Market Segmentation, Product Differentiation, and Marketing Strategy Author(S): Peter R

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Market Segmentation, Product Differentiation, and Marketing Strategy Author(S): Peter R Market Segmentation, Product Differentiation, and Marketing Strategy Author(s): Peter R. Dickson and James L. Ginter Source: Journal of Marketing, Vol. 51, No. 2 (Apr., 1987), pp. 1-10 Published by: American Marketing Association Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1251125 Accessed: 05-10-2016 19:00 UTC JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://about.jstor.org/terms American Marketing Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of Marketing This content downloaded from 143.107.252.158 on Wed, 05 Oct 2016 19:00:47 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms Peter R. Dickson & James L. Ginter Market Segmentation, Product Differentiation, and Marketing Strategy Despite the pervasive use of the terms "market segmentation" and "product differentiation," there has been and continues to be considerable misunderstanding about their meaning and use. The authors attempt to lessen the confusion by the use of traditional and contemporary economic theory and product preference maps. M ARKETS have been segmented and products and Rosenberg 1981; Neidell 1983; Pride and Ferrell and services differentiated for as long as sup- 1985; Stanton 1981) describe product differentiation pliers have differed in their methods of competing for as an alternative to market segmentation and 11 of the trade. The major advance in recent times has been that texts (Abell and Hammond 1979; Buell 1984; Busch market researchers are using economic and behavioral and Houston 1985; Cravens 1982; Dalrymple and Par- theories and sophisticated analytical techniques in their sons 1983; DeLozier and Woodside 1978; Enis 1980; search for better ways of identifying market segments Guiltinan and Paul 1985; Hughes 1978; Kotler 1984; and product differentiation opportunities. If sheer Reibstein 1985) describe it as a complement or means amount of statistical analysis and psychological jar- of implementing market segmentation.1 In addition, gon were the criterion, market segmentation could threebe of the texts (Evans and Berman 1982; Mandel judged to have shifted in status from an art to a sci- and Rosenberg 1981; Pride and Ferrell 1985) limit ence. product differentiation to only nonphysical product We therefore might expect that by now characteristics. the basic purpose, definition of terms, and theory Theunderlying potential for misunderstanding is exacerbated market segmentation and product differentiation by the discussion would of "undifferentiated" and "differ- have been consistently described and well entiated" understood. marketing strategies. These terms are used This is not the case. A review of 16 contemporary to indicate whether or not marketing strategy is based marketing textbooks reveals considerable on recognitionconfusion. of market segments. Where product Five of the texts (Evans and Berman differentiation1982; Mandel is discussed as an alternative to market segmentation, it is described as being an undifferen- tiated marketing strategy. This element of confusion Peter R. Dickson is Assistant Professor and James L. Ginter is Professor, Academic Faculty of Marketing, The Ohio State University. The authors gratefully acknowledge the thoughtful comments and criticisms 'Four texts, onthose ear- of Assael (1985), Cunningham and Cunningham lier versions of the article provided by Brian Ratchford, (1981), Cynthia McCarthy Fraser, and Perreault (1984), and Scott, Warshaw, and Alan Sawyer, Fred Sturdivant, W. Wayne Talarzyk, TaylorBarton (1985) Weitz, are not and included in the classification because they do anonymous JM reviewers. not use the term "product differentiation" in the discussion of market segmentation. Journal of Marketing Vol. 51 (April 1987), 1-10. Market Segmentation, Product Differentiation, and Marketing Strategy / 1 This content downloaded from 143.107.252.158 on Wed, 05 Oct 2016 19:00:47 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms arises from the fact that various authors discuss dif- knowledge or other market "frictions," but a reflec- ferentiation of the market, products, and strategy, and tion of the unsuccessful and successful attempts of the distinctions are seldom made clear. manufacturers to adapt their products to the needs and We attempt to clarify the current misunderstand- tastes of different buyers.2 In his first edition, Cham- ing by precisely defining and contrasting market seg- berlin stated that there seemed to be no particular rea- mentation, product differentiation, and demand func- son why the demand curve would change when a tion modification on both theoretical and practical product is differentiated. However, by his third edi- dimensions. In the first section we present some of tion, Chamberlin had recognized that the demand curve the theories and perspectives of market segmentation would move to the right and therefore become less and product differentiation that have been developed price elastic when the differentiated product more ex- by economists and marketers. We then offer a set of actly satisfied consumer needs. definitions in an attempt to lessen the current confu- Porter (1976) also viewed product differentiation sion in terminology. Finally, we use preference space as depending on both physical product characteristics mapping and practical examples to illustrate the im- and other elements of the marketing mix. Like Cham- portant differences and relationships between product berlin, he recognized that product differentiation can differentiation and demand modification, given var- be based on perceived as well as actual physical and ious states of demand heterogeneity. nonphysical product differences. Porter also adhered to the traditional operational definition of product dif- ferentiation as the degree of cross-price inelasticity with Historical Perspectives respect to competing brands. In a demand equation The concepts of product differentiation and market this cross-inelasticity is represented by a demand segmentation have long been discussed in the litera- function for the firm's offering that is relatively un- ture. One of the pioneers of marketing thought (Shaw affected by changes in the prices of competing brands. 1912) described the strategy of product differentiation Samuelson (1976) discussed what we term "de- as meeting human wants more accurately than the mand function modification" when he asserted that competition. The result is a "buildup of demand" for suppliers "deliberately fragment" industry demand the producer's product and a potential for a price level curves into smaller segments through "contrived" higher than that of the existing stock commodity. In product differentiation. His leading economics text thus discussing the need to treat each distinct geographic takes the position that the supplier is the major cause region as a separate distribution problem, Shaw em- of segmented market demand. Samuelson acknowl- phasized as equally important the recognition of eco- edged that product differentiation can be a genuine nomic and social market "contours" and the need also response to differing consumer needs, but he clearly to treat these as separate marketing problems. Besides believed that most product differentiation is "artifi- specifically recommending separate contour or seg- cial." He also repeated Galbraith's (1967) assertion ment analysis, he pointed out that the law of dimin- that this is achieved by advertising that "distorts" con- ishing returns imposes a limit on the practical value sumer demand. to the company of catering to these different markets. In his classic article, Smith (1956) expressed a view Also generally overlooked by both marketers and of product differentiation similar to Samuelson's posi- economists has been what Chamberlin (1965) had to tion. He described product differentiation as an at- say about market segmentation and product differen- tempt to alter the shape of the price-quantity demand tiation in his theory of monopolistic competition, first curve facing the individual supplier using advertising published in 1933. Product differentiation was de- and promotion. If Smith was referring to alteration of fined simply as distinguishing the goods or services the consumer's demand function when he described of one seller from those of another on any basis that product differentiation as being "concerned with the is important to the buyer and leads to a preference. bending of demand to the will of supply," this de- Chamberlin recognized the importance of both con- scription clearly differs from the view of Chamberlin sumer perceptions and nonphysical product character- and Porter and fits what we subsequently term "de- istics in observing that the basis of differentiation could mand function modification." If, however, Smith ac- be real or imagined, arising from distinct product, tually was referring to alteration of the perceived vec- packaging, or distribution differences, or the prestige tor of product characteristics, his argument is consistent value of a trademark and trade name (e.g., Coca-Cola, with those of Chamberlin and Porter with the excep- Kodak, or Calvin Klein). Chamberlin also recognized
Recommended publications
  • Product Differentiation
    Product differentiation Industrial Organization Bernard Caillaud Master APE - Paris School of Economics September 22, 2016 Bernard Caillaud Product differentiation Motivation The Bertrand paradox relies on the fact buyers choose the cheap- est firm, even for very small price differences. In practice, some buyers may continue to buy from the most expensive firms because they have an intrinsic preference for the product sold by that firm: Notion of differentiation. Indeed, assuming an homogeneous product is not realistic: rarely exist two identical goods in this sense For objective reasons: products differ in their physical char- acteristics, in their design, ... For subjective reasons: even when physical differences are hard to see for consumers, branding may well make two prod- ucts appear differently in the consumers' eyes Bernard Caillaud Product differentiation Motivation Differentiation among products is above all a property of con- sumers' preferences: Taste for diversity Heterogeneity of consumers' taste But it has major consequences in terms of imperfectly competi- tive behavior: so, the analysis of differentiation allows for a richer discussion and comparison of price competition models vs quan- tity competition models. Also related to the practical question (for competition authori- ties) of market definition: set of goods highly substitutable among themselves and poorly substitutable with goods outside this set Bernard Caillaud Product differentiation Motivation Firms have in general an incentive to affect the degree of differ- entiation of their products compared to rivals'. Hence, differen- tiation is related to other aspects of firms’ strategies. Choice of products: firms choose how to differentiate from rivals, this impacts the type of products that they choose to offer and the diversity of products that consumers face.
    [Show full text]
  • Product Differentiation and Economic Progress
    THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF AUSTRIAN ECONOMICS 12, NO. 1 (2009): 17–35 PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION AND ECONOMIC PROGRESS RANDALL G. HOLCOMBE ABSTRACT: In neoclassical theory, product differentiation provides consumers with a variety of different products within a particular industry, rather than a homogeneous product that characterizes purely competitive markets. The welfare-enhancing benefit of product differentiation is the greater variety of products available to consumers, which comes at the cost of a higher average total cost of production. In reality, firms do not differentiate their products to make them different, or to give consumers variety, but to make them better, so consumers would rather buy that firm’s product rather than the product of a competitor. When product differentiation is seen as a strategy to improve products rather than just to make them different, product differentiation emerges as the engine of economic progress. In contrast to the neoclassical framework, where product differentiation imposes a cost on the economy in exchange for more product variety, in real- ity product differentiation lowers costs, creates better products for consumers, and generates economic progress. n the neoclassical theory of the firm, product differentiation enhances consumer welfare by offering consumers greater variety, Ibut that benefit is offset by the higher average cost of production for monopolistically competitive firms. In the neoclassical framework, the only benefit of product differentiation is the greater variety of prod- ucts available, but the reason firms differentiate their products is not just to make them different from the products of other firms, but to make them better. By improving product quality and bringing new Randall G.
    [Show full text]
  • The Theory of Monopolistic Competition, Marketing's Intellectual History, and the Product Differentiation Versus Market Segmen
    Journal of Macromarketing 31(1) 73-84 ª The Author(s) 2011 The Theory of Monopolistic Competition, Reprints and permission: sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav Marketing’s Intellectual History, and the DOI: 10.1177/0276146710382119 Product Differentiation Versus Market http://jmk.sagepub.com Segmentation Controversy Shelby D. Hunt1 Abstract Edward Chamberlin’s theory of monopolistic competition influenced greatly the development of marketing theory and thought in the 1930s to the 1960s. Indeed, marketers held the theory in such high regard that the American Marketing Association awarded Chamberlin the Paul D. Converse Award in 1953, which at the time was the AMA’s highest honor. However, the contemporary marketing literature virtually ignores Chamberlin’s theory. The author argues that the theory of monopolistic competition deserves reexamining on two grounds. First, marketing scholars should know their discipline’s intellectual history, to which Chamberlin’s theory played a significant role in developing. Second, understanding the theory of monopolistic competition can inform contemporary marketing thought. Although our analysis will point out several contributions of the theory, one in partic- ular is argued in detail: the theory of monopolistic competition can contribute to a better understanding of the ‘‘product differ- entiation versus market segmentation’’ controversy in marketing strategy. Keywords Chamberlin, marketing strategy, product differentiation, market segmentation As research specialization has increased, ... knowledge outside Despite the theory’s defeat in economics, the theory of of a person’s specialty may first be viewed as noninstrumental, monopolistic competition (hereafter, TMC) influenced greatly then as nonessential, then as nonimportant, and finally as the development of marketing theory and thought in the 1930s nonexistent.
    [Show full text]
  • Price Competition and Product Differentiation Based on the Subjective and Social Effect of Consumers’ Environmental Awareness
    International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health Article Price Competition and Product Differentiation Based on the Subjective and Social Effect of Consumers’ Environmental Awareness Dayi He *,† and Ximing Deng † School of Economics & Management, China University of Geosciences, Beijing 100083, China; [email protected] * Correspondence: [email protected] † These authors contributed equally to this work. Received: 4 December 2019; Accepted: 19 January 2020; Published: 22 January 2020 Abstract: Consumer environmental awareness (CEA) can affect green consumption decisions in different and confusing ways. In order to explain the reasons for these divergences, this study divides CEA into two main components: the subjective effect and the social effect. Then, we integrate the two effects into the classic Hotelling model to study the influence of CEA’s subjective effect and social effect on price competition and product differentiation strategy. It was found that the subjective and social effects of CEA have opposite impacts on price competition and product differentiation strategies. The subjective effect of CEA increases the price and profit level of enterprises, and enlarges the difference in the environmental friendliness of products. Meanwhile, the social effect of CEA reduces the enterprises’ price and profit level, and narrows the difference in the environmental quality of products. Therefore, we suggest that it is necessary for producers of green products to distinguish between these two effects. Numerical examples
    [Show full text]
  • Product Differentiation, Oligopoly, and Resource Allocation
    Product Differentiation, Oligopoly, and Resource Allocation Bruno Pellegrino University of California Los Angeles Job Market Paper Please click here for the most recent version November 2, 2019 Abstract Industry concentration and profit rates have increased significantly in the United States over the past two decades. There is growing concern that oligopolies are coming to dominate the American economy. I investigate the welfare implications of the consolidation in U.S. industries, introducing a general equilibrium model with oligopolistic competition, differentiated products, and hedonic demand. I take the model to the data for every year between 1997 and 2017, using adatasetofbilateralmeasuresofproductsimilaritythatcoversallpubliclytradedfirmsinthe United States. The model yields a new metric of concentration—based on network centrality— that varies by firm. This measure strongly predicts markups, even after narrow industry controls are applied. I estimate that oligopolistic behavior causes a deadweight loss of about 13% of the surplus produced by publicly traded corporations. This loss has increased by over one-third since 1997, as has the share of surplus that accrues to producers. I also show that these trends can be accounted for by the secular decline of IPOs and the dramatic rise in the number of takeovers of venture-capital-backed startups. My findings provide empirical support for the hypothesis that increased consolidation in U.S. industries, particularly in innovative sectors, has resulted in sizable welfare losses to the consumer. JEL Codes:D2,D4,D6,E2,L1,O4 Keywords: Competition, Concentration, Entrepreneurship, IPO, Market Power, Mergers, Mis- allocation, Monopoly, Networks, Oligopoly, Startups, Text Analysis, Venture Capital, Welfare I gratefully acknowledge financial support from the Price Center for Entrepreneurship at UCLA Anderson.
    [Show full text]
  • Product Differentiation: a Tool of Competitive Advantage and Optimal Organizational Performance (A Study of Unilever Nigeria Plc)
    European Scientific Journal December 2013 edition vol.9, No.34 ISSN: 1857 – 7881 (Print) e - ISSN 1857- 7431 PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION: A TOOL OF COMPETITIVE ADVANTAGE AND OPTIMAL ORGANIZATIONAL PERFORMANCE (A STUDY OF UNILEVER NIGERIA PLC) Joy I. Dirisu Dr. Oluwole Iyiola Dr. O. S. Ibidunni Department of Business Management, Covenant University, Ota, Nigeria Abstract In recent years the concept of competitive advantage has taken centre stage in discussions of business strategy; that is why, one of the major challenges organizations face today is how to have a competitive advantage. In most cases a stand out product will do the job, since products are perceived as both highly relevant and meaningfully, the ability for any one product to standout in a competitive category will guarantee the success of such organization. While there are numerous ways to differentiate brands, identifying meaningful product-driven differentiators can be especially fruitful in gaining and sustaining a competitive advantage. Differentiation is when a firm or brand outperforms rival brands in the provision of a feature(s) such that it faces reduced sensitivity for other features (Sharp & Dawes, 2001). Even in industrial economics, a discipline where there is more of a tradition of providing formal statements of theoretical concepts, two eminent industrial economists felt obligated to write an article for the Journal of Industrial Economics titled "What is Product Differentiation, Really?" (Caves and Williamson, 1985). Keywords: Product differentiation, competitive advantage, organizational performance Introduction Business strategy development is concerned with matching customers requirements (needs, wants, desires, preferences, buying patterns) with the capabilities of the organization, based on the skills and resources available to the business organization, leading to the issue of core competence (Holmes and Hooper, 2000).
    [Show full text]
  • Demand and Supply of Differentiated Products
    Demand and supply of differentiated products Paul Schrimpf Demand and supply of differentiated products Paul Schrimpf UBC Economics 567 January 28, 2021 Demand and supply of differentiated products 1 Introduction Paul Schrimpf Introduction 2 Demand in product space Demand in product space Demand in 3 Demand in characteristic space characteristic space Early work Early work Model Model Model Estimation and Model identification Aggregate product Estimation and identification data Estimation steps Aggregate product data Pricing equation Estimation steps Micro data Pricing equation References Micro data References 4 References Demand and supply of differentiated products References Paul Schrimpf Introduction Demand in product space Demand in • Reviews: characteristic space • Ackerberg et al. (2007) section 1 (these slides use their Early work notation) Model Model • Aguirregabiria (2019) chapter 2 Estimation and identification • Reiss and Wolak (2007) sections 1-7, especially 7 Aggregate product data • Classic papers: Estimation steps Pricing equation • Berry (1994) Micro data • References Berry, Levinsohn, and Pakes (1995) References Demand and supply of differentiated products Paul Schrimpf Introduction Demand in product space Demand in Section 1 characteristic space Early work Model Model Introduction Estimation and identification Aggregate product data Estimation steps Pricing equation Micro data References References Demand and supply of differentiated products Introduction Paul Schrimpf Introduction Demand in product space • Typical
    [Show full text]
  • Econ 712: Empirical Industrial Organization
    Fall 2018 Aviv Nevo 617 PCPSE [email protected] Econ 712: Empirical Industrial Organization The course provides a graduate-level introduction to the topics and methods of Empirical Industrial Organization (IO). It is designed to provide a broad introduction to topics and industries that current researchers are studying as well as to expose students to a wide variety of techniques. It will start the process of preparing economics Ph.D. students to conduct thesis research in the area, and may also be of interest to doctoral students in other fields. Lectures: Tuesday/Thursday 1:30-3:00, 101 PCPSE Office Hours: By appointment TA: Joao Granja de Almeida ([email protected]) Textbooks: There is no textbook for this course. For coverage of theoretical principles (that I will rely on, but not cover in any detail) see: J. Tirole, The Theory of Industrial Organization, MIT, 1988. (Tirole). For a broader coverage of empirical and public policy issues, you should also read: D. Carlton and J. Perloff, Modern Industrial Organization, 4th ed., Pearson, 2005. K. Viscusi, J. Vernon and J. Harrington, Economics of Regulation and Antitrust, 4th ed., MIT, 2005. You also might want to read several of the surveys in: R. Schmalensee and R. Willig, eds., Handbook of Industrial Organization, Volumes 1 and 2 North-Holland, 1989. (HIO). M. Armstrong and R. Poter, eds., Handbook of Industrial Organization, Volume 3, North- Holland, 2007. The two chapters from the Handbook of Econometrics, in the first section below, are probably the closest thing to a textbook for the material I will cover.
    [Show full text]
  • Product Differentiation: a Tool of Competitive Advantage and Optimal Organizational Performance (A Study of Unilever Nigeria Plc)
    CORE Metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk Provided by European Scientific Journal (European Scientific Institute) European Scientific Journal December 2013 edition vol.9, No.34 ISSN: 1857 – 7881 (Print) e - ISSN 1857- 7431 PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION: A TOOL OF COMPETITIVE ADVANTAGE AND OPTIMAL ORGANIZATIONAL PERFORMANCE (A STUDY OF UNILEVER NIGERIA PLC) Joy I. Dirisu Dr. Oluwole Iyiola Dr. O. S. Ibidunni Department of Business Management, Covenant University, Ota, Nigeria Abstract In recent years the concept of competitive advantage has taken centre stage in discussions of business strategy; that is why, one of the major challenges organizations face today is how to have a competitive advantage. In most cases a stand out product will do the job, since products are perceived as both highly relevant and meaningfully, the ability for any one product to standout in a competitive category will guarantee the success of such organization. While there are numerous ways to differentiate brands, identifying meaningful product-driven differentiators can be especially fruitful in gaining and sustaining a competitive advantage. Differentiation is when a firm or brand outperforms rival brands in the provision of a feature(s) such that it faces reduced sensitivity for other features (Sharp & Dawes, 2001). Even in industrial economics, a discipline where there is more of a tradition of providing formal statements of theoretical concepts, two eminent industrial economists felt obligated to write an article for the Journal of Industrial Economics titled "What is Product Differentiation, Really?" (Caves and Williamson, 1985). Keywords: Product differentiation, competitive advantage, organizational performance Introduction Business strategy development is concerned with matching customers requirements (needs, wants, desires, preferences, buying patterns) with the capabilities of the organization, based on the skills and resources available to the business organization, leading to the issue of core competence (Holmes and Hooper, 2000).
    [Show full text]
  • Monopolistic Competition and Product Differentiation 16-3
    Monopolistic Competition and Product Differentiation 1. The three conditions for monopolistic competition are (1) a large number of 16 producers, (2) differentiated products, and (3) free entry and exit. a. There are many bands that play at weddings, parties, and so on. There are no sig- nificant barriers to entry or exit. And products are differentiated by quality (for instance, some bands have better musicians or better electronic equipment) or by style (for instance, different bands play different types of music). All three condi- tions for monopolistic competition are fulfilled. b. The industry for individual-serving juice boxes is dominated by a few very large firms (for example, Minute Maid, Welch’s, and Kool Aid), and there are signifi- cant barriers to entry, in part because of the large costs (for example, advertising) involved in gaining any market share of the national market. Products are, how- ever, differentiated—if perhaps only in the minds of consumers. Because of the small number of competitors, the industry is closer to oligopoly. c. There is a large number of dry cleaners, and each produces a product differentiat- ed by location: customers are likely to prefer to use the dry cleaner closest to their home or workplace. Finally, there are no significant barriers to entry. This is a chapter monopolistically competitive market. d. There is a large number of soybean farmers, and there is free entry and exit in this industry. However, soybeans are not differentiated from each other—they are a standardized product. No individual soybean farmer has market power. This industry is therefore a perfectly competitive industry.
    [Show full text]
  • Impact of Product Differentiation, Marketing Investments and Brand Equity On
    1 Impact of Product Differentiation, Marketing Investments and Brand Equity on Pricing Strategies: A Brand Level Investigation 1. Introduction Most companies use marketing-performance measures such as brand loyalty, market share, price premium and customer lifetime value, to determine their success or failure. Pricing is one of the most important elements of marketing mix and pricing strategies play an important role in a company’s marketing strategy (Kotler and Keller 2012; Tirole 1988). Hence, it is not surprising to see a large body of research on pricing in both marketing and finance areas on pricing; however the application of this type of research to both theory and practice has not been as prevalent as other marketing variables (Duke 1994; Christopher 2000). One of the main reasons for this gap between theory and practice could be the difference in the orientations of marketing and finance researchers, with researchers in finance focusing on the impact of firm strategies and stakeholders’ short-/long-term expectations and marketing researchers on customer reactions and / or impact of branding on marketing strategies and decisions (Madden et al. 2006). A second reason could be that finance researchers typically use firm-level data from equity markets and the company’s financial statements, while marketing researchers generally use surveys or an experimental-research approach (Madden et al. 2006). As a result, it is not usual for marketing researchers to deal with huge databases that can explain company, consumer or product (brand) patterns and behavior, nor is it usual for them to conceptualize their research using the findings from either industrial organizations (or any approach from a broad microeconomic theory) or other fields of economic science (such as finance, etc.).
    [Show full text]
  • COMPETITIVE OUTCOMES in PRODUCT-DIFFERENTIATED OLIGOPOLY Michael J
    COMPETITIVE OUTCOMES IN PRODUCT-DIFFERENTIATED OLIGOPOLY Michael J. Mazzeo* Abstract—This paper analyzes the effect of market concentration and structure. Firms anticipate the competitive effects of market product differentiation on the observed outcomes of competition among oligopolists. The empirical framework is designed to examine whether structure when making their entry and product-type deci- competition is less intense in markets with equal levels of concentration sions. The market structure variables used to explain the but more differentiation among the products offered. A two-stage estima- observed outcomes, therefore, derive from the related entry tion procedure is proposed to address the endogeneity problem inherent in comparing outcomes across different market structures. I estimate the and product choice stage of the game. As a result, it is competitive effects using data from a cross section of oligopoly motel crucial to allow for correlation between unobserved factors markets located along U.S. interstate highways. The results indicate that that affect the entry and product-type decisions of firms and firms benefit substantially by offering differentiated products. The pres- ence of any market competitor drives down prices, but the effect is much unobservables in the outcome regressions. To correct for the smaller when the competitor is a different product type. Differentiation is potential bias caused by this correlation, an econometric optimal product choice behavior because the resulting competition among model of equilibrium market structure is employed as a firms is less tough when their products are differentiated. selection equation in a two-step estimation procedure. The second-step outcome regressions are modified to reflect the I.
    [Show full text]