Demand and Supply of Differentiated Products

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Demand and Supply of Differentiated Products Demand and supply of differentiated products Paul Schrimpf Demand and supply of differentiated products Paul Schrimpf UBC Economics 567 January 28, 2021 Demand and supply of differentiated products 1 Introduction Paul Schrimpf Introduction 2 Demand in product space Demand in product space Demand in 3 Demand in characteristic space characteristic space Early work Early work Model Model Model Estimation and Model identification Aggregate product Estimation and identification data Estimation steps Aggregate product data Pricing equation Estimation steps Micro data Pricing equation References Micro data References 4 References Demand and supply of differentiated products References Paul Schrimpf Introduction Demand in product space Demand in • Reviews: characteristic space • Ackerberg et al. (2007) section 1 (these slides use their Early work notation) Model Model • Aguirregabiria (2019) chapter 2 Estimation and identification • Reiss and Wolak (2007) sections 1-7, especially 7 Aggregate product data • Classic papers: Estimation steps Pricing equation • Berry (1994) Micro data • References Berry, Levinsohn, and Pakes (1995) References Demand and supply of differentiated products Paul Schrimpf Introduction Demand in product space Demand in Section 1 characteristic space Early work Model Model Introduction Estimation and identification Aggregate product data Estimation steps Pricing equation Micro data References References Demand and supply of differentiated products Introduction Paul Schrimpf Introduction Demand in product space • Typical market for consumer goods has many Demand in characteristic differentiated, but similar products, e.g. space Early work • Cars Model • Model Cereal Estimation and identification • Differentiated products are a source of market power Aggregate product data Estimation steps • Having many products can result in many parameters Pricing equation Micro data creating estimation difficulties and requiring References departures from textbook demand and supply models References Demand and supply of differentiated products Motivation Paul Schrimpf Introduction Demand in product space • Counterfactuals that do not change production Demand in characteristic technology space Early work • Mergers Model • Model Tax changes Estimation and identification • Effects of new goods Aggregate product data Estimation steps • Cost-of-living indices Pricing equation Micro data • Product differentiation and market power References • Cross-price elasticities References Demand and supply of differentiated products Paul Schrimpf Introduction Demand in product space Demand in Section 2 characteristic space Early work Model Demand in product space Model Estimation and identification Aggregate product data Estimation steps Pricing equation Micro data References References Demand and supply of differentiated products Demand in product space 1 Paul Schrimpf • J products, each treated as separate good • Introduction Classical demand, Demand in product space q1 =D1(p1, ..., pJ, z1, η1; β1) Demand in . characteristic . = . space Early work Model qJ =DJ(p1, ..., pJ, zJ, ηJ; βJ), Model Estimation and identification Aggregate product data Estimation steps and supply (firms’ first-order conditions for prices): Pricing equation Micro data p =g (q , ..., q , w , ν ; θ ) References 1 1 1 J 1 1 1 . References . = . d pJ =gJ(q1, ..., qJ, wJ, νJ; θJ), where Demand and supply of differentiated products Demand in product space 2 Paul Schrimpf Introduction • Demand in pj = price product space • qj = quantity Demand in • z = observed demand shifter characteristic j space • ηj = unobserved demand shock Early work Model • βj = demand parameters Model • Estimation and wj = observed supply shifter identification • Aggregate product νj = unobserved supply shock data • Estimation steps θj = supply parameters Pricing equation Micro data • Dj typically parametrically specified, e.g. References References ln qj = βj0 + βj1p1 + ··· + βjJpJ + βjy ln y + Z1γ + νj Demand and supply of differentiated products Demand in product space Paul Schrimpf • Use reduced form to find instruments Introduction q q1 =Π1 (Z, W, ν, η; β, θ) Demand in . product space . =. Demand in q characteristic q =Π (Z, W, ν, η; β, θ) space J J Early work p Model p1 =Π1 (Z, W, ν, η; β, θ) Model Estimation and . identification . =. Aggregate product data p Estimation steps pJ =ΠJ (Z, W, ν, η; β, θ) Pricing equation Micro data References • Cost shifters of product j excluded from demand and References supply of product k, but in reduced form • Cost data often not available • If available, unlikely to be product specific • Attributes of other products • Hausman (1996) uses prices of other products • Hard to justify, especially with prices Demand and supply of differentiated products Demand in product space 1 Paul Schrimpf • Advantages of product space: Introduction • Demand in Flexible substitution patterns product space • Does not require detailed product attribute data Demand in characteristic • Problems with product space: space Early work 1 Representative agent and aggregation issues Model • With heterogeneous preferences, aggregate market Model Estimation and demand need not meet restrictions on individual identification Aggregate product demand derived from economic theory data Estimation steps • Cannot use restrictions easily to improve estimates Pricing equation • Can use simulation to aggregate (Pakes, 1986) Micro data 2 References 2 Too many parameters, O(J ) References • Can limit by restricting cross-price elasticities, e.g. Pinkse, Slade, and Brett (2002) 3 Too many instruments needed, J 4 Cannot analyze new goods Demand and supply of differentiated products Paul Schrimpf Introduction Demand in product space Demand in Section 3 characteristic space Early work Model Model Demand in characteristic space Estimation and identification Aggregate product data Estimation steps Pricing equation Micro data References References Demand and supply of differentiated products Demand in characteristic space Paul Schrimpf Introduction Demand in • Motivation: product space • Why do firms differentiate products? Demand in • characteristic Because consumers have heterogeneous tastes for space product characteristics Early work Model • E.g. cars: tastes for size, safety, fuel efficiency, etc Model Estimation and • identification Main idea: model consumer preferences for Aggregate product data characteristics and treat products as bundles of Estimation steps Pricing equation characteristics Micro data • Early work: Lancaster (1971), McFadden (1973) References References • Key extension to early work: Berry, Levinsohn, and Pakes (1995) Demand and supply of differentiated products Early work in characteristic Paul Schrimpf space • Introduction Consumer chooses one or none of J products Demand in • Utility of consumer i from product j product space Demand in uij = xjβ + εij characteristic space with εij iid across i and j (usually Type I extreme value) Early work Model • Implies aggregate demand (for logit) Model Estimation and identification exp(xjβ) Aggregate product qj = PJ data 1 + exp(x β) Estimation steps k=1 k Pricing equation Micro data • Problem: restrictive substitution “independence of References irrelevant alternatives” References • Two goods with the same shares have the same cross price elasticities with any third good (think about a luxury and bargain good with equal shares) • Goods with same shares should have same markups • Solution: add heterogeneity in β and/or allow correlation across j in εij Demand and supply of differentiated products Model 1 Paul Schrimpf Introduction Demand in product space • Consumers i, goods j, markets t Demand in • characteristic Utility: (include good 0 = buy nothing) space Early work unobserved Model z}|{ unobserved Model z}|{ Estimation and uijt = U( ˜xjt , ξjt , zit , νit , pjt ; θ) identification |{z} Aggregate product |{z} |{z} data observed observed observed Estimation steps Pricing equation Micro data RK RR RL References • xjt = (˜xjt, pjt)) ∈ , zit ∈ , νit ∈ References • Choose j if uijt > uikt ∀k ̸= j Demand and supply of differentiated products Model 1 Paul Schrimpf • Usually U(·) linear: Introduction 1×K K×1 1×1 Demand in z}|{ z }| { z}|{ product space u = x θ + ξ +ε ijt jt |{z}it jt ijt Demand in o u characteristic =θ¯+θ zit+θ νit space Early work Model Model Estimation and identification for j = 1...J and normalize ui0t = 0 Aggregate product data • ε Estimation steps Assume ijt i.i.d. double exponential Pricing equation Micro data • Assume νit ∼ fν(·; θ), e.g. independent normal References • Write as product specific + observed interactions + References unobserved interactions u = δ +x θo z + x θu ν + ε ijt |{z}j jt |{z} it jt |{z} it ijt K×R K×L =xjtθ¯+ξjt Demand and supply of differentiated products Endogeneity Paul Schrimpf Introduction Demand in product space • Demand in Usually assume E[νit|xjt, zit] = 0 and E[εijt|xjt, zit] = 0 characteristic • space Not interested in counterfactuals with respect to Early work changes in zit, so can treat as residual, i.e. Model Model Estimation and identification νit = θit − E[θit|zit] Aggregate product data Estimation steps • Market average νit or εijt plausibly correlated with pjt or Pricing equation Micro data other product characteristics, but this correlation References absorbed into ξjt and/or market fixed effects References Demand and supply of differentiated products Endogeneity Paul Schrimpf Introduction Demand in product space Demand in • Problem is ξjt characteristic space • Prices and
Recommended publications
  • Product Differentiation
    Product differentiation Industrial Organization Bernard Caillaud Master APE - Paris School of Economics September 22, 2016 Bernard Caillaud Product differentiation Motivation The Bertrand paradox relies on the fact buyers choose the cheap- est firm, even for very small price differences. In practice, some buyers may continue to buy from the most expensive firms because they have an intrinsic preference for the product sold by that firm: Notion of differentiation. Indeed, assuming an homogeneous product is not realistic: rarely exist two identical goods in this sense For objective reasons: products differ in their physical char- acteristics, in their design, ... For subjective reasons: even when physical differences are hard to see for consumers, branding may well make two prod- ucts appear differently in the consumers' eyes Bernard Caillaud Product differentiation Motivation Differentiation among products is above all a property of con- sumers' preferences: Taste for diversity Heterogeneity of consumers' taste But it has major consequences in terms of imperfectly competi- tive behavior: so, the analysis of differentiation allows for a richer discussion and comparison of price competition models vs quan- tity competition models. Also related to the practical question (for competition authori- ties) of market definition: set of goods highly substitutable among themselves and poorly substitutable with goods outside this set Bernard Caillaud Product differentiation Motivation Firms have in general an incentive to affect the degree of differ- entiation of their products compared to rivals'. Hence, differen- tiation is related to other aspects of firms’ strategies. Choice of products: firms choose how to differentiate from rivals, this impacts the type of products that they choose to offer and the diversity of products that consumers face.
    [Show full text]
  • Product Differentiation and Economic Progress
    THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF AUSTRIAN ECONOMICS 12, NO. 1 (2009): 17–35 PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION AND ECONOMIC PROGRESS RANDALL G. HOLCOMBE ABSTRACT: In neoclassical theory, product differentiation provides consumers with a variety of different products within a particular industry, rather than a homogeneous product that characterizes purely competitive markets. The welfare-enhancing benefit of product differentiation is the greater variety of products available to consumers, which comes at the cost of a higher average total cost of production. In reality, firms do not differentiate their products to make them different, or to give consumers variety, but to make them better, so consumers would rather buy that firm’s product rather than the product of a competitor. When product differentiation is seen as a strategy to improve products rather than just to make them different, product differentiation emerges as the engine of economic progress. In contrast to the neoclassical framework, where product differentiation imposes a cost on the economy in exchange for more product variety, in real- ity product differentiation lowers costs, creates better products for consumers, and generates economic progress. n the neoclassical theory of the firm, product differentiation enhances consumer welfare by offering consumers greater variety, Ibut that benefit is offset by the higher average cost of production for monopolistically competitive firms. In the neoclassical framework, the only benefit of product differentiation is the greater variety of prod- ucts available, but the reason firms differentiate their products is not just to make them different from the products of other firms, but to make them better. By improving product quality and bringing new Randall G.
    [Show full text]
  • The Theory of Monopolistic Competition, Marketing's Intellectual History, and the Product Differentiation Versus Market Segmen
    Journal of Macromarketing 31(1) 73-84 ª The Author(s) 2011 The Theory of Monopolistic Competition, Reprints and permission: sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav Marketing’s Intellectual History, and the DOI: 10.1177/0276146710382119 Product Differentiation Versus Market http://jmk.sagepub.com Segmentation Controversy Shelby D. Hunt1 Abstract Edward Chamberlin’s theory of monopolistic competition influenced greatly the development of marketing theory and thought in the 1930s to the 1960s. Indeed, marketers held the theory in such high regard that the American Marketing Association awarded Chamberlin the Paul D. Converse Award in 1953, which at the time was the AMA’s highest honor. However, the contemporary marketing literature virtually ignores Chamberlin’s theory. The author argues that the theory of monopolistic competition deserves reexamining on two grounds. First, marketing scholars should know their discipline’s intellectual history, to which Chamberlin’s theory played a significant role in developing. Second, understanding the theory of monopolistic competition can inform contemporary marketing thought. Although our analysis will point out several contributions of the theory, one in partic- ular is argued in detail: the theory of monopolistic competition can contribute to a better understanding of the ‘‘product differ- entiation versus market segmentation’’ controversy in marketing strategy. Keywords Chamberlin, marketing strategy, product differentiation, market segmentation As research specialization has increased, ... knowledge outside Despite the theory’s defeat in economics, the theory of of a person’s specialty may first be viewed as noninstrumental, monopolistic competition (hereafter, TMC) influenced greatly then as nonessential, then as nonimportant, and finally as the development of marketing theory and thought in the 1930s nonexistent.
    [Show full text]
  • Price Competition and Product Differentiation Based on the Subjective and Social Effect of Consumers’ Environmental Awareness
    International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health Article Price Competition and Product Differentiation Based on the Subjective and Social Effect of Consumers’ Environmental Awareness Dayi He *,† and Ximing Deng † School of Economics & Management, China University of Geosciences, Beijing 100083, China; [email protected] * Correspondence: [email protected] † These authors contributed equally to this work. Received: 4 December 2019; Accepted: 19 January 2020; Published: 22 January 2020 Abstract: Consumer environmental awareness (CEA) can affect green consumption decisions in different and confusing ways. In order to explain the reasons for these divergences, this study divides CEA into two main components: the subjective effect and the social effect. Then, we integrate the two effects into the classic Hotelling model to study the influence of CEA’s subjective effect and social effect on price competition and product differentiation strategy. It was found that the subjective and social effects of CEA have opposite impacts on price competition and product differentiation strategies. The subjective effect of CEA increases the price and profit level of enterprises, and enlarges the difference in the environmental friendliness of products. Meanwhile, the social effect of CEA reduces the enterprises’ price and profit level, and narrows the difference in the environmental quality of products. Therefore, we suggest that it is necessary for producers of green products to distinguish between these two effects. Numerical examples
    [Show full text]
  • Product Differentiation, Oligopoly, and Resource Allocation
    Product Differentiation, Oligopoly, and Resource Allocation Bruno Pellegrino University of California Los Angeles Job Market Paper Please click here for the most recent version November 2, 2019 Abstract Industry concentration and profit rates have increased significantly in the United States over the past two decades. There is growing concern that oligopolies are coming to dominate the American economy. I investigate the welfare implications of the consolidation in U.S. industries, introducing a general equilibrium model with oligopolistic competition, differentiated products, and hedonic demand. I take the model to the data for every year between 1997 and 2017, using adatasetofbilateralmeasuresofproductsimilaritythatcoversallpubliclytradedfirmsinthe United States. The model yields a new metric of concentration—based on network centrality— that varies by firm. This measure strongly predicts markups, even after narrow industry controls are applied. I estimate that oligopolistic behavior causes a deadweight loss of about 13% of the surplus produced by publicly traded corporations. This loss has increased by over one-third since 1997, as has the share of surplus that accrues to producers. I also show that these trends can be accounted for by the secular decline of IPOs and the dramatic rise in the number of takeovers of venture-capital-backed startups. My findings provide empirical support for the hypothesis that increased consolidation in U.S. industries, particularly in innovative sectors, has resulted in sizable welfare losses to the consumer. JEL Codes:D2,D4,D6,E2,L1,O4 Keywords: Competition, Concentration, Entrepreneurship, IPO, Market Power, Mergers, Mis- allocation, Monopoly, Networks, Oligopoly, Startups, Text Analysis, Venture Capital, Welfare I gratefully acknowledge financial support from the Price Center for Entrepreneurship at UCLA Anderson.
    [Show full text]
  • Product Differentiation: a Tool of Competitive Advantage and Optimal Organizational Performance (A Study of Unilever Nigeria Plc)
    European Scientific Journal December 2013 edition vol.9, No.34 ISSN: 1857 – 7881 (Print) e - ISSN 1857- 7431 PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION: A TOOL OF COMPETITIVE ADVANTAGE AND OPTIMAL ORGANIZATIONAL PERFORMANCE (A STUDY OF UNILEVER NIGERIA PLC) Joy I. Dirisu Dr. Oluwole Iyiola Dr. O. S. Ibidunni Department of Business Management, Covenant University, Ota, Nigeria Abstract In recent years the concept of competitive advantage has taken centre stage in discussions of business strategy; that is why, one of the major challenges organizations face today is how to have a competitive advantage. In most cases a stand out product will do the job, since products are perceived as both highly relevant and meaningfully, the ability for any one product to standout in a competitive category will guarantee the success of such organization. While there are numerous ways to differentiate brands, identifying meaningful product-driven differentiators can be especially fruitful in gaining and sustaining a competitive advantage. Differentiation is when a firm or brand outperforms rival brands in the provision of a feature(s) such that it faces reduced sensitivity for other features (Sharp & Dawes, 2001). Even in industrial economics, a discipline where there is more of a tradition of providing formal statements of theoretical concepts, two eminent industrial economists felt obligated to write an article for the Journal of Industrial Economics titled "What is Product Differentiation, Really?" (Caves and Williamson, 1985). Keywords: Product differentiation, competitive advantage, organizational performance Introduction Business strategy development is concerned with matching customers requirements (needs, wants, desires, preferences, buying patterns) with the capabilities of the organization, based on the skills and resources available to the business organization, leading to the issue of core competence (Holmes and Hooper, 2000).
    [Show full text]
  • Econ 712: Empirical Industrial Organization
    Fall 2018 Aviv Nevo 617 PCPSE [email protected] Econ 712: Empirical Industrial Organization The course provides a graduate-level introduction to the topics and methods of Empirical Industrial Organization (IO). It is designed to provide a broad introduction to topics and industries that current researchers are studying as well as to expose students to a wide variety of techniques. It will start the process of preparing economics Ph.D. students to conduct thesis research in the area, and may also be of interest to doctoral students in other fields. Lectures: Tuesday/Thursday 1:30-3:00, 101 PCPSE Office Hours: By appointment TA: Joao Granja de Almeida ([email protected]) Textbooks: There is no textbook for this course. For coverage of theoretical principles (that I will rely on, but not cover in any detail) see: J. Tirole, The Theory of Industrial Organization, MIT, 1988. (Tirole). For a broader coverage of empirical and public policy issues, you should also read: D. Carlton and J. Perloff, Modern Industrial Organization, 4th ed., Pearson, 2005. K. Viscusi, J. Vernon and J. Harrington, Economics of Regulation and Antitrust, 4th ed., MIT, 2005. You also might want to read several of the surveys in: R. Schmalensee and R. Willig, eds., Handbook of Industrial Organization, Volumes 1 and 2 North-Holland, 1989. (HIO). M. Armstrong and R. Poter, eds., Handbook of Industrial Organization, Volume 3, North- Holland, 2007. The two chapters from the Handbook of Econometrics, in the first section below, are probably the closest thing to a textbook for the material I will cover.
    [Show full text]
  • Product Differentiation: a Tool of Competitive Advantage and Optimal Organizational Performance (A Study of Unilever Nigeria Plc)
    CORE Metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk Provided by European Scientific Journal (European Scientific Institute) European Scientific Journal December 2013 edition vol.9, No.34 ISSN: 1857 – 7881 (Print) e - ISSN 1857- 7431 PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION: A TOOL OF COMPETITIVE ADVANTAGE AND OPTIMAL ORGANIZATIONAL PERFORMANCE (A STUDY OF UNILEVER NIGERIA PLC) Joy I. Dirisu Dr. Oluwole Iyiola Dr. O. S. Ibidunni Department of Business Management, Covenant University, Ota, Nigeria Abstract In recent years the concept of competitive advantage has taken centre stage in discussions of business strategy; that is why, one of the major challenges organizations face today is how to have a competitive advantage. In most cases a stand out product will do the job, since products are perceived as both highly relevant and meaningfully, the ability for any one product to standout in a competitive category will guarantee the success of such organization. While there are numerous ways to differentiate brands, identifying meaningful product-driven differentiators can be especially fruitful in gaining and sustaining a competitive advantage. Differentiation is when a firm or brand outperforms rival brands in the provision of a feature(s) such that it faces reduced sensitivity for other features (Sharp & Dawes, 2001). Even in industrial economics, a discipline where there is more of a tradition of providing formal statements of theoretical concepts, two eminent industrial economists felt obligated to write an article for the Journal of Industrial Economics titled "What is Product Differentiation, Really?" (Caves and Williamson, 1985). Keywords: Product differentiation, competitive advantage, organizational performance Introduction Business strategy development is concerned with matching customers requirements (needs, wants, desires, preferences, buying patterns) with the capabilities of the organization, based on the skills and resources available to the business organization, leading to the issue of core competence (Holmes and Hooper, 2000).
    [Show full text]
  • Monopolistic Competition and Product Differentiation 16-3
    Monopolistic Competition and Product Differentiation 1. The three conditions for monopolistic competition are (1) a large number of 16 producers, (2) differentiated products, and (3) free entry and exit. a. There are many bands that play at weddings, parties, and so on. There are no sig- nificant barriers to entry or exit. And products are differentiated by quality (for instance, some bands have better musicians or better electronic equipment) or by style (for instance, different bands play different types of music). All three condi- tions for monopolistic competition are fulfilled. b. The industry for individual-serving juice boxes is dominated by a few very large firms (for example, Minute Maid, Welch’s, and Kool Aid), and there are signifi- cant barriers to entry, in part because of the large costs (for example, advertising) involved in gaining any market share of the national market. Products are, how- ever, differentiated—if perhaps only in the minds of consumers. Because of the small number of competitors, the industry is closer to oligopoly. c. There is a large number of dry cleaners, and each produces a product differentiat- ed by location: customers are likely to prefer to use the dry cleaner closest to their home or workplace. Finally, there are no significant barriers to entry. This is a chapter monopolistically competitive market. d. There is a large number of soybean farmers, and there is free entry and exit in this industry. However, soybeans are not differentiated from each other—they are a standardized product. No individual soybean farmer has market power. This industry is therefore a perfectly competitive industry.
    [Show full text]
  • Market Segmentation, Product Differentiation, and Marketing Strategy Author(S): Peter R
    Market Segmentation, Product Differentiation, and Marketing Strategy Author(s): Peter R. Dickson and James L. Ginter Source: Journal of Marketing, Vol. 51, No. 2 (Apr., 1987), pp. 1-10 Published by: American Marketing Association Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1251125 Accessed: 05-10-2016 19:00 UTC JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://about.jstor.org/terms American Marketing Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of Marketing This content downloaded from 143.107.252.158 on Wed, 05 Oct 2016 19:00:47 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms Peter R. Dickson & James L. Ginter Market Segmentation, Product Differentiation, and Marketing Strategy Despite the pervasive use of the terms "market segmentation" and "product differentiation," there has been and continues to be considerable misunderstanding about their meaning and use. The authors attempt to lessen the confusion by the use of traditional and contemporary economic theory and product preference maps. M ARKETS have been segmented and products and Rosenberg 1981; Neidell 1983; Pride and Ferrell and services differentiated for as long as sup- 1985; Stanton 1981) describe product differentiation pliers have differed in their methods of competing for as an alternative to market segmentation and 11 of the trade.
    [Show full text]
  • Impact of Product Differentiation, Marketing Investments and Brand Equity On
    1 Impact of Product Differentiation, Marketing Investments and Brand Equity on Pricing Strategies: A Brand Level Investigation 1. Introduction Most companies use marketing-performance measures such as brand loyalty, market share, price premium and customer lifetime value, to determine their success or failure. Pricing is one of the most important elements of marketing mix and pricing strategies play an important role in a company’s marketing strategy (Kotler and Keller 2012; Tirole 1988). Hence, it is not surprising to see a large body of research on pricing in both marketing and finance areas on pricing; however the application of this type of research to both theory and practice has not been as prevalent as other marketing variables (Duke 1994; Christopher 2000). One of the main reasons for this gap between theory and practice could be the difference in the orientations of marketing and finance researchers, with researchers in finance focusing on the impact of firm strategies and stakeholders’ short-/long-term expectations and marketing researchers on customer reactions and / or impact of branding on marketing strategies and decisions (Madden et al. 2006). A second reason could be that finance researchers typically use firm-level data from equity markets and the company’s financial statements, while marketing researchers generally use surveys or an experimental-research approach (Madden et al. 2006). As a result, it is not usual for marketing researchers to deal with huge databases that can explain company, consumer or product (brand) patterns and behavior, nor is it usual for them to conceptualize their research using the findings from either industrial organizations (or any approach from a broad microeconomic theory) or other fields of economic science (such as finance, etc.).
    [Show full text]
  • COMPETITIVE OUTCOMES in PRODUCT-DIFFERENTIATED OLIGOPOLY Michael J
    COMPETITIVE OUTCOMES IN PRODUCT-DIFFERENTIATED OLIGOPOLY Michael J. Mazzeo* Abstract—This paper analyzes the effect of market concentration and structure. Firms anticipate the competitive effects of market product differentiation on the observed outcomes of competition among oligopolists. The empirical framework is designed to examine whether structure when making their entry and product-type deci- competition is less intense in markets with equal levels of concentration sions. The market structure variables used to explain the but more differentiation among the products offered. A two-stage estima- observed outcomes, therefore, derive from the related entry tion procedure is proposed to address the endogeneity problem inherent in comparing outcomes across different market structures. I estimate the and product choice stage of the game. As a result, it is competitive effects using data from a cross section of oligopoly motel crucial to allow for correlation between unobserved factors markets located along U.S. interstate highways. The results indicate that that affect the entry and product-type decisions of firms and firms benefit substantially by offering differentiated products. The pres- ence of any market competitor drives down prices, but the effect is much unobservables in the outcome regressions. To correct for the smaller when the competitor is a different product type. Differentiation is potential bias caused by this correlation, an econometric optimal product choice behavior because the resulting competition among model of equilibrium market structure is employed as a firms is less tough when their products are differentiated. selection equation in a two-step estimation procedure. The second-step outcome regressions are modified to reflect the I.
    [Show full text]