Alternative Instruments for Open Market and Discount Window Operations

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Alternative Instruments for Open Market and Discount Window Operations Federal Reserve System Alternative Instruments for Open Market and Discount Window Operations Federal Reserve System Study Group on Alternative Instruments for System Operations Federal Reserve System Alternative Instruments for Open Market and Discount Window Operations Federal Reserve System Study Group on Alternative Instruments for System Operations Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington, D.C., December 2002 CONTENTS Study Group on Alternative Instruments for System Operations v Foreword vii 1. Principles and illustrations for Federal Reserve portfolio selection and management 1-1 Principles 1-1 Illustrations of the principles 1-9 Appendix 1.A: Legislative history of the Federal Reserve Act as it relates to the discount window and open market operations 1-17 Appendix 1.B: Portfolio risks and accounting treatment 1-24 Appendix 1.C: The practice of central banking in other industrialized countries 1-28 Appendix 1.D: Criteria for assessing discount window collateral 1-36 2. Financial assets available for purchase in the open markets 2-1 Common issues 2-1 Assets available for purchase in the open markets 2-7 Appendix 2.A: Section 14 of the Federal Reserve Act–– Selected passages authorizing purchases in the open markets 2-26 3. Discount window alternatives to open market operations 3-1 Alternative Federal Reserve lending facilities 3-3 Central banking principles and related key policy issues 3-10 Summary 3-27 Appendix 3.A: Current discount window lending arrangements 3-29 Appendix 3.B: Basic framework of the discount window alternatives 3-34 Appendix 3.C: The potential effects on financial markets and institutions of replacing the SOMA's Treasury securities with advances of Federal Reserve credit 3-45 Appendix 3.D: Practical and operational issues associated with expanded use of discount window credit 3-75 Appendix 3.E: Assessment of discount window alternatives in terms of the study's overall principles 3-87 v FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM Study Group on Alternative Instruments for System Operations TEAM LEADERS AND TEAM MEMBERS Affiliations are as of the time the papers were written (November 2000). Team leaders are listed alphabetically and are the principal authors of their chapters except as noted in the appendixes. Team members are listed alphabetically within their System affiliations, which are the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (Board) and the Federal Reserve Banks in Federal Reserve District order (1–Boston, 2–New York, 3–Philadelphia, 4–Cleveland, 5–Richmond, 6–Atlanta, 7–Chicago, 8–St. Louis, 9–Minneapolis, 10–Kansas City, 11–Dallas, 12–San Francisco) 1. Principles and Illustrations for Federal Reserve Portfolio Selection and Management TEAM LEADERS: Jack Beebe (San Francisco) and Christine M. Cumming (New York) TEAM MEMBERS: BOARD: Carol C. Bertaut, Seth Carpenter, William R. Nelson, Vincent R. Reinhart BOSTON: Richard W. Kopcke, Jane Sneddon Little, Giovanni P. Olivei, Geoffrey M.B. Tootell NEW YORK: Leonardo Bartolini, Paul Bennett, George Bentley, Joyce M. Hansen, HaeRan Kim CLEVELAND: Mark S. Sniderman, Gregory Stefani RICHMOND: Marvin Goodfriend, Robert Hetzel ATLANTA: Robert A. Eisenbeis CHICAGO: Anne Marie Gonczy, Edward Green ST. LOUIS: Robert H. Rasche MINNEAPOLIS: Arthur Rolnick SAN FRANCISCO: John P. Judd 2. Financial Assets Available for Purchase in the Open Markets TEAM LEADERS: Sandra Krieger (New York) and Brian Madigan (Board) TEAM MEMBERS: BOARD: Marvin Barth, Antulio Bomfim, Seth Carpenter, Alex David, Christopher T. Downing, Eric Engen, Paul Harrison, Kathleen Johnson, Linda Kole, Joe Lange, Dean Maki, Stephen D. Oliner, Wayne Passmore, Martha Scanlon, Steven A. Sharpe, Jeffrey Slone NEW YORK: Clay Berry, Jason Bonanca, Sophia Drossos, Steven Friedman, R.J. Gallo, Richard Insalaco, Timothy Johnson, Frank Keane, Helen Mucciolo, Michael Nelson, Michael Pedroni, Wayne Pettway, Michael Schetzel, Charles Sims, Teresa Tijerina, Robert B. Toomey, Laura Weir, Patricia Zobel CLEVELAND: Joseph G. Haubrich, James Thomson DALLAS: John Duca 3. Discount Window Alternatives to Open Market Operations TEAM LEADERS: Craig Hakkio (Kansas City) and Rick Lang (Philadelphia) TEAM MEMBERS: BOARD: James A. Clouse, William R. Nelson NEW YORK: Spence Hilton PHILADELPHIA: Stephen Meyer ATLANTA: Lois Berthaume CHICAGO: Carl Vander Wilt KANSAS CITY: Gordon Sellon vii FOREWORD During its meeting on January 30-31, 2001, the Federal Open Market Committee discussed the management of the Federal Reserve System's asset portfolio in light of the rapid declines at that time in the amount of Treasury debt outstanding. The FOMC's historical reliance on purchases and sales of Treasury securities to implement monetary policy would be difficult to maintain if large budget surpluses and the associated steep reductions in Treasury debt were to continue. To prepare for such a contingency, the Committee needed to identify alternative instruments for the conduct of monetary policy and to explore the implications of their use. Staff members of the Federal Reserve System prepared a variety of materials for the Committee's January 2001 meeting. During the meeting, Committee members indicated that an edited version of the staff's background work should be released to make the public aware of the System’s efforts and to spur examination of the topic in the academic and financial communities. Since then, the prospects for large reductions in Treasury debt appear to have been significantly reduced, at least in the near term. In addition, the Federal Reserve System has revised some of its operating procedures, procedures that in some cases were the subject of close attention in these papers. Especially important among these initiatives has been the redesign of the Federal Reserve's lending facility, to be implemented in early January 2003. The studies in this volume represent conditions as they appeared in late 2000, and they have not been revised to reflect subsequent changes in circumstances. They have been edited for the sake of clarity, to update some citations to the literature, and to remove confidential information. The analyses and conclusions set forth are those of the authors and do not necessarily indicate concurrence by the Board of Governors, by the Federal Open Market Committee, by the Federal Reserve Banks, or by members of their staffs. VINCENT R. REINHART Secretary, Federal Open Market Committee 1-1 1. PRINCIPLES AND ILLUSTRATIONS FOR FEDERAL RESERVE PORTFOLIO SELECTION AND MANAGEMENT If the Federal Reserve wishes to widen the types of assets it acquires for the System Open Market Account, it should be guided by a prior set of principles for managing the composition and operations of the account. This chapter offers four such principles for managing the Federal Reserve's portfolio and provides several illustrations of putting them into practice. In discussing the four principles, we cast the presentation largely in terms of open market operations because they currently are the principal method for effecting the growth and cyclical flexibility of the Federal Reserve's balance sheet. The same principles apply, however, to any discount window credit that would substitute for, or complement, direct purchases and repurchase agreements in the open market. PRINCIPLES The starting point for developing a set of principles is the Federal Reserve Act, which gives the central bank its goals of achieving price stability and fostering sustainable economic growth.1 To accomplish its long-run objectives, the Federal Reserve should adhere to the following principles: 1. Exercise effective control over the stock of high-powered money and the size of the System's balance sheet, both in a technical sense and in the broader sense that the Federal Open Market Committee alone is able to choose and achieve its monetary policy stance in furtherance of its pursuit of the overall goals given by the legislation ("instrument independence") 2. Structure its portfolio and undertake its activities so as to minimize their effect on relative asset values and credit allocation within the private sector 3. Manage its portfolio to be adequately compensated for risks and to maintain sufficient liquidity in its portfolio to conduct potentially large actions on short notice NOTE. For helpful comments, the authors thank Peter Fisher, Donald L. Kohn, David E. Lindsey, Brian Madigan, Glenn D. Rudebusch, Thomas D. Simpson, and Bharat Trehan. 1. The Federal Open Market Committee has used these terms to describe the Federal Reserve's goals. Section 2A of the Federal Reserve Act gives the goals as maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates (12 U.S.C. §225a). 1-2 Federal Reserve System 4. Place a high priority on transparency and accountability in its monetary policy operations. The principles as stated are not immutable, and in other periods of the Federal Reserve's history, they undoubtedly would have been stated differently. But each principle is related to the goals of price stability and sustainable economic growth. The principle of instrument independence is of fundamental importance. Its importance to achieving the Federal Reserve's goals is supported by a very broad theoretical and empirical literature in monetary economics. In the 1990s, instrument independence figured prominently in central bank reforms in several major foreign economies. These developments reflect a greater social and political consensus globally on the importance of price stability in enhancing economic growth over time and on the
Recommended publications
  • Understanding Open Market Operations
    Foreword The Federal Reserve Bank of New York is responsible for Michael Akbar Akhtar, vice president of the day-to-day implementation of the nation’s monetary pol- Federal Reserve Bank of New York, leads the reader— icy. It is primarily through open market operations—pur- whether a student, market professional or an interested chases or sales of U.S. Government securities in the member of the public—through various facets of mone- open market in order to add or drain reserves from the tary policy decision-making, and offers a general per- banking system—that the Federal Reserve influences spective on the transmission of policy effects throughout money and financial market conditions that, in turn, the economy. affect output, jobs and prices. Understanding Open Market Operations pro- This edition of Understanding Open Market vides a nontechnical review of how monetary policy is Operations seeks to explain the challenges in formulat- formulated and executed. Ideally, it will stimulate read- ing and implementing U.S. monetary policy in today’s ers to learn more about the subject as well as enhance highly competitive financial environment. The book high- appreciation of the challenges and uncertainties con- lights the broad and complex set of considerations that fronting monetary policymakers. are involved in daily decisions for open market opera- William J. McDonough tions and details the steps taken to implement policy. President Understanding Open Market Operations / i Acknowledgment Much has changed in U.S. financial markets and institu- Partlan for extensive comments on drafts; and to all of tions since 1985, when the last edition of Open Market the Desk staff for graciously and patiently answering my Operations, written by Paul Meek, was published.
    [Show full text]
  • Payment System Disruptions and the Federal Reserve Followint
    Working Paper Series This paper can be downloaded without charge from: http://www.richmondfed.org/publications/ Payment System Disruptions and the Federal Reserve Following September 11, 2001† Jeffrey M. Lacker* Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Richmond, Virginia, 23219, USA December 23, 2003 Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Working Paper 03-16 Abstract The monetary and payment system consequences of the September 11, 2001, terrorist attacks are reviewed and compared to selected U.S. banking crises. Interbank payment disruptions appear to be the central feature of all the crises reviewed. For some the initial trigger is a credit shock, while for others the initial shock is technological and operational, as in September 11, but for both types the payments system effects are similar. For various reasons, interbank payment disruptions appear likely to recur. Federal Reserve credit extension following September 11 succeeded in massively increasing the supply of banks’ balances to satisfy the disruption-induced increase in demand and thereby ameliorate the effects of the shock. Relatively benign banking conditions helped make Fed credit policy manageable. An interbank payment disruption that coincided with less favorable banking conditions could be more difficult to manage, given current daylight credit policies. Keywords: central bank, Federal Reserve, monetary policy, discount window, payment system, September 11, banking crises, daylight credit. † Prepared for the Carnegie-Rochester Conference on Public Policy, November 21-22, 2003. Exceptional research assistance was provided by Hoossam Malek, Christian Pascasio, and Jeff Kelley. I have benefited from helpful conversations with Marvin Goodfriend, who suggested this topic, David Duttenhofer, Spence Hilton, Sandy Krieger, Helen Mucciolo, John Partlan, Larry Sweet, and Jack Walton, and helpful comments from Stacy Coleman, Connie Horsley, and Brian Madigan.
    [Show full text]
  • Is the Discount Window Necessary?
    Charles W. Calomiris Charles W Calomiris is associate professor of finance, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign; faculty research fellow, National Bureau of Economic Research; and visiting scholar at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Lou/s. Greg Chaudoin, Thekla Halouva and Christopher A. Williams provided research assistance. The data analysis for this article was conducted in part at the University of Illinois and the Federal Reserve Bank of Chica got 11~Jsthe Discount Window Necessary? A Penn Central Perspective N RECENT YEARS, ECONOMISTS have come Some economists (Goodfmiend and King, 1988; to question the desirability of granting banks Bordo, 1990; Kaufman, 1991, 1992; and Schwartz, the privilege of borrowing from the Federal 1992) have argued that there is no gain from al- Reserve’s discount window. The discount win- lowing the Fed to lend through the discount dow’s detractors cite several disadvantages. window. These cmitics argue that open market First, the Fed’s control over high-powet-ed operations can accomplish all legitimate policy money can be hampered. tf bank borrowing be- goals without resort to Federal Reserve lending havior is hard to predict, open market opera- to banks. Clearly, if the only policy goal is to tions cannot pem’fectly peg high-powered money, peg the supply of high-powered money, open which somne economists believe the Fed should market operations are a sufficient tool. Similar- do. Second, there are microeconomic concerns ly, the Fed could peg interest rates on traded about potential abuse of the discount window securities by purchasing or selling them. Any argument for a possible role for the discount (Schwartz1 1992).
    [Show full text]
  • LIBOR Transition: SOFR, So Good Implications of a New Reference Rate for Your Business • 2021
    LIBOR transition: SOFR, so good Implications of a new reference rate for your business • 2021 Contents What is LIBOR? 2 What fallback language is currently in place? 16 Why does LIBOR have to go? 4 How will derivative contracts be impacted? 17 Who is driving the process? 5 How will loans and bonds be impacted? 19 How can LIBOR be replaced? 7 How is Wells Fargo contributing? 21 What should I know about SOFR? 9 Where can I get further information? 22 Why are repo transactions so important? 10 Contacts 22 How can SOFR fill LIBOR’s big shoes? 11 What is LIBOR? A brief history of the London Interbank Offered Rate The London Interbank Offered Rate (LIBOR) emerged in How is LIBOR set? the 1980s as the fast-growing and increasingly international financial markets demanded aconsistent rate to serve as • 11 – 16 contributor banks submit rates based on a common reference rate for financial contracts. A Greek theoretical borrowing costs banker is credited with arranging the first transaction to • The top 25% and bottom 25% of submissions are be based on the borrowing rates derived from a “set of thrown out reference banks” in 1969.¹ • Remaining rates are averaged together The adoption of LIBOR spread quickly as many market participants saw the value in a common base rate that could underpin and standardize private transactions. At first, the rate was self-regulated, but in 1986, the British 35 LIBOR rates published at 11:00 a.m. London Time Bankers’ Association (BBA), a trade group representing 5 currencies (USD, EUR, GBP, JPY, CHF) with the London banks, stepped in to provide some oversight.
    [Show full text]
  • Csl/19-28/Download
    CFTC Letter No. 19-28 No-Action December 17, 2019 U.S. COMMODITY FUTURES TRADING COMMISSION Three Lafayette Centre 1155 21st Street, NW, Washington, DC 20581 Telephone: (202) 418-5000 Division of Clearing and Risk M. Clark Hutchison III Director Re: Staff No-Action Relief from the Swap Clearing Requirement for Amendments to Legacy Uncleared Swaps to Facilitate Orderly Transition from Inter-Bank Offered Rates to Alternative Risk-Free Rates Ladies and Gentlemen: This letter from the Division of Clearing and Risk (DCR) responds to a November 5, 2019 letter from the Alternative Reference Rates Committee (ARRC)1 on behalf of its members that are subject to certain Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC or Commission) regulations.2 Among other things, ARRC requested no-action relief for failure to comply with certain provisions of the swap clearing requirement promulgated pursuant to section 2(h)(1)(A) of the Commodity Exchange Act (CEA) and codified in part 50 of Commission regulations when swap counterparties amend certain uncleared swaps as part of an industry-wide initiative to amend swaps that reference certain London Interbank Offered Rate (LIBOR) rates and other interbank offered rates (collectively with LIBOR, the IBORs)3 to reference specified risk-free rates (RFRs). ARRC’s request to DCR focuses on swaps that were executed prior to the compliance date on which swap counterparties were required to begin centrally clearing interest rate swaps (IRS) pursuant to the CFTC’s swap clearing requirement and thus were not required to be 1 Authorities representing U.S. banking regulators and other financial sector members, including the Commission, serve as non-voting ex officio members of the ARRC.
    [Show full text]
  • Money Supply ECON 40364: Monetary Theory & Policy
    Money Supply ECON 40364: Monetary Theory & Policy Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2017 1 / 59 Readings I Mishkin Ch. 3 I Mishkin Ch. 14 I Mishkin Ch. 15, pg. 341-348 2 / 59 Money I Money is defined as anything that is accepted as payments for goods or services or in the repayment of debts I Money serves three functions: 1. Medium of exchange 2. Unit of account 3. Store of value I Any asset can serve as a store of value (e.g. house, land, stocks, bonds), but most assets do not perform the first two roles of money I Money is a stock concept { how much money you have (in your wallet, in the bank) at a given point in time. Income is a flow concept 3 / 59 Roles of Money I Medium of exchange role is the most important role of money: I Eliminates need for barter, reduces transactions costs associated with exchange, and allows for greater specialization I Unit of account is important (particularly in a diverse economy), though anything could serve as a unit of account I As a store of value, money tends to be crummy relative to other assets like stocks and houses, which offer some expected return over time I An advantage money has as a store of value is its liquidity I Liquidity refers to ease with which an asset can be converted into a medium of exchange (i.e. money) I Money is the most liquid asset because it is the medium of exchange I If you held all your wealth in housing, and you wanted to buy a car, you would have to sell (liquidate) the house, which may not be easy to do, may take a while, and may involve selling at a discount if you must do it quickly 4 / 59 Evolution of Money and Payments I Commodity money: money made up of precious metals or other commodities I Difficult to carry around, potentially difficult to divide, price may fluctuate if precious metal or commodity has consumption value independent of medium of exchange role I Paper currency: pieces of paper that are accepted as medium of exchange.
    [Show full text]
  • FEDERAL FUNDS Marvin Goodfriend and William Whelpley
    Page 7 The information in this chapter was last updated in 1993. Since the money market evolves very rapidly, recent developments may have superseded some of the content of this chapter. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Richmond, Virginia 1998 Chapter 2 FEDERAL FUNDS Marvin Goodfriend and William Whelpley Federal funds are the heart of the money market in the sense that they are the core of the overnight market for credit in the United States. Moreover, current and expected interest rates on federal funds are the basic rates to which all other money market rates are anchored. Understanding the federal funds market requires, above all, recognizing that its general character has been shaped by Federal Reserve policy. From the beginning, Federal Reserve regulatory rulings have encouraged the market's growth. Equally important, the federal funds rate has been a key monetary policy instrument. This chapter explains federal funds as a credit instrument, the funds rate as an instrument of monetary policy, and the funds market itself as an instrument of regulatory policy. CHARACTERISTICS OF FEDERAL FUNDS Three features taken together distinguish federal funds from other money market instruments. First, they are short-term borrowings of immediately available money—funds which can be transferred between depository institutions within a single business day. In 1991, nearly three-quarters of federal funds were overnight borrowings. The remainder were longer maturity borrowings known as term federal funds. Second, federal funds can be borrowed by only those depository institutions that are required by the Monetary Control Act of 1980 to hold reserves with Federal Reserve Banks.
    [Show full text]
  • Markets Committee Central Bank Collateral Frameworks and Practices
    Markets Committee Central bank collateral frameworks and practices A report by a Study Group established by the Markets Committee This Study Group was chaired by Guy Debelle, Assistant Governor of the Reserve Bank of Australia March 2013 This publication is available on the BIS website (www.bis.org). © Bank for International Settlements 2013. All rights reserved. Brief excerpts may be reproduced or translated provided the source is stated. ISBN 92-9131-926-0 (print) ISBN 92-9197-926-0 (online) Preface In July 2012, the Markets Committee established a Study Group to take stock of how collateral frameworks and practices compare across central banks and the key changes they have undergone since mid-2007. This initiative followed from the fact that, in the light of recent experience with market stress and other underlying changes in the financial landscape, many central banks have re-examined and adapted their collateral policies. It is also a natural extension of the Committee’s previous work on central bank monetary policy and operating frameworks. The Study Group was chaired by Guy Debelle, Assistant Governor of the Reserve Bank of Australia. The Group completed an interim report for review by the Markets Committee in November 2012. The finalised report was presented to central bank Governors of the Global Economy Meeting in early March 2013. The subject matter of this study is of core relevance to central banking. I believe the report could become a reference piece for those who are interested in central bank liquidity operations in different jurisdictions. Moreover, given the growing attention focused on collateral-related issues in the broader financial system, this report, which covers one specific area of collateral practices, could also serve as factual input to the wider debate.
    [Show full text]
  • Mark Carney: the Evolution of the International Monetary System
    Mark Carney: The evolution of the international monetary system Remarks by Mr Mark Carney, Governor of the Bank of Canada, to the Foreign Policy Association, New York, 19 November 2009. * * * In response to the worst financial crisis since the 1930s, policy-makers around the globe are providing unprecedented stimulus to support economic recovery and are pursuing a radical set of reforms to build a more resilient financial system. However, even this heavy agenda may not ensure strong, sustainable, and balanced growth over the medium term. We must also consider whether to reform the basic framework that underpins global commerce: the international monetary system. My purpose this evening is to help focus the current debate. While there were many causes of the crisis, its intensity and scope reflected unprecedented disequilibria. Large and unsustainable current account imbalances across major economic areas were integral to the buildup of vulnerabilities in many asset markets. In recent years, the international monetary system failed to promote timely and orderly economic adjustment. This failure has ample precedents. Over the past century, different international monetary regimes have struggled to adjust to structural changes, including the integration of emerging economies into the global economy. In all cases, systemic countries failed to adapt domestic policies in a manner consistent with the monetary system of the day. As a result, adjustment was delayed, vulnerabilities grew, and the reckoning, when it came, was disruptive for all. Policy-makers must learn these lessons from history. The G-20 commitment to promote strong, sustainable, and balanced growth in global demand – launched two weeks ago in St.
    [Show full text]
  • The Discount Window Refers to Lending by Each of Accounts” on the Liability Side
    THE DISCOUNT -WINDOW David L. Mengle The discount window refers to lending by each of Accounts” on the liability side. This set of balance the twelve regional Federal Reserve Banks to deposi- sheet entries takes place in all the examples given in tory institutions. Discount window loans generally the Box. fund only a small part of bank reserves: For ex- The next day, Ralph’s Bank could raise the funds ample, at the end of 1985 discount window loans to repay the loan by, for example, increasing deposits were less than three percent of total reserves. Never- by $1,000,000 or by selling $l,000,000 of securities. theless, the window is perceived as an important tool In either case, the proceeds initially increase reserves. both for reserve adjustment and as part of current Actual repayment occurs when Ralph’s Bank’s re- Federal Reserve monetary control procedures. serve account is debited for $l,000,000, which erases the corresponding entries on Ralph’s liability side and Mechanics of a Discount Window Transaction on the Reserve Bank’s asset side. Discount window lending takes place through the Discount window loans, which are granted to insti- reserve accounts depository institutions are required tutions by their district Federal Reserve Banks, can to maintain at their Federal Reserve Banks. In other be either advances or discounts. Virtually all loans words, banks borrow reserves at the discount win- today are advances, meaning they are simply loans dow. This is illustrated in balance sheet form in secured by approved collateral and paid back with Figure 1.
    [Show full text]
  • Open Market Operations and Money Supply at Zero Nominal Interest Rates
    Open Market Operations and Money Supply at Zero Nominal Interest Rates Roberto Robatto∗ University of Chicago October 21, 2012 (first draft: February 2012) Abstract What are the paths of money supply that are consistent with zero nominal interest rates and that can be implemented through open market operations? To answer this question, I present an Irrelevance Proposition for some open market operations that exchange money and one-period bonds at the zero lower bound. The result has implications for the conduct of monetary policy (non-irrelevant open market operations modify the equilibrium) and for the implementation of the Friedman rule (any growth rate of money supply above the negative of the rate of time preferences can implement zero nominal interest rate forever, even a positive growth rate, provided that the government collects \large enough" surpluses). The result holds under several specifications, including models with heterogeneity, non- separable utility, borrowing constraints, incomplete and segmented markets and sticky prices; and generalizes to any situation in which the cost of holding money vs. bonds is zero, such as the payment of interest on money. ∗Email: [email protected]. I am extremely greatful to Fernando Alvarez for his suggestions and guidance. I would like to thank also John Cochrane, Thorsten Drautzburg, Tom Sargent, Harald Uhlig and participants to the AMT, Capital Theory and Economic Dynamics Working Groups at the University of Chicago for their comments. 1 1 Introduction At zero nominal interest rates, money is perfect substitutes for bonds from the point of view of the private sector. Money demand is thus not uniquely determined, therefore the equilibrium in the money market depends on the supply of money.
    [Show full text]
  • Liquidity, Information, and the Overnight Rate
    WORKING PAPER SERIES NO. 378 / JULY 2004 LIQUIDITY, INFORMATION, AND THE OVERNIGHT RATE by Christian Ewerhart, Nuno Cassola, Steen Ejerskov and Natacha Valla WORKING PAPER SERIES NO. 378 / JULY 2004 LIQUIDITY, INFORMATION, AND THE OVERNIGHT RATE 1 by Christian Ewerhart 2, Nuno Cassola 3, Steen Ejerskov 3 and Natacha Valla 3 In 2004 all publications will carry This paper can be downloaded without charge from a motif taken http://www.ecb.int or from the Social Science Research Network from the €100 banknote. electronic library at http://ssrn.com/abstract_id=564623. 1 The authors would like to thank Joseph Stiglitz for encouragement and for a helpful discussion on the topic of the paper. The paper also benefitted from comments made by attendents to the Lecture Series on Monetary Policy Implementation, Operations and Money Markets at the ECB in January 2004 and by participants of the joint ETH/University of Zurich quantitative methods workshop in April 2004. The opinions expressed in this paper are those of the authors alone and do not necessarily reflect the views of the European Central Bank. 2 Postal address for correspondence: Institute for Empirical Research in Economics,Winterthurerstrasse 30, CH-8006 Zurich, Switzerland. E-mail: [email protected]. 3 European Central Bank, D Monetary Policy, Kaiserstrasse 29, 60311 Frankfurt am Main, Germany, e-mail: [email protected] © European Central Bank, 2004 Address Kaiserstrasse 29 60311 Frankfurt am Main, Germany Postal address Postfach 16 03 19 60066 Frankfurt am Main, Germany Telephone +49 69 1344 0 Internet http://www.ecb.int Fax +49 69 1344 6000 Telex 411 144 ecb d All rights reserved.
    [Show full text]