Draft Lecture 1

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Draft Lecture 1 Leipzig University Faculty of Economics and Business Administration Institute for Economic Policy International Economics Kristoffer J. M. Hansen II. Trade Theory: Mercantilism, Smith and Ricardo 26 Apr 2021 Kristoffer J. M. Hansen, Institute for Economic Policy 1 II. Trade Theory: Mercantilism, Smith and Ricardo 1. Mercantilism 2. Adam Smith and Absolute Advantage 3. David Ricardo and Comparative Advantage 4. Comparative Advantage under Increasing Costs 5. The Heckscher-Ohlin Theory 6. The Alchian-Allen Effect 7. Summary 8. References Pugel, International Economics, pp. 32-66 26 Apr 2021 Kristoffer J. M. Hansen, Institute for Economic Policy 2 Russian and German Exports by Commodity in 2007 120 Agriculture Crude Materials Manufactured Products 100 80 What characteristics of production help to D S U explain patterns of world trade? n o i l 60 l i b 40 20 0 Exports Russia to Germany Exports Germany to Russia Source: UN Comtrade Statistics 2009. 26 Apr 2021 Kristoffer J. M. Hansen, Institute for Economic Policy 3 1. Mercantilism • Mercantilism is not so much an organized body of thought as a collection of ideas and policies used to interfere with international trade. • Especially prominent from the 16th to the 18th century in Europe. • The Montaigne fallacy: in trade, the gain of one person or country can only come at the loss of another person or country. • “No profit can possibly be made but at the expense of another.” • The assumption behind mercantilist policies: a nation’s wealth depends on its stock of precious metals (i.e., money). • Therefore, exports should be encouraged and imports discouraged. 26 Apr 2021 Kristoffer J. M. Hansen, Institute for Economic Policy 4 Mercantilist Practices To encourage exports: • Export subsidies, encourage manufacturing, subsidize national shipping (navigation acts). To discourage imports: • High tariffs on manufactured goods. • Colonies for raw materials (and later: captive markets). Other practices: • Chartered companies: Dutch East India Company, English East India Company. 26 Apr 2021 Kristoffer J. M. Hansen, Institute for Economic Policy 5 Critique of Mercantilism • Opposition to mercantilism was widespread, really took off in late 17th century. • Jean-Baptiste Colbert (1619-1683), minister to Louis XIV of France whose name became synonymous with mercantilism (colbertisme) thought he improved trade (and enriched the king!); in reality, France became impoverished. • Colbert once asked a group of merchants what he could do to help them. The answer was: “laissez faire, laisser passer, le monde va de lui même!” • Roughly translated: get out of our way and let commerce and industry develop freely! 26 Apr 2021 Kristoffer J. M. Hansen, Institute for Economic Policy 6 Critique of Mercantilism • What’s so good about accumulating specie (i.e., precious metals)? As we saw earlier, people keep as much cash as they think good; an “adverse balance of payments” can only endure if people desire to reduce their cash holding and export specie. • Hume’s price-specie flow mechanism: if you import money, i.e., have a “positive” balance of trade, the money supply increases domestically → higher prices. Then the profit from exporting goods evaporates, foreign goods become relatively cheaper and merchants will import more foreign goods, reversing the “positive” balance of trade. • In the end, you’ve simply disturbed the patterns of trade with no gain. 26 Apr 2021 Kristoffer J. M. Hansen, Institute for Economic Policy 7 Critique of Mercantilism • Adam Smith’s Wealth of Nations was a sustained attack on mercantilism. Absolute advantage was the basis of the superiority of trade over autarky: • “It is the maxim of every prudent master of a family, never to attempt to make at home what it will cost… more to make than to buy. The tailor does not attempt to make his own shoes, but buys them from the shoemaker… What is prudence in the conduct of every private family, can scarce be folly in that of a great kingdom. If a foreign country can supply us with a commodity cheaper than we ourselves can make it, better buy it of them with some part of the product of our own industry, employed in a way in which we have some advantage.” 26 Apr 2021 Kristoffer J. M. Hansen, Institute for Economic Policy 8 Implications of Mercantilism Distortions to Factor Allocation • Government imposed monopolies led to corruption and inefficient factor allocation. • Price ceilings (on food) favoured the rise of black markets. • As money in circulation increased relative to the amount of goods, inflationary pressure rose. Distribution Effects • The working population (farmers and workers) were to live at the “margins of subsistence”. • Merchants gained from the enforced monopolies, bans on foreign competition and poverty of workers. • Governments earned high tariffs and payments from merchants. • Almost all mercantilist writers were merchants or government representatives. 26 Apr 2021 Kristoffer J. M. Hansen, Institute for Economic Policy 9 Neo-Mercantilism • In the 20th century, mercantilism came back. The goal is no longer to increase the amount of specie in a country, but to create jobs through protectionism. • Jobs need to be protected from international competition, foreign workers “take” domestic jobs. • No recognition of mutual gains from trade or of comparative advantage. Examples • China is accused of pursuing a mercantilist policy by “flooding” international markets with exports. • West European trade unions oppose labour mobility, East European labourers 26 Apr 2021 Kristoffer J. M. Hansen, Institute for Economic Policy 10 2. Adam Smith and Absolute Advantage Adam Smith (1723 – 1790) • response to mercantilism which prevailed at the time • absolute advantage as determinant of international trade • Smith compared nations to households. • Since every household finds it worthwhile to produce some of its needs and to buy others with products it can sell, the same should apply to nations. Assumptions • two countries and two goods • the hours of constituent labour determine the price/cost of goods. • fixed labour supply in each country • homogeneity of labour • perfect competition 26 Apr 2021 Kristoffer J. M. Hansen, Institute for Economic Policy 11 Absolute Advantage: Numerical Example Absolute advantages: The foreign country (home country) has an absolute advantage in producing food (clothing). Foreign Country Home Country 1 unit of food 2 hours < 2.5 hours 1 unit of clothing 4 hours > 1 hour Relative commodity prices in autarky • Individuals trade equal labour values of food for clothing. • For example the price of 1 unit of clothing in the home country is 0.4 units of food that is 1 hour/2.5 hours. Foreign Country Home Country price of 1 unit of food 0.5 units of clothing 2.5 units of clothing price of 1 unit of clothing 2 units of food 0.4 units of food 26 Apr 2021 Kristoffer J. M. Hansen, Institute for Economic Policy 12 Absolute Advantage: Numerical Example • After opening up to trade, both countries completely focus on their absolute advantages. • The foreign country´s (home country´s) labor completely shifts towards producing food (clothing), which has a higher value when exported abroad. The foreign country (home country) imports clothing (food) which is cheaper abroad. • Assuming that both countries completely specialize in their absolute advantage the international prices must be somewhere in the range: - 0.5 ≤ international price of 1 unit of food ≤ 2.5 and - 2 ≥ international price of 1 unit of clothing ≥ 0.4. • Both countries gain by trade and specialize according to their absolute advantages. The other commodity can be imported at a lower price than before trade. • Both countries gain by reaching a higher utility than in autarky. 26 Apr 2021 Kristoffer J. M. Hansen, Institute for Economic Policy 13 Absolute Advantage: Summary • A country will produce and export those goods in which is has an absolute advantage. • It will import those goods in which it has an absolute disadvantage. • This is in reality a special case of the the principle of comparative advantage! 26 Apr 2021 Kristoffer J. M. Hansen, Institute for Economic Policy 14 3. The Principle of Comparative Advantage Absolute versus comparative advantage • The theory of absolute advantage showed that countries gain by free trade if each country has an absolute advantage. • David Ricardo demonstrated in the early 19th century that trade is beneficial whether or not countries have any absolute advantage. Comparative advantage and gains from trade • The Ricardian setting is based on the same assumptions as the theory of absolute advantage. • Here, the opportunity cost of producing another unit of one commodity is assumed to be constant. • A nation gains from trade by exporting goods in which it has its greatest comparative (relative) advantage in productivity and importing those in which it has the least comparative advantage. • Even if one nation has an absolute advantage at producing everything, both countries gain by trading with each other. 26 Apr 2021 Kristoffer J. M. Hansen, Institute for Economic Policy 15 The Higher Productivity under Division of Labour • Recall the example of two persons from the introductory lecture • Let us say that person A is more productive than B in the production of both p and q. For the production of one unit of p A needs 3 hours compared to B’s 5 and for q 2 hours compared to B’s 4. • If each produce p for 60 hours and q for 60 hours, the total output is 32 p + 45 q. • If A concentrates on production of q and B on production of p, the total result is 24 p + 60 q. • Can we say that this is a preferable outcome? 26 Apr 2021 Kristoffer J. M. Hansen, Institute for Economic Policy 16 The Higher Productivity under Division of Labour • Yes we can! For A, p has a substitution ratio of 3/2 q and for B a substitution ratio of 5/4 q, which means that 24 p + 60 q signifies a higher output than 32 p + 45 q.
Recommended publications
  • Redalyc.Theory of Money of David Ricardo
    Lecturas de Economía ISSN: 0120-2596 [email protected] Universidad de Antioquia Colombia Takenaga, Susumu Theory of Money of David Ricardo: Quantity Theory and Theory of Value Lecturas de Economía, núm. 59, julio-diciembre, 2003, pp. 73-126 Universidad de Antioquia .png, Colombia Available in: http://www.redalyc.org/articulo.oa?id=155218004003 How to cite Complete issue Scientific Information System More information about this article Network of Scientific Journals from Latin America, the Caribbean, Spain and Portugal Journal's homepage in redalyc.org Non-profit academic project, developed under the open access initiative . El carro del heno, 1500 Hieronymus Bosch –El Bosco– Jerónimo, ¿vos cómo lo ves?, 2002 Theory of Money of David Ricardo: Quantity Theory and Theory of Value Susumu Takenaga Lecturas de Economía –Lect. Econ.– No. 59. Medellín, julio - diciembre 2003, pp. 73-126 Theory of Money of David Ricardo : Quantity Theory and Theory of Value Susumu Takenaga Lecturas de Economía, 59 (julio-diciembre, 2003), pp.73-126 Resumen: En lo que es necesario enfatizar, al caracterizar la teoría cuantitativa de David Ricardo, es en que ésta es una teoría de determinación del valor del dinero en una situación particular en la cual se impide que el dinero, sin importar cual sea su forma, entre y salga libremente de la circulación. Para Ricardo, la regulación del valor del dinero por su cantidad es un caso particular en el cual el ajuste del precio de mercado al precio natural requiere un largo periodo de tiempo. La determinación cuantitativa es completamente inadmisible, pero solo cuando el período de observación es más corto que el de ajuste.
    [Show full text]
  • The Economists' Quartet - a Game, Not a Theory
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Gruescu, Sandra; Thomas, Niels Peter Working Paper The Economists' Quartet - A Game, not a Theory Darmstadt Discussion Papers in Economics, No. 109 Provided in Cooperation with: Darmstadt University of Technology, Department of Law and Economics Suggested Citation: Gruescu, Sandra; Thomas, Niels Peter (2002) : The Economists' Quartet - A Game, not a Theory, Darmstadt Discussion Papers in Economics, No. 109, Technische Universität Darmstadt, Department of Law and Economics, Darmstadt This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/84840 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Darmstadt Discussion Papers in Economics The Economists' Quartet A Game, not a Theory Sandra Gruescu and Niels Peter Thomas No.
    [Show full text]
  • Legitimacy, Globally: the Incoherence of Free Trade Practice, Global Economics and Their Governing Principles of Political Economy
    Cleveland State University EngagedScholarship@CSU Law Faculty Articles and Essays Faculty Scholarship 2001 Legitimacy, Globally: The Incoherence of Free Trade Practice, Global Economics and their Governing Principles of Political Economy Michael Henry Davis Cleveland State University, [email protected] Dana Neacsu Follow this and additional works at: https://engagedscholarship.csuohio.edu/fac_articles Part of the International Law Commons, and the International Trade Law Commons How does access to this work benefit ou?y Let us know! Original Citation Michael Henry Davis, Legitimacy, Globally: The Incoherence of Free Trade Practice, Global Economics and their Governing Principles of Political Economy 69 University of Missouri at Kansas City Law Review 733 (2001) This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at EngagedScholarship@CSU. It has been accepted for inclusion in Law Faculty Articles and Essays by an authorized administrator of EngagedScholarship@CSU. For more information, please contact [email protected]. +(,121/,1( Citation: 69 UMKC L. Rev. 733 2000-2001 Content downloaded/printed from HeinOnline (http://heinonline.org) Thu Sep 27 14:40:03 2012 -- Your use of this HeinOnline PDF indicates your acceptance of HeinOnline's Terms and Conditions of the license agreement available at http://heinonline.org/HOL/License -- The search text of this PDF is generated from uncorrected OCR text. -- To obtain permission to use this article beyond the scope of your HeinOnline license, please use: https://www.copyright.com/ccc/basicSearch.do? &operation=go&searchType=0 &lastSearch=simple&all=on&titleOrStdNo=0047-7575 LEGITIMACY, GLOBALLY: THE INCOHERENCE OF FREE TRADE PRACTICE, GLOBAL ECONOMICS AND THEIR GOVERNING PRINCIPLES OF POLITICAL ECONOMY Michael H.
    [Show full text]
  • Working Paper No. 40, the Rise and Fall of Georgist Economic Thinking
    Portland State University PDXScholar Working Papers in Economics Economics 12-15-2019 Working Paper No. 40, The Rise and Fall of Georgist Economic Thinking Justin Pilarski Portland State University Follow this and additional works at: https://pdxscholar.library.pdx.edu/econ_workingpapers Part of the Economic History Commons, and the Economic Theory Commons Let us know how access to this document benefits ou.y Citation Details Pilarski, Justin "The Rise and Fall of Georgist Economic Thinking, Working Paper No. 40", Portland State University Economics Working Papers. 40. (15 December 2019) i + 16 pages. This Working Paper is brought to you for free and open access. It has been accepted for inclusion in Working Papers in Economics by an authorized administrator of PDXScholar. Please contact us if we can make this document more accessible: [email protected]. The Rise and Fall of Georgist Economic Thinking Working Paper No. 40 Authored by: Justin Pilarski A Contribution to the Working Papers of the Department of Economics, Portland State University Submitted for: EC456 “American Economic History” 15 December 2019; i + 16 pages Prepared for Professor John Hall Abstract: This inquiry seeks to establish that Henry George’s writings advanced a distinct theory of political economy that benefited from a meteoric rise in popularity followed by a fall to irrelevance with the turn of the 20th century. During the depression decade of the 1870s, the efficacy of the laissez-faire economic system came into question, during this same timeframe neoclassical economics supplanted classical political economy. This inquiry considers both of George’s key works: Progress and Poverty [1879] and The Science of Political Economy [1898], establishing the distinct components of Georgist economic thought.
    [Show full text]
  • David Ricardo's Comparative Advantage and Developing Countries
    David Ricardo’s Comparative Advantage and Developing Countries: Myth and Reality Kalim Siddiqui1 In International Critical Thought, Vol 8, issue 3. Abstract This article examines David Ricardo’s trade theory, which emphasises that if protection is removed, resources would be expected to move away from high cost to low cost products and as a result productivity would rise. His comparative advantage trade theory advocates in favour of a free trade, the argument implied generally to defend laissez faire. This study aims to critically analyse the theoretical and empirical basis for trade liberalisation. It also discusses the mainstream arguments relating to static and dynamic gains from trade liberalisation which seem to be based on weak theoretical and empirical grounds. The study analyses the phenomenon from a historical materialist perspective. It will also briefly discuss free trade and its impact on the industrial and agricultural sectors and how the performance of both sectors could have a long-term impact on local industrialisation, food security, employment and well-being of the people in developing countries. This article builds on this political economy and looks in particular at free trade policies and their impact on the economies of developing countries. Free trade theory, which has wide support among international financial institutions, namely the IMF, World Bank, WTO (World Trade Organisation) draws on David Ricardo’s theory. The study has argued that free trade policy will deepen further the process of uneven development and unequal exchange. The study concludes that free trade policy will deepen further the process of uneven development and unequal exchange. Keywords: Comparative Advantage, developing countries, capitalist expansion, WTO and free trade.
    [Show full text]
  • Part II Core Theory: Classic International Trade Theories
    Part II Core Theory: Classic International Trade Theories Table of Contents Part II Core Theory: Classic International Trade Theories.........................2 1. Mercantilism ...........................................................................................2 The Classical World of David Ricardo and Comparative (Chapter 3).......3 Advantage ...................................................................................................3 Absolute Advantage and Comparative Advantage .....................................5 Problems of Using Absolute Advantage to Guide Allocation of Tasks......8 Ricardian Comparative Advantage.............................................................9 Resource Constraints: ...............................................................................18 Complete Specialization: ..........................................................................20 Technological take over by less developed countries...............................21 Production Possibilities: ...........................................................................21 Complete versus Partial Specialization ....................................................23 The case of a small country ......................................................................24 Some concluding observations .................................................................25 2. Extensions and Tests of the Classical Model of Trade (chapter 4).......26 2.1 The classical model in money terms...................................................27
    [Show full text]
  • PROFESSIONALIZING ECONOMICS: the 'Marginalist Revolution' in Historical Context Michael A. Bernstein Department of History 0
    PROFESSIONALIZING ECONOMICS: The ‘Marginalist Revolution’ in Historical Context Michael A. Bernstein Department of History 0104 University of California, San Diego 9500 Gilman Drive La Jolla, California 92093-0104 [USA] [Phone: 858-534-1070] [Fax: 858-534-7283] [[email protected]] 2 Economic analysis, serving for two centuries to win an understanding of the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, has been fobbed off with another bride -- a Theory of Value. There were no doubt deep-seated political reasons for the substitution but there was also a purely technical, intellectual reason. -- Joan Robinson [1956]i If the last years of the nineteenth century witnessed the first, genuine articulation of a professional self-consciousness among American economists, then they also demarcated the establishment of an altogether novel protocol for those experts. This new agenda, developed with increasing rigor and authority as the twentieth century beckoned, began a significant reorientation of the field's object of study while at the same time it reconfigured long-standing perceptions of the history of economic thought as a whole. Scientific sophistication necessarily involved a revision of practice, yet it also encouraged the articulation of new perceptions of its pedigree.ii Linking the object of study with particular and venerable authorities from the ages was of singular importance to the successful construction of a distinctly professional knowledge. Framing that understanding in a particular way was the result of both a social and an intellectual process. With their most apparent and seemingly immediate intellectual roots in the moral philosophy of the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries, modern economists were (and are) eager to invoke validation by impressive forebears and traditions.
    [Show full text]
  • 8. David Ricardo and Classical Economics Robert L
    Section XIV: The ndusI trial Revolution, Classical Contemporary Civilization (Ideas and Institutions Economics, and Economic Liberalism of Western Man) 1958 8. David Ricardo and Classical Economics Robert L. Bloom Gettysburg College Basil L. Crapster Gettysburg College Harold L. Dunkelberger Gettysburg College See next page for additional authors Follow this and additional works at: https://cupola.gettysburg.edu/contemporary_sec14 Part of the Economic History Commons, Economic Theory Commons, and the Growth and Development Commons Share feedback about the accessibility of this item. Bloom, Robert L. et al. "8. David Ricardo and Classical Economics. Pt XIV: The ndusI trial Revolution, Classical Economics, and Economic Liberalism." Ideas and Institutions of Western Man (Gettysburg College, 1958), 37-49. This is the publisher's version of the work. This publication appears in Gettysburg College's institutional repository by permission of the copyright owner for personal use, not for redistribution. Cupola permanent link: https://cupola.gettysburg.edu/ contemporary_sec14/8 This open access book chapter is brought to you by The uC pola: Scholarship at Gettysburg College. It has been accepted for inclusion by an authorized administrator of The uC pola. For more information, please contact [email protected]. 8. David Ricardo and Classical Economics Abstract It is David Ricardo, (1772-1823) rather than Malthus who has long been regarded as the more outstanding of the classical economists after Adam Smith. His father was a Jewish immigrant to England who became a prosperous merchant and broker. Ricardo entered his father's business, but after marrying a Quakeress and embracing her faith was forced onto his own resources.
    [Show full text]
  • Neoliberalism, Capital Accumulation, and Austerity in Academia, the Term
    Neoliberalism, Capital Accumulation, and Austerity Mehdi S. Shariati, Ph.D. Professor, Economics, Sociology and Geography Kansas City Kansas City Community College Abstract Recent crisis in global capitalism has once again brought to the fore major structural contradictions and the consequences of these contradictions are reflected in the massive dislocation of the economy, growing number of (the) poor, concentration of wealth in the hands of a few around the globe, indebtedness, rampant speculation and an unprecedented concentration of financial capital at the expense of productive sector of the economy. The austerity program by which the global working class must endure has generated much social protests including "occupy Wall Street," but with very little discussion of an alternative to the current global system. In academia, the term descriptive of finance capital’s policy prescription is “neoliberalism.” Yet the term not only has created confusion since in the North American context, liberals and neoliberals have always been viewed as left leaning people and not the free marketers and market fundamentalists. Neoliberalism often refers to a set of economic policies designed for intense and accelerated capital accumulation. Rarely the discussion of the process of intense capital accumulation includes a restructuring of society and social institutions as a precondition for the successful implementation of the policies. This paper is an attempt to add to the discussion by pointing out the indispensability of the practice of social imperialism in the process of reproducing the hegemonic structure and effective implementation of the policy. Reaction to the evolving socio-economic and political events has been one of the greatest preoccupation in the social and political sciences as a habit and of necessity.
    [Show full text]
  • Xerox University Microfilms 300 North Zeeb Road Ann Arbor, Michigan 4B106 73-18,905
    INFORMATION TO USERS This material was produced from a microfilm copy of the original document. While the most advanced technological means to photograph and reproduce this document have been used, the quality is heavily dependent upon the quality of the original submitted. The following explanation of techniques is provided to help you understand markings or patterns which may appear on this reproduction. 1. The sign or "target" for pages apparently lacking from die document photographed is "Missing Page(s)". If it was possible to obtain the missing page(s) or section, they are spliced into the film along with adjacent pages. This may have necessitated cutting thru an image and duplicating adjacent pages to insure you complete continuity. 2. When an image on the film is obliterated with a large round black mark, it is an indication that the photographer suspected that the copy may have moved during exposure and thus cause a blurred image. You will find a good image of the page in die adjacent frame. 3. When a map, drawing or chart, etc., was part of the material being photographed the photographer followed a definite method in "sectioning" the material. It is customary to begin photoing at the upper left hand corner of a large sheet and to continue photoing from left to right in equal sections with a small overlap. If necessary, sectioning is continued again — beginning below the first row and continuing on until complete. 4. The majority of users indicate that the textual contentof greatest is value, however, a somewhat higher quality reproduction could be made from "photographs" if essential to the understanding of the dissertation.
    [Show full text]
  • Ricardos Theory of Value and International Trade
    Ricardo’s Theory of Value and International Trade: On the Invalidity of the Alleged ‘Labour Theory of Value’* Taichi Tabuchi Abstract: This paper presents a new interpretation of Ricardo’s international trade theory. It shows that Ricardo’s value theory in his Principles can be understood exclusively as the cost-of-produc- tion theory of value, which integrates the domestic value theory and international value theo- ry, requisitely taking into consideration changes in the value of money when it is applied to the analysis of international exchange. In Section II, we critically re-examine the standard interpretation of Ricardo’s trade the- ory in the so-called ‘Ricardian Model’ in textbooks today. Based on the concepts of ‘compara- tive advantage’ and ‘gains from trade’ within the two-country two-commodity framework, we show that it is a distorted interpretation, which originated from J. S. Mill’s arguments and established through the debate between Viner and Haberler, in the opposite direction of Ricardo’s original value theory. In Section III, we present that Ricardo consistently adopted the cost-of-production theory of value, which is valid not only for domestic, but also inter- national, exchange based on the concept of natural price, with the so-called ‘labour theory of value’ being merely a subset rule in the analysis of domestic exchange. We then show that Ricardo’s original value theory inevitably takes into consideration the differences and adjust- ments in the value of money in international exchange, in the analysis of international ex- change. Finally, we will briefly review that Ricardo was heading in the right direction to- wards today’s theory of international trade including intermediate goods.
    [Show full text]
  • Ricardo and the Corn Laws: a Revision
    Ricardo and the Corn Laws: a revision Samuel Hollander I was delighted to observe in your book how forcibly you de- scribed the inexhaustible energies of this tight little Island. -HUTCHES TROWERto Ricardo, 9 November I817 I Perhaps the best-known feature of Professor J. A. Schumpeter’s fa- mous account of Ricardian economics in his History of Economic Analysis is the severe criticism of the so-called Ricardian Vice-“the habit of piling a heavy load of practical conclusions upon a tenuous groundwork, which was unequal to it yet seemed in its simplicity not only attractive but also convincing.”’ More specifically: His interest was in the clear-cut result of direct, practical signifi- cance. In order to get this he cut that general system to pieces, bundled up as large parts of it as possible, and put them in cold storage-so that as many things as possible should be frozen and “given.” He then piled one simplifying assumption upon another until, having really settled everything by these assumptions, he was left with only a few aggregative variables between which, given these assumptions, he set up simple one-way relations so that, in the end, the desired results emerged almost as tautologies. The habit of applying results of this character to the solution of practical problems we shall call the Ricardian Vice. SAMUELHOLLANDER is Professor of Economics at the University of Toronto. I. Schumpeter, A History ofEconomic Analysis (New York, 1954), p. 1171. 2. Ibid., pp. 472-3. See also pp. 541, 618, 653 n., 668. In his exhaustive new study of McCulloch, Professor O’Brien draws a sharp distinction between the procedures of his subject and those of Ricardo: “Ricardo was the abstractionist par excellence: and as a pure theoretician he has had very few intellectual equals.” By contrast, for McCul- loch, “abstract ideas on their own were of very little interest, it was their practical conclusions, taking account of peculiar circumstances, which were important to McCul- loch.
    [Show full text]