Abuse of Dominance and Monopolisation 1996

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Abuse of Dominance and Monopolisation 1996 Abuse of Dominance and Monopolisation 1996 The OECD Competition Committee debated abuse of dominance and monopolisation in February 1996. This document includes an analytical note by Ms. Sally Van Siclen for the OECD Secretariat, written submissions from Ms. M. Janow and Mr. A. Fels, contributions from Canada, the European Commission, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, the United Kingdom, the United States and BIAC, as well as an aide-memoire of the discussion. The competition laws of many OECD countries contain a concept of single firm exploitation of market power or use of improper means of attaining or retaining market power. Some laws also contain the concept of “joint dominance”, distinct from multiple firms acting pursuant to an agreement. Topics covered include how observed conduct, notably exclusionary conduct, interacts with finding whether a firm has a dominant position; economic dependency; abusive conduct; whether abuse of dominance can give rise to market access problems; and appropriate relief. Remedies and Sanctions in Abuse of Dominance Cases (2006) Competition on the Merits (2005) Policy Brief: Preserving Competition: Keeping Predators at Bay (2005) Predatory Foreclosure (2004) Predatory Pricing (1989) General Distribution OCDE/GD(96)131 Cancels & replaces the same document: distributed 09-Sep-1996 ABUSE OF DOMINANCE AND MONOPOLISATION ORGANISATION FOR ECONOMIC CO-OPERATION AND DEVELOPMENT Paris 1996 42291 Document complet disponible sur OLIS dans son format d'origine Complete document available on OLIS in its original format Copyright OECD, 1996 Applications for permission to reproduce or translate all or part of this material should be made to: Head of Publications Service, OECD, 2 rue André-Pascal, 75775 - Paris Cedex 16, France. Copyright OCDE, 1996 Les demandes de reproduction ou de traduction totales ou partielles doivent être adressées à : M. le Chef du Service des Publications, OCDE, 2 rue André-Pascal, 75775 Paris Cedex 16, France 2 FOREWORD This document comprises proceedings in the original languages of a roundtable on Abuse of Dominance which was held by the Committee on Competition Law and Policy in February 1996. It is published as a general distribution document under the responsibility of the Secretary General of the OECD to bring information on this topic to the attention of a wider audience. This compilation is one of several published in a series named “Competition Policy Roundtables.” PRÉFACE Ce document rassemble la documentation, dans la langue d’origine dans laquelle elle a été soumise, relative à une table ronde sur “l’abus de position dominante” qui s’est tenue en février 1996 dans le cadre du Comité du droit et de la politique de la concurrence. Il est mis en diffusion générale sous la responsabilité du Secrétaire général de l’OCDE afin de porter à la connaissance d’un large public, les éléments d’informations qui ont été réunis à cette occasion. 3 4 TABLE OF CONTENTS BACKGROUND NOTE (by Sally Van Siclen, OECD Secretariat)...................................................... 7 NOTE DE REFERENCE (par Sally Van Siclen, Secrétariat de l’OCDE)............................................ 19 INTERNATIONAL PERSPECTIVES ON ABUSE OF DOMINANCE (by Merit E. Janow).............. 33 L’ABUS DE POSITION DOMINANTE DANS UNE OPTIQUE INTERNATIONALE (par Merit E. Janow)........................................................................................................................... 59 NATIONAL CONTRIBUTIONS: Canada................................................................................................................................ 89 Germany............................................................................................................................ 113 Ireland............................................................................................................................... 121 Italy................................................................................................................................... 125 Japan................................................................................................................................. 131 Portugal............................................................................................................................. 143 Portugal............................................................................................................................. 145 Spain................................................................................................................................. 149 Sweden............................................................................................................................. 153 The United Kingdom......................................................................................................... 155 The United States.............................................................................................................. 161 Commission of the European Union, part I........................................................................ 173 Commission de l’Union européenne, partie I..................................................................... 185 Commission de l’Union européenne, partie II.................................................................... 197 Commission of the European Union, part III...................................................................... 203 CONTRIBUTION BY PROFESSOR ALAN FELS......................................................................... 207 CONTRIBUTIONS FROM BIAC: Article 86 EC: Abuse of Dominance, by Christopher Bright.............................................. 219 Abuse of dominance in the United States, by Joseph J. Simons......................................... 225 Abuse of dominant position under the Canadian Competition Act, by Calvin S. Goldman and Crystal L. Witterick.................................................................................................... 233 5 AIDE-MÉMOIRE OF THE DISCUSSION...................................................................................... 247 AIDE-MÉMOIRE DE LA DISCUSSION........................................................................................ 267 OTHER TITLES IN THE SERIES ROUNDTABLES ON COMPETITION POLICY...................... 288 6 BACKGROUND NOTE (by Sally Van Siclen) The competition laws of many OECD countries contain a concept of single firm exploitation of market power or use of improper means of attaining or retaining market power.1 These concepts are variously called "abuse of dominant position" or "monopolisation" or "misuse of market power," or some similar term. Competition laws may also contain a related concept, called "joint dominance" in some jurisdictions, which involves multiple firms but which is a distinct concept from firms acting pursuant to an "agreement." Typically, an analysis of an abuse of dominance involves two distinct parts, determining the status of the firm or firms and then evaluating the behaviour.2 This note will briefly examine some of these concepts. The first part will discuss the similarities of the various definitions of dominant position or monopoly. The second part concerns some of the conduct that is condemned. The third part discusses remedies and the last part is a conclusion. Before turning to definitions of specific legal concepts, however, the economic concept of "dominance" should be discussed. A useful definition would anticipate the objective of the competition law and policy that will use it. One possible definition is, "circumstances in which single firm strategies may" -- or, perhaps, "are likely to" -- "have adverse effects on welfare." (Ordover and Saloner, p. 539) This definition anticipates a welfare maximisation objective without clarifying the relative weights of static and dynamic efficiencies. An alternative is the definition of dominant position provided by the European Court of Justice: "a position of economic strength enjoyed by an undertaking which enables it to prevent effective competition being maintained on the relevant market by affording it the power to behave to an appreciable extent independently of its competitors, customers and ultimately of its consumers" (United Brands v Commission, Case 27/76 [1978] ECR 207, [1978] 1 CMLR 429). This definition contains two elements -- an ability to prevent effective competition and an ability to behave independently of three sets of market actors. While the definition cannot be taken as its dictionary meaning -- even a pure monopolist must take into account the alternative opportunities of its customers -- it could perhaps mean that such a firm's strategies do not change much with changes in the strategies of the other market actors. This might anticipate an objective like "equalisation of bargaining power." A better understanding of just what the legal standards try to measure would improve, in turn, the legal standards themselves. We turn now to those standards, bearing in mind the economic concept(s) and objective(s) towards which they are employed. Definitions This section contains a discussion of the status of the firms with which we are concerned in this note, i.e., the definitions of "dominant position." Despite the broad similarity of terms and concepts, distinct concepts appear to be involved. It is perhaps useful first to suggest commonalities. 7 Determining whether a firm has a dominant position is done with reference to a defined market. That is, the firm
Recommended publications
  • Report on the Results of the Icn Survey on Dominance/Substantial Market Power in Digital Markets
    Unilateral Conduct Working Group, July 2020. REPORT ON THE RESULTS OF THE ICN SURVEY ON DOMINANCE/SUBSTANTIAL MARKET POWER IN DIGITAL MARKETS 1. Introduction Digital technologies have entered all sectors of the economy and more and more companies are transitioning to the use of digital systems and technologies. Competition authorities are increasingly confronted with the need to assess unilateral conduct in digital markets.1 A number of competition authorities have commissioned studies aiming at understanding how digital markets operate and many authorities have already gathered experience in dealing with unilateral conduct in such markets. The literature on this subject has been growing exponentially too. In response to these developments, in 2019 the Unilateral Conduct Working Group (UCWG) decided to start a new multi-year project which focuses on issues relating to unilateral conduct in digital markets, and in particularly, on the assessment of dominance/substantial market power2 in these markets. The discussions held in May 2019 at the annual ICN conference in Cartagena, and in November 2019 at the UCWG workshop in Mexico, showed that these issues are of interest to many ICN members. Indeed, establishing dominance/substantial market power is an important step, and often the starting point, in the assessment of unilateral conduct. Therefore, as part of the UCWG multi-year project, the co-chairs of the UCWG prepared a survey, which sought to collect information on the ICN members’ experience in assessing dominance/substantial market power in digital markets. Its aim was to clarify whether this experience suggests that the assessment of dominance/substantial market power in digital markets requires considerations or techniques of assessment different from those applied in non-digital markets.
    [Show full text]
  • Antitrust Status of Farmer Cooperatives
    USDA Antitrust Status of Farmer Cooperatives: United States Department of Agriculture The Story of the Capper- Rural Business- Volstead Act Cooperative Service Cooperative Information Report 59 Abstract The Capper-Volstead Act provides a limited exemption from antitrust liability for agricultural producers who market the products they produce on a cooperative basis. Without Capper-Volstead, farmers who agree among themselves on the pric es they'll accept for their products and other terms of trade would risk being held in violation of antitrust law. Even with the exemption, agricultural producers are not free to unduly enhance the prices they charge, consolidate with or collaborate in anticompetitive conduct with nonproducers, or engage in conduct with no legitimate business purpose that is intended to reduce competition. Keywords: cooperative, antitrust, Capper-Volstead Act, law ________________________________________ Antitrust Status of Farmer Cooperatives: The Story of the Capper-Volstead Act Donald A. Frederick Program Leader Law, Policy & Governance Rural Business-Cooperative Service U.S. Department of Agriculture Cooperative Information Report 59 September 2002 RBS publications and information are available on the Internet. The RBS w eb site is: http://www.rurdev.usda.gov/rbs Preface Antitrust law poses a special challenge to agricultural marketing associations. Certain conduct by independent business people-- agreeing on prices, terms of sale, and whom to sell to--violates the Sherman Act and other antitrust statutes. And these are the very types of collaborative activities that agricultural producers conduct through their marketing cooperatives. Since 1922, the Capper-Volstead Act has provided a limited antitrust exemption for agricultural marketing associations. Producers, through qualifying associations, can agree on prices and other terms of sale, select the extent of their joint marketing activity, agree on common marketing practices with other cooperatives, and achieve substantial market share and influence.
    [Show full text]
  • Defensive and Offensive Strategies for Market Success
    International Journal of Business and Social Science Vol. 2 No. 13 [Special Issue - July 2011] Defensive and Offensive Strategies for Market Success Dr. Peter Yannopoulos Associate Professor Brock University, St. Catharines Ontario, Canada, L2S 3A1 E-mail: [email protected] Tel: (905) 688-5550 ext. 3909 Abstract In industries in which there is strategic interaction among competing firms, companies are continuously involved in defensive and offensive strategies. In this paper we discuss several defensive and offensive strategies that managers can you for market success. Defensive strategies are divided into pre-entry and post-entry stretegies. Marketing managers should attempt to discourage would be entrants before entry has occurred. They can achieve this goal by engaging in pre-entry startegies. After entry is occurred it is more difficult to persuade new entrants to exit the industry. For this reason, marketing managers should use different defensive strategies for defending their positions in pre-entry and post-entry situations. Key words: Defensive strategies, offensive strategies, pre-entry strategies, post-entry strategies 1. Introduction Competition forces companies to constantly engage in offensive and defensive marketing strategies. Rivalry occurs because one or more competitors either feels the pressure or sees an opportunity to enter an industry or to improve its position within an industry. In most cases, competitive moves by one firm have noticeable effects on its competitors and, thus, may invite retaliation or efforts to counter the move (Porter 1980). Companies respond to competitor challenges by counterattacking with increasing advertising expenditures, cutting prices, increasing innovation, and introducing new products, or even accommodating the entrant by doing nothing or decreasing the level of marketing effort (Karakaya and Yannopoulos, 2011; Scherer, 1980).
    [Show full text]
  • In the United States Court of Appeals for the Eleventh
    Case: 15-14160 Date Filed: 03/04/2019 Page: 1 of 74 [PUBLISH] IN THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ELEVENTH CIRCUIT ________________________ No. 15-14160 ________________________ D.C. Docket Nos. 6:14-md-02557-GAP-TBS, 6:14-cv-06012-GAP-TBS QUALITY AUTO PAINTING CENTER OF ROSELLE, INC., Traded as Prestige Auto Body, Plaintiff-Appellant, versus STATE FARM INDEMNITY COMPANY, STATE FARM GUARANTY INSURANCE COMPANY, et al., Defendants-Appellees. ________________________ No. 15-14162 ________________________ D.C. Docket Nos. 6:14-md-02557-GAP-TBS, 6:14-cv-06013-GAP-TBS ULTIMATE COLLISION REPAIR, INC., Case: 15-14160 Date Filed: 03/04/2019 Page: 2 of 74 Plaintiff-Appellant, versus STATE FARM INDEMNITY COMPANY, STATE FARM GUARANTY INSURANCE COMPANY, et al., Defendants-Appellees. ________________________ No. 15-14178 ________________________ D.C. Docket Nos. 6:14-md-02557-GAP-TBS, 6:14-cv-06018-GAP-TBS CAMPBELL COUNTY AUTO BODY, INC., Plaintiff-Appellant, versus STATE FARM MUTUAL AUTOMOBILE INSURANCE COMPANY, STATE FARM FIRE & CASUALTY COMPANY, et al., Defendants-Appellees. ________________________ No. 15-14179 ________________________ D.C. Docket Nos. 6:14-md-02557-GAP-TBS, 2 Case: 15-14160 Date Filed: 03/04/2019 Page: 3 of 74 6:14-cv-06019-GAP-TBS LEE PAPPAS BODY SHOP, INC., DAVID C. BROSIUS, d.b.a. Martins Auto Body Works, Inc., ART WALKER AUTO SERVICES, INC., WHITEFORD COLLISION AND REFINISHING, INC., Plaintiffs-Appellants, versus STATE FARM MUTUAL AUTOMOBILE INSURANCE COMPANY, STATE FARM FIRE & CASUALTY COMPANY, et al, Defendants-Appellees. ________________________ No. 15-14180 ________________________ D.C. Docket Nos. 6:14-md-02557-GAP-TBS, 6:15-cv-06022-GAP-TBS CONCORD AUTO BODY, INC., Plaintiff-Appellant, versus STATE FARM MUTUAL AUTOMOBILE INSURANCE COMPANY, STATE FARM FIRE & CASUALTY COMPANY, et al, 3 Case: 15-14160 Date Filed: 03/04/2019 Page: 4 of 74 Defendants-Appellees.
    [Show full text]
  • Buyer Power: Is Monopsony the New Monopoly?
    COVER STORIES Antitrust , Vol. 33, No. 2, Spring 2019. © 2019 by the American Bar Association. Reproduced with permission. All rights reserved. This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or stored in an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association. Buyer Power: Is Monopsony the New Monopoly? BY DEBBIE FEINSTEIN AND ALBERT TENG OR A NUMBER OF YEARS, exists—or only when it can also be shown to harm consumer commentators have debated whether the United welfare; (2) historical case law on monopsony; (3) recent States has a monopoly problem. But as part of the cases involving monopsony issues; and (4) counseling con - recent conversation over the direction of antitrust siderations for monopsony issues. It remains to be seen law and the continued appropriateness of the con - whether we will see significantly increased enforcement Fsumer welfare standard, the debate has turned to whether the against buyer-side agreements and mergers that affect buyer antitrust agencies are paying enough attention to monopsony power and whether such enforcement will be successful, but issues. 1 A concept that appears more in textbooks than in case what is clear is that the antitrust enforcement agencies will be law has suddenly become mainstream and practitioners exploring the depth and reach of these theories and clients should be aware of developments when they counsel clients must be prepared for investigations and enforcement actions on issues involving supply-side concerns. implicating these issues. This topic is not going anywhere any time soon.
    [Show full text]
  • The Dominance and Monopolies Review, Fifth Edition
    Dominance and Monopolies Review Fifth Edition Editors Maurits Dolmans and Henry Mostyn lawreviews the Dominance and Monopolies Review The Dominance and Monopolies Review Reproduced with permission from Law Business Research Ltd. This article was first published in The Dominance and Monopolies Review, - Edition 5 (published in July 2017 – editors Maurits Dolmans and Henry Mostyn) For further information please email [email protected] Dominance and Monopolies Review Fifth Edition Editors Maurits Dolmans and Henry Mostyn lawreviews PUBLISHER Gideon Roberton SENIOR BUSINESS DEVELOPMENT MANAGER Nick Barette BUSINESS DEVELOPMENT MANAGERS Thomas Lee, Joel Woods ACCOUNT MANAGERS Pere Aspinall, Sophie Emberson, Laura Lynas, Jack Bagnall MARKETING AND READERSHIP COORDINATOR Rebecca Mogridge RESEARCHER Arthur Hunter EDITORIAL COORDINATOR Gavin Jordan HEAD OF PRODUCTION Adam Myers PRODUCTION EDITOR Martin Roach SUBEDITOR Janina Godowska CHIEF EXECUTIVE OFFICER Paul Howarth Published in the United Kingdom by Law Business Research Ltd, London 87 Lancaster Road, London, W11 1QQ, UK © 2017 Law Business Research Ltd www.TheLawReviews.co.uk No photocopying: copyright licences do not apply. The information provided in this publication is general and may not apply in a specific situation, nor does it necessarily represent the views of authors’ firms or their clients. Legal advice should always be sought before taking any legal action based on the information provided. The publishers accept no responsibility for any acts or omissions contained
    [Show full text]
  • Are You Using the Term “Agile” Correctly?
    Are you using the term “Agile” correctly? There are a host of technical terms that get thrown around when discussing software implementations and outsourcing solutions. Understandably, these concepts are often misused or confused, which can improperly influence our decision-making and ultimately our allocation of resources. In this article, we will explore some key terms and how we can properly apply them to business planning and vendor management as we move into the modern digital age. Modern Application Architecture (“MAA”). Prior to recent advancements in technology (e.g., cloud platforms such as Amazon Web Services) and a growing demand for nimble contracting strategies, single-platform or single-solution providers were the go-to choice for the pharmaceutical industry when tackling commercial and government contracting. As the world evolves, however, so must our thinking around the solutions that support our business functions. Recognizing the value of recent advancements, when Riparian embarked on the journey of developing our software solutions, we centered on some key concepts that were critical to our success. One of them is MAA which is a foundational concept used for flexible and Agile software development, giving organizations the ability to reduce risk and pivot. MAA stresses certain process characteristics such as organizing around business capabilities, componentization, the ability to interface with other platforms, and Agile development. Having explored these concepts from a foundational business perspective in developing our software solutions, we also believe the concepts should be applied more broadly--- beyond software to the process of outsourcing commercialization services for the life sciences industry. Componentization. Again, historically, organizations looked to single software-platforms or single-solution providers to implement or outsource their revenue management/ contract management requirements.
    [Show full text]
  • Product Compatibility in Markets with Network Effects
    Avoiding Market Dominance: Product Compatibility in Markets with Network E®ects¤ Jiawei Chen Department of Economics University of California-Irvine Irvine, CA 92697 (949) 824-3189, -2182 (Fax) [email protected] www.socsci.uci.edu/~jiaweic Ulrich Doraszelski Department of Economics Harvard University Cambridge, MA 02138 617-495-2896, -8570 (Fax) [email protected] www.economics.harvard.edu/faculty/doraszelski Joseph E. Harrington, Jr. Department of Economics Johns Hopkins University Baltimore, MD 21218 410-516-7615, -7600 (Fax) [email protected] www.econ.jhu/people/harrington September 13, 2008 ¤The comments of two anonymous referees, the editor, Mike Baye, Brian Viard, and seminar participants at Indiana (Kelley School of Business), Ohio State, Illinois, Antitrust Division of the U.S. Department of Justice, 2007 IIOC, and 2007 EARIE are very much appreciated. The second author gratefully acknowledges the hospitality of the Hoover Institution during 2006/07 and the third author expresses his gratitude to the Department of Economics of Harvard University where, during 2005/06, much of this work was done. 1 Abstract As is well-recognized, market dominance is a typical outcome in markets with network e®ects. A ¯rm with a larger installed base o®ers a more attractive product which induces more consumers to buy its product which produces a yet bigger installed base advantage. Such a setting is investigated here but with the main di®erence that ¯rms have the option of making their products compatible. When ¯rms have similar installed bases, they make their products compatible in order to expand the market. Nevertheless, random forces could result in one ¯rm having a bigger installed base in which case the larger ¯rm may make its product incompatible.
    [Show full text]
  • Market Dominance Determinations and the Use of Product and Geographic Competition: a Verified Statement Before the Surface Transportation Board
    MARKET DOMINANCE DETERMINATIONS AND THE USE OF PRODUCT AND GEOGRAPHIC COMPETITION: A VERIFIED STATEMENT BEFORE THE SURFACE TRANSPORTATION BOARD John D. Bitzan Denver D. Tolliver July 1998 ABSTRACT On April 29, 1998, the Surface Transportation Board (STB) opened a proceeding to consider elimination of the consideration of geographic and product competition from its market dominance guidelines for rail rates. This publication includes the Verified Statement of John Bitzan and Denver Tolliver in this proceeding.1 Before a rate can be challenged under the maximum reasonable rate guidelines established by Ex Parte 347, it must first be determined that the STB has jurisdiction over the movements in question. Currently, the STB considers four factors in its determination of market dominance: intramodal competition, competition between railroads at the same general location; intermodal competition, competition between railroads and other modes: geographic competition, competition between railroads able to supply the same product to a destination, but originating at different sources, or competition between railroads able to ship an originating product to different destinations; and product competition, competition between railroads at different locations in shipping substitute products. Because of the large burdens placed on shippers from responding to railroad statements of geographic and product competition in market dominance proceedings, and because of the potential inconsistency of burdensome market dominance guidelines with the STB’s recent efforts to make rate challenges more accessible to small shippers, the STB has opened this proceeding. In our Verified Statement, we argue that geographic and product competition should be eliminated 1The verified statement of Bitzan and Tolliver was submitted with the filing by the North Dakota Public Service Commission, the North Dakota Wheat Commission, and the North Dakota Grain Dealers Association.
    [Show full text]
  • Hewlett Packard: Continuing Dominance in the Printer Industry
    HEWLETT PACKARD: CONTINUING DOMINANCE IN THE PRINTER INDUSTRY BEM 106 Friday May 28, 2004 Anita Choi, Chris Flatt, Mike Lammers, Jason Quimby 1. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY By the 2006, Americans will be printing 1.8 trillion pages and spending $15 billion a year on ink and toner. Printers are one of the most important complements to the PC, needed by users both at home and in the office to transfer any electronic document onto paper. Since the first dot-matrix printer was introduced into the market in the early 1980s, printer technology has rapidly evolved to become machines that are increasingly efficient in producing sophisticated looking documents both in color and black-and- white. Hewlett Packard is a global leader in the industry of home and office printing. Even after merging with Compaq in 2002, HP’s Imaging and Printing group accounts for about 30% of the companies revenues and is markedly the most profitable division with earnings 1.4 times that of the company as a whole. Recently HP has faced new challenges with the entry of Dell and the surge in inkjet cartridge refill kits. This paper explores the challenges that HP faces in maintaining its dominance in the printer industry with respect to the competitive landscape and its current business strategy. 2. BACKGROUND ON HEWLETT PACKARD HP was founded in 1939 by Bill Hewlett and Dave Packard. The company has its roots in the electronics, microwave, and radio industries. World War II government contracts enabled the business to grow into a million dollar company by 1944. By the 1960s, HP had diversified into personal computing, starting with programmable calculators in 1972, and eventually entering the desktop market in 1980.
    [Show full text]
  • Competition Policy Review: Draft Report Submissions
    Submission to the Harper Review – Response to Draft Report 14 November 2014 Nicolas J. Taylor, Partner Prudence J. Smith, Of-Counsel The contents of this document are proprietary and should not be duplicated or shared without express permission from Jones Day (109967). SYI-720126869v1 1. Introduction 1.1. Jones Day welcomes the opportunity to make a submission to the Harper Review Panel (Panel) in response to the Draft Report dated September 2014 (draft report). 1.2. In this submission Jones Day focuses on the Panel’s views expressed in the draft report on the prohibition on resale price maintenance (RPM). In particular the Panel states, at page 236 of the draft report: There is not a sufficient case for changing the prohibition of RPM from a per se prohibition to a competition-based test. Nevertheless, the notification process should be extended to RPM, to provide a quicker and less expensive exemption process for business. The prohibition should also be amended to include an exemption for RPM conduct between related bodies corporate, as is the case under section 45 and 47. 1.3. Jones day is of the view that RPM would benefit from a reform to adopt a competition- based test. Our reasons are presented below. In the event that the Panel is not minded to recommend the competition-based test, Jones Day submits, at the minimum, the Panel’s recommendation in the draft report, to extend the notification process to RPM conduct, must be implemented. If such an approach is adopted, guidance from the Panel to the ACCC as to the matters to be considered in respect of a notification of RPM would be invaluable.
    [Show full text]
  • Broader Access Models for Realizing Information Dominance
    HORIZONTAL INTEGRATION: Broader Access Models for Realizing Information Dominance JSR-04-132 Approved for Public Release JASON Program Office MITRE Corporation 7515 Colshire Dr. McLean, Virginia 22102 (703) 883-6997 Form Approved REPORT DOCUMENTATION PAGE OMB No. 0704-0188 Public reporting burden for this collection of information estimated to average 1 hour per response, including the time for review instructions, searching existing data sources, gathering and maintaining the data needed, and completing and reviewing the collection of information. Send comments regarding this burden estimate or any other aspect of this collection of information, including suggestions for reducing this burden, to Washington Headquarters Services, Directorate for Information Operations and Reports, 1215 Jefferson Davis Highway, Suite 1204, Arlington, VA 22202-4302, and to the Office of Management and Budget. Paperwork Reduction Project (0704-0188), Washington, DC 20503. 1. AGENCY USE ONLY (Leave blank) 2. REPORT DATE 3. REPORT TYPE AND DATES COVERED December 2004 4. TITLE AND SUBTITLE 5. FUNDING NUMBERS Horizontal Integration: Broader Access Models for Realizing Information Dominance 6. AUTHOR(S) 13049022-DC 7. PERFORMING ORGANIZATION NAME(S) AND ADDRESS(ES) 8. PERFORMING ORGANIZATION REPORT NUMBER The MITRE Corporation JASON Program Office JSR-04-132 7515 Colshire Drive McLean, Virginia 22102 9. SPONSORING/MONITORING AGENCY NAME(S) AND ADDRESS(ES) 10. SPONSORING/MONITORING AGENCY REPORT NUMBER Office of Defense Research and Engineering (ODDR&E) Director, Plans and Programs 3030 Defense Pentagon JSR-04-132 Room 3D108 Washington, DC 20301-3030 11. SUPPLEMENTARY NOTES 12a. DISTRIBUTION/AVAILABILITY STATEMENT 12b. DISTRIBUTION CODE Approved for public release. Distribution Statement A 13. ABSTRACT (Maximum 200 words) Horizontal integration refers to the desired end-state where intelligence of all kinds flows rapidly and seamlessly to the warfighter, and enables information dominance warfare.
    [Show full text]