorfor business gross product is in Table 8.4, line 3, in National Income and Product Accounts. Cashflow of domesticfinancial corporations is in Table 1.14, line 16. Net interestpayments and dividendsof nonfinancialcorporations are in Table 1.14,lines 24 and 29. Pricedeflators for equipmentand nonresidentialcon- structionare in Table 8.1, lines 9 and 10. Historicaldata for Moody'sdividend yields and Moody's bond yieldsare found in variousissues of Surveyof CurrentBusiness, generally on page S-20,and in the supplement,1969 Business Statistics, 17th Biennial Edition (1970). Historicaldata for the yield on new issues of corporatebonds are from variousissues of BusinessConditions Digest, listed as Series116. The marketvalues of bonds and equitiesof nonfinancialcorporations were cal- culatedby the author.Historical data for Standardand Poor's combined index of 500 stocks are found on page S-21 of Surveyof CurrentBusiness and in 1969 Business Statistics. Commentsand Discussion

BarryBosworth: This comparativestudy of investmentmodels is to be commendedbecause it uses a common set of data and common time period, and because,unlike severalprevious studies, it attemptsto use a common statisticaltechnique. It is strikingthat, over the period of esti- mation,the alternativeformulations of investmentbehavior all fit relatively well. Their fits are barely distinguishablefrom one another, in part because of the use of the autocorrelationadjustments, in part because of the greatpower of least-squaresregression to make things fit. But, whenwe turnto the predictions,a widerange of differencesemerges. It is somewhatdisappointing that, after a decadeof intensiveresearch, we can achieve so little agreementin predictinginvestment. In view of this situation,I decidedto look again at the basic theoriesof investmentand some of the data problemsinvolved. The simplest formulation of investmentbehavior is the accelerator model. It postulatesthat the capital-outputratio, though it may change over time, does not changein responseto other economicvariables, such as relativeprices. The neoclassicalmodel attempts to extendthe accelerator model by allowing the desired capital stock to be affectedby relative prices.In the neoclassicaltheoretical view, capitalis treatedessentially as a variable input, and thus no differentlyfrom labor. Capital can be "rented,"as it were,for the shortrun. Thus,theory ignores the irreversible long-termcharacter of investment-a matterthat is greatlystressed in the theory of the firm. The neoclassicalmodel takes a myopic view of the investmentdecision, comparingthe currentproductivity and the rental cost of capital;it thusfinesses the standardpractice of summingdiscounted futureincome flows to see whethera projectis profitableover its lifetime. The irreversibilityis broughtin, however,when the model is modified to allow for imperfectionsin the resalemarket for capital.But that leaves

59 60 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1971 us with two differentrules: The discountedpresent value of futureincome flow indicateswhether a given investmentwould be ultimatelyprofitable, whilethe myopicrule indicateswhether now is the best time to make that investment.That split of the decisionprocess is not a satisfactorysolution and its weaknessmay be empiricallyimportant, because the two rulesmay departfrom each other over the businesscycle. Long-termexpectations shouldinfluence investment behavior and they do not necessarilyconform to the businesssituation of the momentor to mechanicalmoving averages of the past. For example,after nine years of continuouseconomic expan- sion, businessmenmay have concludedin 1969 that governmentpolicy would generallykeep the economyclose to potentialoutput. The real rate of interestbecomes an odd concept in this formulation. It is the net combinationof a nominaldiscount rate used for the invest- mentdecision and a rate of expectedcapital gains (or losses) on investment goods. Onlyif the resalemarket is perfect,however, will the expectationof greatercapital gains just offsetthe influenceof an equalrise in the interest or discountrate. The two influencesmay not be symmetric. I am also botheredby the fact that the elasticityof substitutionis really the only interestingempirical parameter in the neoclassicalmodel. The focus on that elasticity,in effect,makes three bold assumptions:that firms have correct a priori knowledge of all production opportunities,that alternativemethods of productionare available,and that firmsmaximize profits.The neoclassicalmodel does offera useful analyticaltechnique for dealingwith a varietyof changesin taxes and interestrates. But some of the empirical applicationsleave me uncomfortable-for example, the exclusionof propertytaxes. Thereis a third approach,which is not well representedby any of the empiricalmodels Bischoff reviews. That model,which I shallcall the flow- of-fundsmodel, extends the neoclassicalapproach by makingthe discount rate a functionof the internalfinancial structure of the firm. The crucial aspectof this model is the balancingof financialstocks and flows. Such a modelhas the majoradvantage of specifyingan optimalrate of adjustment for capitalstocks and integratingthe theoriesof productionand valuation. John Lintnerhas done some empiricalwork alongthese lines, showingthe influenceof debtpositions as well as pricesand interest rates on investment. The Federal Reserve-MIT-Penn(FMP) model lies between the neo- classicalandf low-of-funds models. The discountrate is a weightedaverage of dividendand bond yields,and hencematches the ex post cost of capital. CharlesW. Bischoff 61 But it may not be a good measureof the ex ante cost of capitalas viewed by the firm;for example,the firmwould view the cost of equitycapital as includingexpected capital gains on stocks.The centralaspect of the FMP model,as Bischoffemphasizes, is the differentiallag in the responsesto out- put and prices.The putty-claymodel would accountfor such a differential lag, as Bischoffpoints out. But there are many other reasonswhy firms might react more promptlyto rises in output than to changesin relative prices. Empiricalwork on investmentshould recognizethat investmentarises from many differentmotives, and that these apply differentlyin different industries.Regulated industries like utilitiesdo not behavethe way manu- facturingdoes. Commercialconstruction presents still a differentcase; the decisionto producebuilding space is basicallyan inventorydecision influencedby vacancyrates. Hence,it would be usefulto disaggregatethe investmentdata and developinvestment functions by sector. These differencesbetween sectors seem especiallyimportant in the cur- rentsituation. I wouldexpect that, in the near future,investment by public utilitieswill continueto be strong;that commercialconstruction will begin to flatten out, decliningless rapidly than in recent quarters;and that manufacturinginvestment will continuerather weak until the rest of the economyresumes a substantialupturn.

RobertHall: The paperoffers a usefulcomparison of the variousmodels, but the comparisonis not as neat and clean as I would have hoped.In the first place, the statistical adjustmentfor autocorrelationobscures the differences.If the standarderrors of the equationsare taken withoutthe autocorrelationadjustment, FMP stands out as far superiorto its closest competitor,the cash flow model. Even more important,Bischoff's equations are substantialgeneraliza- tions of the underlyingmodels. For example,his versionof the standard neoclassicalmodel departsin threeways from what I would regardas the standardneoclassical model. First, the equationhas a constantterm that theoreticallydoes not belongthere. Second, the neoclassicalequation used by Jorgensondoes not sum the coefficientson a lagged, relative price variable,but sumsthe coefficientson a changein the relativeprice variable, and constrainsthe sum of the coefficientsto be zero. Third,Bischoff treats capitalstock as an independentvariable with a fittedcoefficient, while the 62 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 1:1971 neoclassicallogic requiresthat the coefficientbe equal to the replacement rate, which is supposedlyknown in advance.These departuresfrom my notion of the neoclassicalmodel are generalizationsthat should improve the fit of the equation;in otherwords, they makethe standardneoclassical (SNC) model look better during the sample period. But they may also explainwhy the investmentprojections by that model are so implausibly low relativeto those of othermodels. Somethinghas to be holdingthe SNC forecastsdown; the constantterm is one thing that could reducethe acceleratorresponse to changesin out- put, but that can't be the whole story. The flatnessof the SNC projection remains,in part, a mysteryto me.' Finally, I want to urge caution in interpretingthe calculatedeffects of changesin tax policy. Many things, such as interestrates and prices,are held constantin these calculationsand some of them would not be likely to remainconstant in fact. If price equalsfull cost, includingthe cost of capital,and if the "rental"price of capitalchanges while the price of out- put and interestrates do not, a compensatingchange in wages is implied. Thereis thus a hiddenassumption that wages go up wheneverthe cost of capital goes down. In addition,holding constantthe marketinterest rate (that is, interestbefore taxes) resultsin the interestrate aftertaxes falling by the full proportionateamount of any tax increaseor risingby the full amountof a tax reduction.In fact, one would expectthe interestrate on corporatedebt to be sensitiveto the corporatetax rate.Furthermore, there is an assumptionthat the marginalcost of borrowingis fullytax deductible and that is unrealistic;at most, the averagecost is deductible,and even that is not the case when equity funds are raised. Last, the calculations assumezero shiftingof the corporatetax, anotherextreme and unrealistic assumption.

GeneralDiscussion

RobertEisner was concernedthat the manycritical assumptions in these models be made clearin examiningthe implicationsof tax changes,espe- cially with respectto accelerateddepreciation. It is not knownhow depre-

1. I have subsequentlylearned that the problemis that the constantsin the accelerator and FMP equations are large and negative. Again, the logic of those models suggests that there should be no constants. CharlesW. Bischoff 63 ciation affects either the relativeprice of capital or the concept of cash flow relevantto capitalspending decisions. Investment functions are con- cernedwith anticipationsof thefuture, and the variablesfrom the past and presentthat are measurableserve primarilyas proxies for expectations. Thereis no particularreason to assumethat a given increasein measured cash flow due to accelerateddepreciation creates the same anticipated changesas one due to a rise in profits. Alan Greenspanfelt that the data on real investmentin structuresmight have been biaseddownward, particularly in recentyears, by the use of the officialprice deflators,which virtuallyrule out the possibilityof produc- tivity gains in construction.He noted that a more realisticprice series is available,although only on an annualbasis. Robert Eisnerregretted that the elasticityof substitutionhad been assumedto have a value of 1 for equipmentand of 0.5 for construction,rather than being freelyestimated in this study. He felt that the unity value for equipmentwas considerably too high. Bischoff emphasizedthat he had estimated the elasticity of substitutionin a numberof other studies.The estimatesof elasticityfor equipmenttended to come out somewhatabove 1 when freelyestimated, but he had scaledit down for this study on a priorigrounds.