Chapter 7: Product Differentiation

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Chapter 7: Product Differentiation Chapter 7: Product Differentiation A1. Firms meet only once in the market. Relax A2. Products are differentiated. A3. No capacity constraints. Timing: 1. firms choose simultaneously their location in the product space, 2. given the location, price competition. Spatial-differentiation model • – Linear city (Hotelling, 1929) – Circular city (Salop, 1979) Vertical differentiation model • – Gabszwicz and Thisse (1979, 1980); – Shaked and Sutton (1982, 1983) Monopolistic competition (Chamberlin, 1933) • Advertising and Informational product differentiation • (Grossman and Shapiro, 1984) 1 1 Spatial Competition 1.1 The linear city (Hotelling, 1929) Linear city of length 1. • Duopoly with same physical good. • Consumers are distributed uniformly along the city, • N =1 Quadratic transportation costs t per unit of length. • They consume either 0 or 1 unit of the good. • If locations are given, what is the NE in price? • Price Competition Maximal differentiation 2 shops are located at the 2 ends of the city, shop 1 is at • x =0andofshop2isatx =1. c unit cost p1 and p2 are the prices charged by the 2 shops. • 2 Price of going to shop 1 for a consumer at x is p1 + tx . • 2 Price of going to shop 2 for a cons. at xp2 + t(1 x) . • − The utility of a consumer located at x is • 2 2 s p1 tx if he buys from shop 1 − − 2 U = s p2 t(1 x) if he buys from shop 2 − − − 0 otherwise Assumption: prices are not too high (2 firms serve the • market) Demands are • p2 p1 + t D (p ,p )= − 1 1 2 2t p1 p2 + t D2(p1,p2)= − 2t and profit • i pj pi + t Π (pi,pj)=(pi c) − − 2t So each firm maximizes its profit and the FOC gives • pj + t c pi = − for each firm i 2 Prices are strategic complements: • ∂2Πi(p ,p ) i j > 0. ∂pi∂pj 3 The Nash equilibrium in price is • pi∗ = pj∗ = c + t The equilibrium profits are • t Π1 = Π2 = 2 Minimal differentiation 2 shops are located at the same location xo. • p1 and p2 are the prices charged by the 2 shops. • Price of going to shop 1 for a consumer at x is • 2 p1 + t(xo x) . − Price of going to shop 2 for a consumer at x is • 2 p2 + t(xo x) . − The consumers compare prices.... Bertrand competition • Nash equilibrium in prices is • pi∗ = pj∗ = c and the equilibrium profits are • Π1 = Π2 =0 4 Different locations 2 shops are located at x = a andofshop2isatx =1 b • where 1 a b 0. − − − ≥ If a = b =0: maximal differentiation • If a + b =1: minimal differentiation • p1 and p2 are the prices charged by the 2 shops. • Price of going to shop 1 for a consumer at x is • 2 p1 + t(x a) . − Price of going to shop 2 for a consumer at x is • 2 p2 + t(1 b x) . − − Thus there exists an indifferent consumer located at x • 2 2 p1 + t(x a) = p2 + t(1 b x) − − − p2 p1 1 b + a x = − + − e ⇒ e2(1 a b) 2 e and thus the demand− for− each firm is • e 1 b a p2 p1 D (p ,p )=a + − − + − 1 1 2 2 2(1 a b) − − 1 b a p1 p2 D2(p1,p2)=b + − − + − 2 2(1 a b) − − 5 The Nash equilibrium in price is • a b p∗(a, b)=c + t(1 a b)(1 + − ) 1 − − 3 b a p∗(a, b)=c + t(1 a b)(1 + − ) 2 − − 3 Profits are • 1 Π (a, b)=[p∗(a, b) c]D1(a, p∗(a, b),p∗(a, b)) 1 − 1 2 2 Π (a, b)=[p∗(a, b) c]D2(b, p∗(a, b),p∗(a, b)) 2 − 1 2 Product Choice Timing: 1. firms choose their location simultaneously 2. given the location, they simultaneously choose prices Firm 1 chooses a that maximizes Π1(a, b) a(b) • ⇒ Firm 2 chooses b that maximizes Π2(a, b) b(a) • ⇒ andthen(a∗,b∗). • What is the optimal choice of location? • 6 dΠ1(a, b) ∂Π1(a, b)∂p ∂Π1(a, b) ∂Π1(a, b)∂p = 1 + + 2 da ∂p1 ∂a ∂a ∂p2 ∂a ∂Π1(a, b)∂p where 1 =0(due to envelope theorem) ∂p1 ∂a We can rewrite • 1 dΠ (a, b) ∂D1(.) ∂D2(.)∂p2 =[p1∗(a, b) c]( + ) da − ∂a ∂p2 ∂a ∂D1(.) 3 5a b where = − − Demand Effect (DE) ∂a 6(1 a b) − − ∂D2(.)∂p2 2+a and = − < 0 Strategic Effect (SE) ∂p2 ∂a 3(1 a b) − − dΠ1(a, b) 1 3a b Thus, =[p∗(a, b) c](− − − ) < 0 da 1 − 6(1 a b) − − As a decreases, Π1(a, b) increases. • Result The Nash Equilibrium is such that there is maximal differentiation,i.e.(a∗ =0,b∗ =0) 7 2 effects may work in opposite direction • –SE<0 (always): price competition pushes firms to locate as far as possible. –DEcan be >0ifa 1/2,toincreasemarket share, given prices, pushes≤firms toward the center. – But overall SE>DE, and they locate at the two extremes. 1.1.1 Social planner Minimizes the average transportation costs. • Thus locates firms at • 1 1 as = ,bs = 4 4 Result Maximal differentiation yields too much product differentiation compared to what is socially optimal. 8 1.2 The circular city (Salop, 1979) circular city • large number of identical potential firms • Free entry condition • consumers are located uniformly on a circle of perimeter • equal to 1 Density of unitary around the circle. • Each consumer has a unit demand • unit transportation cost • gross surplus s. • f fixed cost of entry • marginal cost is c • Firm i’s profitis • (pi c)Di f if entry Πi = − − ( 0 otherwise How many firms enter the market? (entry decision) • 9 Timing: two-stage game 1. Potential entrants simultaneously choose whether or not to enter (n). They are automatically located equidistant from one another on the circle. 2. Price competition given these locations. Price Competition Equilibrium is such that all firms charge the same price. • Firm i has only 2 real competitors, on the left and right. • Firm i charges pi. • Consumer indifferent is located at x (0, 1/n) from i • 1 ∈ pi + tx = p + t( x) n − Thus demand for i is t • p + pi D (p ,p)=2x = n − i i t Firm i maximizes its profit • (pi c)Di(pi,p) f − − Because of symmetry pi = p, and the FOC gives • t p = c + n 10 How many firms? Because of free entry condition 1 t (pi c) f =0 f =0 − n − ⇒ n2 − which gives t 1 n =( )2 ∗ f and the price is 1 p∗ = c +(tf)2 Remark: p c>0 but profit =0.... • − If f increases, n decreases, and p c increases. • − If t increases, n increases, and p c increases. • − If f 0, n and p c (competitive market). • → →∞ → Average transportation cost is • 1 2n t 2n xtdx = 0 4n From a social viewpointZ • 1 2n Min[nf +2n xtdx] n Z0 s 1 n = n∗ <n∗ ⇒ 2 11 Result The market generates too many firms. Firms have too much an incentive to enter: incentive is • stealing the business of other firms. Natural extensions: • – location choice – sequential entry – brand proliferation 12 1.3 Maximal or minimal differentiation Spatial or vertical differentiation models make important • prediction about business strategies Firms want to differentiate to soften price compe- tition In some case: maximal product differentiation. Opposition to maximal differentiation • – Be where the demand is (near the center of linear city) – Positive externalities between firms (many firms may locate near a source of raw materials for instance) – Absence of price competition (prices of ticket airline before deregulation) 13 2 Vertical differentiation Gabszwicz and Thisse (1979, 1980); Shaked and Sutton • (1982, 1983) Timing: two-stage game 1. Simultaneously choice of quality. 2. Price competition given these qualities. Duopoly • Each consumer consumes 0 or 1 unit of a good. • N =1consumers. • A consumer has the following preferences: • θs p if he buys the good of quality s at price p u = − ( 0 if he does not buy where θ > 0 is a taste parameter. θ is uniformly distributed between θ and θ = θ +1; • density f(θ)=1; cumulative distribution F (θ) [0, ) ∈ ∞ F (θ): fraction of consumers with a taste parameter < θ. • 2 qualities s2 >s1 • 14 Quality differential: ∆s = s2 s1 • − Unit cost of production: c • Assumptions • A1. θ > 2θ (insure demand for the two qualities) θ 2θ p1∗ A2. c + − ∆s<θs1 (insure that < θ) 3 s1 Firms choose p1 and p2 • Price competition (given qualities) p2 p1 There exists an indifferent consumer: θ = − . s2 s1 • – A consumer with θ θ buys the quality− 2 (θ p2 p1 ≥ ≥ − ). The proportion of consumers who will buy s2 s1 e − good of quality 2 is F (θe) F (θ). − – A consumer with θ < θ and θ θ > p1 buys low s1 quality 1. So the proportion ofe consumers≥ who will p2 p1 buy good of quality 1 iseF ( − ) F (θ). s2 s1 − – if θ < θ no purchase. − Then demands are • p2 p1 D1(p1,p2)= − θ ∆s − p2 p1 D2(p1,p2)=θ − − ∆s 15 Each firm maximizes its profit • Max(pi c)Di(pi,pj) pi − The reaction functions are • 1 R1(p2)=p1 = [p2 + c θ∆s] 2 − 1 R (p )=p = [p + c + θ∆s] 2 1 2 2 1 The Nash equilibrium is • θ 2θ p∗ = c + − ∆s (A2.) 1 3 2θ θ p∗ = c + − ∆s>p∗ 2 3 1 Demands are • θ 2θ D∗ = − (A1.) 1 3 2θ θ D∗ = − 2 3 and profits • (θ 2θ)2 Π1(s ,s )= − ∆s 1 2 9 (2θ θ)2 Π2(s ,s )= − ∆s 1 2 9 16 High quality firm charges a higher price than low quality • firm.
Recommended publications
  • Product Differentiation
    Product differentiation Industrial Organization Bernard Caillaud Master APE - Paris School of Economics September 22, 2016 Bernard Caillaud Product differentiation Motivation The Bertrand paradox relies on the fact buyers choose the cheap- est firm, even for very small price differences. In practice, some buyers may continue to buy from the most expensive firms because they have an intrinsic preference for the product sold by that firm: Notion of differentiation. Indeed, assuming an homogeneous product is not realistic: rarely exist two identical goods in this sense For objective reasons: products differ in their physical char- acteristics, in their design, ... For subjective reasons: even when physical differences are hard to see for consumers, branding may well make two prod- ucts appear differently in the consumers' eyes Bernard Caillaud Product differentiation Motivation Differentiation among products is above all a property of con- sumers' preferences: Taste for diversity Heterogeneity of consumers' taste But it has major consequences in terms of imperfectly competi- tive behavior: so, the analysis of differentiation allows for a richer discussion and comparison of price competition models vs quan- tity competition models. Also related to the practical question (for competition authori- ties) of market definition: set of goods highly substitutable among themselves and poorly substitutable with goods outside this set Bernard Caillaud Product differentiation Motivation Firms have in general an incentive to affect the degree of differ- entiation of their products compared to rivals'. Hence, differen- tiation is related to other aspects of firms’ strategies. Choice of products: firms choose how to differentiate from rivals, this impacts the type of products that they choose to offer and the diversity of products that consumers face.
    [Show full text]
  • Product Differentiation and Economic Progress
    THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF AUSTRIAN ECONOMICS 12, NO. 1 (2009): 17–35 PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION AND ECONOMIC PROGRESS RANDALL G. HOLCOMBE ABSTRACT: In neoclassical theory, product differentiation provides consumers with a variety of different products within a particular industry, rather than a homogeneous product that characterizes purely competitive markets. The welfare-enhancing benefit of product differentiation is the greater variety of products available to consumers, which comes at the cost of a higher average total cost of production. In reality, firms do not differentiate their products to make them different, or to give consumers variety, but to make them better, so consumers would rather buy that firm’s product rather than the product of a competitor. When product differentiation is seen as a strategy to improve products rather than just to make them different, product differentiation emerges as the engine of economic progress. In contrast to the neoclassical framework, where product differentiation imposes a cost on the economy in exchange for more product variety, in real- ity product differentiation lowers costs, creates better products for consumers, and generates economic progress. n the neoclassical theory of the firm, product differentiation enhances consumer welfare by offering consumers greater variety, Ibut that benefit is offset by the higher average cost of production for monopolistically competitive firms. In the neoclassical framework, the only benefit of product differentiation is the greater variety of prod- ucts available, but the reason firms differentiate their products is not just to make them different from the products of other firms, but to make them better. By improving product quality and bringing new Randall G.
    [Show full text]
  • The Theory of Monopolistic Competition, Marketing's Intellectual History, and the Product Differentiation Versus Market Segmen
    Journal of Macromarketing 31(1) 73-84 ª The Author(s) 2011 The Theory of Monopolistic Competition, Reprints and permission: sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav Marketing’s Intellectual History, and the DOI: 10.1177/0276146710382119 Product Differentiation Versus Market http://jmk.sagepub.com Segmentation Controversy Shelby D. Hunt1 Abstract Edward Chamberlin’s theory of monopolistic competition influenced greatly the development of marketing theory and thought in the 1930s to the 1960s. Indeed, marketers held the theory in such high regard that the American Marketing Association awarded Chamberlin the Paul D. Converse Award in 1953, which at the time was the AMA’s highest honor. However, the contemporary marketing literature virtually ignores Chamberlin’s theory. The author argues that the theory of monopolistic competition deserves reexamining on two grounds. First, marketing scholars should know their discipline’s intellectual history, to which Chamberlin’s theory played a significant role in developing. Second, understanding the theory of monopolistic competition can inform contemporary marketing thought. Although our analysis will point out several contributions of the theory, one in partic- ular is argued in detail: the theory of monopolistic competition can contribute to a better understanding of the ‘‘product differ- entiation versus market segmentation’’ controversy in marketing strategy. Keywords Chamberlin, marketing strategy, product differentiation, market segmentation As research specialization has increased, ... knowledge outside Despite the theory’s defeat in economics, the theory of of a person’s specialty may first be viewed as noninstrumental, monopolistic competition (hereafter, TMC) influenced greatly then as nonessential, then as nonimportant, and finally as the development of marketing theory and thought in the 1930s nonexistent.
    [Show full text]
  • Price Competition and Product Differentiation Based on the Subjective and Social Effect of Consumers’ Environmental Awareness
    International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health Article Price Competition and Product Differentiation Based on the Subjective and Social Effect of Consumers’ Environmental Awareness Dayi He *,† and Ximing Deng † School of Economics & Management, China University of Geosciences, Beijing 100083, China; [email protected] * Correspondence: [email protected] † These authors contributed equally to this work. Received: 4 December 2019; Accepted: 19 January 2020; Published: 22 January 2020 Abstract: Consumer environmental awareness (CEA) can affect green consumption decisions in different and confusing ways. In order to explain the reasons for these divergences, this study divides CEA into two main components: the subjective effect and the social effect. Then, we integrate the two effects into the classic Hotelling model to study the influence of CEA’s subjective effect and social effect on price competition and product differentiation strategy. It was found that the subjective and social effects of CEA have opposite impacts on price competition and product differentiation strategies. The subjective effect of CEA increases the price and profit level of enterprises, and enlarges the difference in the environmental friendliness of products. Meanwhile, the social effect of CEA reduces the enterprises’ price and profit level, and narrows the difference in the environmental quality of products. Therefore, we suggest that it is necessary for producers of green products to distinguish between these two effects. Numerical examples
    [Show full text]
  • Product Differentiation, Oligopoly, and Resource Allocation
    Product Differentiation, Oligopoly, and Resource Allocation Bruno Pellegrino University of California Los Angeles Job Market Paper Please click here for the most recent version November 2, 2019 Abstract Industry concentration and profit rates have increased significantly in the United States over the past two decades. There is growing concern that oligopolies are coming to dominate the American economy. I investigate the welfare implications of the consolidation in U.S. industries, introducing a general equilibrium model with oligopolistic competition, differentiated products, and hedonic demand. I take the model to the data for every year between 1997 and 2017, using adatasetofbilateralmeasuresofproductsimilaritythatcoversallpubliclytradedfirmsinthe United States. The model yields a new metric of concentration—based on network centrality— that varies by firm. This measure strongly predicts markups, even after narrow industry controls are applied. I estimate that oligopolistic behavior causes a deadweight loss of about 13% of the surplus produced by publicly traded corporations. This loss has increased by over one-third since 1997, as has the share of surplus that accrues to producers. I also show that these trends can be accounted for by the secular decline of IPOs and the dramatic rise in the number of takeovers of venture-capital-backed startups. My findings provide empirical support for the hypothesis that increased consolidation in U.S. industries, particularly in innovative sectors, has resulted in sizable welfare losses to the consumer. JEL Codes:D2,D4,D6,E2,L1,O4 Keywords: Competition, Concentration, Entrepreneurship, IPO, Market Power, Mergers, Mis- allocation, Monopoly, Networks, Oligopoly, Startups, Text Analysis, Venture Capital, Welfare I gratefully acknowledge financial support from the Price Center for Entrepreneurship at UCLA Anderson.
    [Show full text]
  • Product Differentiation: a Tool of Competitive Advantage and Optimal Organizational Performance (A Study of Unilever Nigeria Plc)
    European Scientific Journal December 2013 edition vol.9, No.34 ISSN: 1857 – 7881 (Print) e - ISSN 1857- 7431 PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION: A TOOL OF COMPETITIVE ADVANTAGE AND OPTIMAL ORGANIZATIONAL PERFORMANCE (A STUDY OF UNILEVER NIGERIA PLC) Joy I. Dirisu Dr. Oluwole Iyiola Dr. O. S. Ibidunni Department of Business Management, Covenant University, Ota, Nigeria Abstract In recent years the concept of competitive advantage has taken centre stage in discussions of business strategy; that is why, one of the major challenges organizations face today is how to have a competitive advantage. In most cases a stand out product will do the job, since products are perceived as both highly relevant and meaningfully, the ability for any one product to standout in a competitive category will guarantee the success of such organization. While there are numerous ways to differentiate brands, identifying meaningful product-driven differentiators can be especially fruitful in gaining and sustaining a competitive advantage. Differentiation is when a firm or brand outperforms rival brands in the provision of a feature(s) such that it faces reduced sensitivity for other features (Sharp & Dawes, 2001). Even in industrial economics, a discipline where there is more of a tradition of providing formal statements of theoretical concepts, two eminent industrial economists felt obligated to write an article for the Journal of Industrial Economics titled "What is Product Differentiation, Really?" (Caves and Williamson, 1985). Keywords: Product differentiation, competitive advantage, organizational performance Introduction Business strategy development is concerned with matching customers requirements (needs, wants, desires, preferences, buying patterns) with the capabilities of the organization, based on the skills and resources available to the business organization, leading to the issue of core competence (Holmes and Hooper, 2000).
    [Show full text]
  • Demand and Supply of Differentiated Products
    Demand and supply of differentiated products Paul Schrimpf Demand and supply of differentiated products Paul Schrimpf UBC Economics 567 January 28, 2021 Demand and supply of differentiated products 1 Introduction Paul Schrimpf Introduction 2 Demand in product space Demand in product space Demand in 3 Demand in characteristic space characteristic space Early work Early work Model Model Model Estimation and Model identification Aggregate product Estimation and identification data Estimation steps Aggregate product data Pricing equation Estimation steps Micro data Pricing equation References Micro data References 4 References Demand and supply of differentiated products References Paul Schrimpf Introduction Demand in product space Demand in • Reviews: characteristic space • Ackerberg et al. (2007) section 1 (these slides use their Early work notation) Model Model • Aguirregabiria (2019) chapter 2 Estimation and identification • Reiss and Wolak (2007) sections 1-7, especially 7 Aggregate product data • Classic papers: Estimation steps Pricing equation • Berry (1994) Micro data • References Berry, Levinsohn, and Pakes (1995) References Demand and supply of differentiated products Paul Schrimpf Introduction Demand in product space Demand in Section 1 characteristic space Early work Model Model Introduction Estimation and identification Aggregate product data Estimation steps Pricing equation Micro data References References Demand and supply of differentiated products Introduction Paul Schrimpf Introduction Demand in product space • Typical
    [Show full text]
  • Econ 712: Empirical Industrial Organization
    Fall 2018 Aviv Nevo 617 PCPSE [email protected] Econ 712: Empirical Industrial Organization The course provides a graduate-level introduction to the topics and methods of Empirical Industrial Organization (IO). It is designed to provide a broad introduction to topics and industries that current researchers are studying as well as to expose students to a wide variety of techniques. It will start the process of preparing economics Ph.D. students to conduct thesis research in the area, and may also be of interest to doctoral students in other fields. Lectures: Tuesday/Thursday 1:30-3:00, 101 PCPSE Office Hours: By appointment TA: Joao Granja de Almeida ([email protected]) Textbooks: There is no textbook for this course. For coverage of theoretical principles (that I will rely on, but not cover in any detail) see: J. Tirole, The Theory of Industrial Organization, MIT, 1988. (Tirole). For a broader coverage of empirical and public policy issues, you should also read: D. Carlton and J. Perloff, Modern Industrial Organization, 4th ed., Pearson, 2005. K. Viscusi, J. Vernon and J. Harrington, Economics of Regulation and Antitrust, 4th ed., MIT, 2005. You also might want to read several of the surveys in: R. Schmalensee and R. Willig, eds., Handbook of Industrial Organization, Volumes 1 and 2 North-Holland, 1989. (HIO). M. Armstrong and R. Poter, eds., Handbook of Industrial Organization, Volume 3, North- Holland, 2007. The two chapters from the Handbook of Econometrics, in the first section below, are probably the closest thing to a textbook for the material I will cover.
    [Show full text]
  • Product Differentiation: a Tool of Competitive Advantage and Optimal Organizational Performance (A Study of Unilever Nigeria Plc)
    CORE Metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk Provided by European Scientific Journal (European Scientific Institute) European Scientific Journal December 2013 edition vol.9, No.34 ISSN: 1857 – 7881 (Print) e - ISSN 1857- 7431 PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION: A TOOL OF COMPETITIVE ADVANTAGE AND OPTIMAL ORGANIZATIONAL PERFORMANCE (A STUDY OF UNILEVER NIGERIA PLC) Joy I. Dirisu Dr. Oluwole Iyiola Dr. O. S. Ibidunni Department of Business Management, Covenant University, Ota, Nigeria Abstract In recent years the concept of competitive advantage has taken centre stage in discussions of business strategy; that is why, one of the major challenges organizations face today is how to have a competitive advantage. In most cases a stand out product will do the job, since products are perceived as both highly relevant and meaningfully, the ability for any one product to standout in a competitive category will guarantee the success of such organization. While there are numerous ways to differentiate brands, identifying meaningful product-driven differentiators can be especially fruitful in gaining and sustaining a competitive advantage. Differentiation is when a firm or brand outperforms rival brands in the provision of a feature(s) such that it faces reduced sensitivity for other features (Sharp & Dawes, 2001). Even in industrial economics, a discipline where there is more of a tradition of providing formal statements of theoretical concepts, two eminent industrial economists felt obligated to write an article for the Journal of Industrial Economics titled "What is Product Differentiation, Really?" (Caves and Williamson, 1985). Keywords: Product differentiation, competitive advantage, organizational performance Introduction Business strategy development is concerned with matching customers requirements (needs, wants, desires, preferences, buying patterns) with the capabilities of the organization, based on the skills and resources available to the business organization, leading to the issue of core competence (Holmes and Hooper, 2000).
    [Show full text]
  • Monopolistic Competition and Product Differentiation 16-3
    Monopolistic Competition and Product Differentiation 1. The three conditions for monopolistic competition are (1) a large number of 16 producers, (2) differentiated products, and (3) free entry and exit. a. There are many bands that play at weddings, parties, and so on. There are no sig- nificant barriers to entry or exit. And products are differentiated by quality (for instance, some bands have better musicians or better electronic equipment) or by style (for instance, different bands play different types of music). All three condi- tions for monopolistic competition are fulfilled. b. The industry for individual-serving juice boxes is dominated by a few very large firms (for example, Minute Maid, Welch’s, and Kool Aid), and there are signifi- cant barriers to entry, in part because of the large costs (for example, advertising) involved in gaining any market share of the national market. Products are, how- ever, differentiated—if perhaps only in the minds of consumers. Because of the small number of competitors, the industry is closer to oligopoly. c. There is a large number of dry cleaners, and each produces a product differentiat- ed by location: customers are likely to prefer to use the dry cleaner closest to their home or workplace. Finally, there are no significant barriers to entry. This is a chapter monopolistically competitive market. d. There is a large number of soybean farmers, and there is free entry and exit in this industry. However, soybeans are not differentiated from each other—they are a standardized product. No individual soybean farmer has market power. This industry is therefore a perfectly competitive industry.
    [Show full text]
  • Market Segmentation, Product Differentiation, and Marketing Strategy Author(S): Peter R
    Market Segmentation, Product Differentiation, and Marketing Strategy Author(s): Peter R. Dickson and James L. Ginter Source: Journal of Marketing, Vol. 51, No. 2 (Apr., 1987), pp. 1-10 Published by: American Marketing Association Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1251125 Accessed: 05-10-2016 19:00 UTC JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://about.jstor.org/terms American Marketing Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of Marketing This content downloaded from 143.107.252.158 on Wed, 05 Oct 2016 19:00:47 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms Peter R. Dickson & James L. Ginter Market Segmentation, Product Differentiation, and Marketing Strategy Despite the pervasive use of the terms "market segmentation" and "product differentiation," there has been and continues to be considerable misunderstanding about their meaning and use. The authors attempt to lessen the confusion by the use of traditional and contemporary economic theory and product preference maps. M ARKETS have been segmented and products and Rosenberg 1981; Neidell 1983; Pride and Ferrell and services differentiated for as long as sup- 1985; Stanton 1981) describe product differentiation pliers have differed in their methods of competing for as an alternative to market segmentation and 11 of the trade.
    [Show full text]
  • Impact of Product Differentiation, Marketing Investments and Brand Equity On
    1 Impact of Product Differentiation, Marketing Investments and Brand Equity on Pricing Strategies: A Brand Level Investigation 1. Introduction Most companies use marketing-performance measures such as brand loyalty, market share, price premium and customer lifetime value, to determine their success or failure. Pricing is one of the most important elements of marketing mix and pricing strategies play an important role in a company’s marketing strategy (Kotler and Keller 2012; Tirole 1988). Hence, it is not surprising to see a large body of research on pricing in both marketing and finance areas on pricing; however the application of this type of research to both theory and practice has not been as prevalent as other marketing variables (Duke 1994; Christopher 2000). One of the main reasons for this gap between theory and practice could be the difference in the orientations of marketing and finance researchers, with researchers in finance focusing on the impact of firm strategies and stakeholders’ short-/long-term expectations and marketing researchers on customer reactions and / or impact of branding on marketing strategies and decisions (Madden et al. 2006). A second reason could be that finance researchers typically use firm-level data from equity markets and the company’s financial statements, while marketing researchers generally use surveys or an experimental-research approach (Madden et al. 2006). As a result, it is not usual for marketing researchers to deal with huge databases that can explain company, consumer or product (brand) patterns and behavior, nor is it usual for them to conceptualize their research using the findings from either industrial organizations (or any approach from a broad microeconomic theory) or other fields of economic science (such as finance, etc.).
    [Show full text]