Interview with Giovanni Arrighi

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Interview with Giovanni Arrighi Special Contribution: Interview with Giovanni Arrighi “At Some Point Something Has To Give” – Declining U.S. Power, the Rise of China, and an Adam Smith for the Contemporary Left1 Conducted and transcribed by Kevan Harris Princeton University iovanni Arrighi (1937-2009) spent rise of everyone else, or to paraphrase Alice his life thinking and writing about Amsden (and Zakaria himself), what we are G what he saw on his well-traveled seeing is the “Rise of the Rest.” Zakaria path: liberation movements in Africa, writes, “Billions of people are escaping from worker rebellion in Italy, global inequality abject poverty. The world will be enriched between North and South, the military and and ennobled as they become consumers, financial limits of US power, and the producers, inventors, thinkers, dreamers, and economic rise of China. In his many articles doers. This is all happening because of and books, including an unplanned trilogy American ideas and actions. For 60 years the on the origins and workings of global United States has pushed countries to open capitalism, Arrighi grappled with the their markets, free up their politics, and complexities of history and the limitations of embrace trade and technology – to learn the existing economic and political theories. secrets of our success.” He goes on to say This rethinking was fully on display in his that rising protectionist and isolationist final book, Adam Smith in Beijing: Lineages sentiments in the U.S. today go directly of the Twenty-First Century. Although I against this track record of success. How interviewed Arrighi on May 18, 2008, much truth is there in Zakaria’s argument? several months before the financial meltdown in global markets, his prescient Giovanni Arrighi: Well, there is one statements are relevant for the crises we element of truth there. The United States did face today. Arrighi passed away in June indeed push countries to liberalize trade. 2009. His scholarly and intellectual And it is true that the liberalization of trade tradition continues on at the Giovanni in the world, generally, has enabled many Arrighi Center for Global Studies at The countries to industrialize and “modernize.” Johns Hopkins University. However, in spite of widespread “modernization,” “industrialization,” etc. of Kevan Harris: Fareed Zakaria, in his book “the Rest,” the income gap between the The Post-American World, says that the North and the Rest – what used to be the United States is no longer the country of Second and Third Worlds – has not been “number ones.” We don’t have the tallest reduced much. So, on the whole, the wealthy building in the world, the biggest mall, the remain wealthy, and the poor remain poor. biggest company, the biggest airplane, or However, starting in the 1980s, there has even the biggest movie industry. Zakaria been major diversification and unevenness believes, however, this is not a world of outcomes within the global South. Some defined by the decline of America but by the regions have done well, most notably East Copyright ©2012, American Sociological Association, Volume 18, Number 2, Pages 157-166 ISSN 1076-156X Interview with Giovanni Arrighi 158 Asia and to a lesser extent South Asia. Some neoliberal economic principles, and through regions have done very badly, experiencing this a fusion of militarism (public and social, economic, and political catastrophes private) and market fundamentalism has – first and foremost Sub-Saharan Africa, but pervaded the reunification of the world also Latin America in the 1980s and 1990s, economy since the 1970s. This is and the former Soviet Union in the 1990s. emblematic of a more general belief on the So, it is true that on the whole there is not an US and European left that participation in absolute decline of the United States as the world market carries with it the much as the relative rise of certain regions. subjugation of a country’s population to the First Europe and Japan narrowed the gap in prevailing international political and relation to the United States in the decades economic order. There is similarity here immediately following the Second World with Zakaria’s argument, except that Klein War, and then more recently certain regions sees this as disastrous for the global South. in the global South. But this has been Is this a better way to view the last 30 years? counterbalanced by the widening of the gap in other places. GA: Well, this other way of viewing the last 30 years is as problematic as the first view. Also, in terms of periods, one has to It is problematic because, just for the distinguish the 1980s and 1990s, which had countries you mentioned, only Chile meets been rather bad for most of the global South, the characteristic of having trade and the late 1990s and early 2000s, where liberalization and shock therapies applied by just within China there has been a great a dictatorship. In China, though it may be improvement of living conditions. Zakaria considered a dictatorship, it certainly did not says “billions,” but in fact there have been introduce any shock therapy or rapid hundreds of millions of people uplifted from liberalization and privatization of the kind poverty, according to and as defined by the that was done in Chile and elsewhere. In World Bank. But almost all of them are other cases, these changes were introduced actually in China. So one has to look at what democratically. If you take the 1980s, it was has happened in China and ask if China has a period when Latin American dictatorships lifted hundreds of millions of people out of were in crisis and were displaced by poverty because it followed the advice of the democratic regimes, who then often United States. In my view, China has not introduced these changes in the 1990s. followed that advice. Certainly that’s also the case with the implementation of shock therapy in Russia KH: Let’s turn to another popular book under Yeltsin, where the country had moved about global development, Naomi Klein’s from a Soviet dictatorship to a The Shock Doctrine. Klein argues that free democratically elected leadership. So I think markets did not spread around the world the problem with that type of democratically and peacefully, and that characterization is that the introduction of countries such as Chile, Russia, China, and shock therapies and neoliberal prescriptions most recently, Iraq, were “shocked,” or occurred under diverse circumstances, since subjected to rapid and severe social in many cases the neoliberal changes dislocation as a result of political or occurred during the shift from authoritarian economic catastrophes. Afterwards, regimes to parliamentary democracies. international and local elites subsequently reengineered these societies based on 159 Journal of World-Systems Research In the case that matters most in terms of but also to an historical heritage that doesn’t positive results – that is, China – as Joseph exist elsewhere. Stiglitz and many others have pointed out, they did not follow the prescriptions of For example, two legacies have been crucial Washington at all. They were very gradual in the success of the Chinese reforms. One is and careful, issuing countermeasures to the revolutionary tradition that created very prevent massive unemployment, for equal conditions in the country. China did example. So, again, if we single out China, it not dispossess or destroy the peasantry, as is a case which doesn’t fit in either one of had happened in the Soviet Union, but these views. In fact, there is a convergence uplifted the peasantry through health and of views, between liberals and those on the educational improvements, which were left, which claims that China followed the major achievements before the reforms prescriptions that came out of Washington, began. So they had a large peasantry that whereas in fact they didn’t. So, in a way, supplied not just cheap labor but also large China is the exception that proves the rule masses of small-scale entrepreneurship who that the prescriptions that came out of mobilized this labor locally and translated it Washington in the 1980s and ‘90s were into the growth of the Chinese domestic disastrous rather than beneficial. market, which was crucial in generating the rates of growth that China has been KH: You’ve argued that the world has experiencing. moved from a Washington consensus towards a Beijing consensus, though you Another important legacy was that of the certainly didn’t coin those phrases yourself. late Imperial market economy that had What is the difference between the two, and involved peasants and artisans in widespread are you saying that the rise of China as an market exchanges but was not a capitalist economic power is a model that other market economy, in the sense that it did not countries can follow? lead to massive dispossession of the peasants. So these were characteristics of the GA: Well, the Chinese themselves are very labor force that were rather different than careful in not setting themselves up as a those produced by proletarianization, model. In some ways, the experience of specialization, and divisions of labor of the China is a model in the sense that market kind experienced by the West. These reforms have to be introduced very conditions exist in China because of legacies cautiously, gradually, and always with other that don’t exist elsewhere, nor can they be actions that counter the negative effects of reproduced. For example, in Southern liberalization. From this point of view, in a Africa, there was an extreme dispossession general sense it could be taken as a of the peasantry. prescription that is antithetical and opposite to that of the Washington consensus. So, there is an awareness that different However, unlike the Washington consensus, regions of the global South have different the so-called Beijing consensus goes against legacies and therefore policies have to be the idea that “one size fits all.” The Chinese tailored to these differences.
Recommended publications
  • 1 Introduction: Why Geopolitical Economy?
    1 INTRODUCTION: WHY GEOPOLITICAL ECONOMY? The owl of Minerva, Hegel once remarked, takes wing at dusk. Knowledge results from reflection after the tumult of the day. This gloomy view may be too sweeping, but it certainly applies to the multipolar world order. Influential figures began hailing it in the wake of the 2008 financial crisis and the Great Recession. The American president of the World Bank spoke of ‘a new, fast-evolving multi-polar world economy’ (World Bank, 2010). Veteran international financier George Soros predicted that ‘the current financial crisis is less likely to cause a global recession than a radical realignment of the global economy, with a relative decline of the US and the rise of China and other countries in the developing world’ (2008). However, the multipolar world order was much longer in the making. Developments of this magnitude simply don’t happen overnight even in a crisis (though, as we shall see, emerging multipolarity was a decisive factor in causing it), and this has important implications for prevailing understandings of the capitalist world order. Recent accounts stressed its economic unity: globalization conceived a world unified by markets alone while empire proposed one unified by the world’s most powerful – ‘hegemonic’ or ‘imperial’ (the terms tended to be used interchangeably) – state. They also assumed either that nation-states were not relevant to explaining the world order (globalization), or that only one, the United States, was (empire). We can call these views cosmopolitan, a term the Oxford English Dictionary defines as ‘not restricted to any one country or its inhabitants’ and ‘free from national limitations or attachments’.
    [Show full text]
  • Adam Smith in Beijing: Lineages of the Twenty-Frst Century
    Giovanni Arrighi. Adam Smith in Beijing: Lineages of the Twenty-first Century. London: Verso, 2007. 420 S. $35.00, cloth, ISBN 978-1-84467-104-5. Reviewed by Jan-Frederik Abbeloos Published on H-Soz-u-Kult (September, 2008) The Italian economist Giovanni Arrighi In 1994 Arrighi believed the American Centu‐ presents the sole-authored sequel to his 1994 The ry was drawing to a close. Following his own anal‐ Long Twentieth Century: money power and the ysis and the global ecological and economic limits origins of our time. In The Long Twentieth Centu‐ the capitalist economy is encountering, he fore‐ ry Arrighi in his own words “lumped” together saw three scenarios for the future. The frst op‐ the insights of Fernand Braudel, Adam Smith, Karl tion would be for the world to slip into the sort of Marx, Herni Pirenne , Max Weber, Joseph Schum‐ systemic chaos out of which capitalism emerged peter and Charles Tilly to present a macro-history some 600 years ago. In the second scenario the ex‐ of capitalist history that critically engaged with tent of the state-and war-making capabilities of Immanuel Wallerstein’s analyses of the Modern the United States and its European allies would World-System. The crux of Arrighi’s conceptual‐ create the frst true global empire. The third sce‐ ization was the assumption that the nature and nario is worth quoting: origins of capitalism should not be looked for in “[…] East Asian capital may come to occupy a property relations or institutional configurations commanding position in systemic processes of but in the changing relationship between the con‐ capital accumulation.
    [Show full text]
  • Giovanni Arrighi: Systemic Cycles of Accumulation, Hegemonic Transitions, and the Rise of China William I
    This article was downloaded by: [informa internal users] On: 15 November 2010 Access details: Access Details: [subscription number 755239602] Publisher Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House, 37- 41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK New Political Economy Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information: http://www.informaworld.com/smpp/title~content=t713439457 Giovanni Arrighi: Systemic Cycles of Accumulation, Hegemonic Transitions, and the Rise of China William I. Robinsona a Department of Sociology, University of California, Santa Barbara, USA First published on: 05 November 2010 To cite this Article Robinson, William I.(2010) 'Giovanni Arrighi: Systemic Cycles of Accumulation, Hegemonic Transitions, and the Rise of China', New Political Economy,, First published on: 05 November 2010 (iFirst) To link to this Article: DOI: 10.1080/13563467.2010.512657 URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/13563467.2010.512657 PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE Full terms and conditions of use: http://www.informaworld.com/terms-and-conditions-of-access.pdf This article may be used for research, teaching and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematic reproduction, re-distribution, re-selling, loan or sub-licensing, systematic supply or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden. The publisher does not give any warranty express or implied or make any representation that the contents will be complete or accurate or up to date. The accuracy of any instructions, formulae and drug doses should be independently verified with primary sources. The publisher shall not be liable for any loss, actions, claims, proceedings, demand or costs or damages whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with or arising out of the use of this material.
    [Show full text]
  • A Tribute to Giovanni Arrighi
    JOURNAL FÜR ENTWICKLUNGSPOLITIK herausgegeben vom Mattersburger Kreis für Entwicklungspolitik an den österreichischen Universitäten vol. XXVII 1–2011 GIOVANNI ARRIGHI: A Global Perspective Schwerpunktredaktion: Amy Austin-Holmes, Stefan Schmalz Inhaltsverzeichnis 4 Amy Austin-Holmes, Stefan Schmalz From Africa to Asia: The Intellectual Trajectory of Giovanni Arrighi 14 Samir Amin A Tribute to Giovanni Arrighi 25 Fortunata Piselli Reflections on Calabria: A Critique of the Concept of ‘Primitive Accumulation’ 44 Çaglar Keyder, Zafer Yenal Agrarian Transformation, Labour Supplies, and Proletarianization Processes in Turkey: A Historical Overview 72 Thomas Ehrlich Reifer Global Inequalities, Alternative Regionalisms and the Future of Socialism 95 Walden Bello China and the Global Economy: The Persistence of Export-Led Growth 113 Rezension 116 Editors of the Special Issue and Authors 119 Impressum Journal für Entwicklungspolitik XXVII 1-2011, S. 14-24 SAMIR AMIN A Tribute to Giovanni Arrighi 1. Giovanni Arrighi: a preeminent analyst of contemporary globalization Born in Italy, died on June 18, 2009 at the age of 71, Giovanni Arrighi was one of the most eminent critical analysts of the contemporary world system. Faced with arrest due to his support of the liberation movement in colonial Rhodesia, Giovanni went on to deepen his analysis of Africa’s dependency during his stay in Tanzania. He continued his work on the contemporary world system at the Fernand Braudel Center of SUNY-Bing- hamton in the United States, which was directed at that time by Immanuel Wallerstein, and then later at John Hopkins University in Baltimore. At the end of 1970, Giovanni Arrighi – along with André Gunder Frank, Immanuel Wallerstein and myself – believed that capitalism had entered a phase of systemic crisis, marked by the fall in growth rates in its dominant cores (with, as a result, the system never again returning to its former rates).
    [Show full text]
  • The Winding Paths of Capital
    giovanni arrighi THE WINDING PATHS OF CAPITAL Interview by David Harvey Could you tell us about your family background and your education? was born in Milan in 1937. On my mother’s side, my fam- ily background was bourgeois. My grandfather, the son of Swiss immigrants to Italy, had risen from the ranks of the labour aristocracy to establish his own factories in the early twentieth Icentury, manufacturing textile machinery and later, heating and air- conditioning equipment. My father was the son of a railway worker, born in Tuscany. He came to Milan and got a job in my maternal grand- father’s factory—in other words, he ended up marrying the boss’s daughter. There were tensions, which eventually resulted in my father setting up his own business, in competition with his father-in-law. Both shared anti-fascist sentiments, however, and that greatly influenced my early childhood, dominated as it was by the war: the Nazi occupation of Northern Italy after Rome’s surrender in 1943, the Resistance and the arrival of the Allied troops. My father died suddenly in a car accident, when I was 18. I decided to keep his company going, against my grandfather’s advice, and entered the Università Bocconi to study economics, hoping it would help me understand how to run the firm. The Economics Department was a neo- classical stronghold, untouched by Keynesianism of any kind, and no help at all with my father’s business. I finally realized I would have to close it down. I then spent two years on the shop-floor of one of my new left review 56 mar apr 2009 61 62 nlr 56 grandfather’s firms, collecting data on the organization of the production process.
    [Show full text]
  • Political Economy Paul Adler Marshall School of Business University of Southern California Los Angeles, CA, USA Email: [email protected] Version: Dec 29
    Political Economy Paul Adler Marshall School of Business University of Southern California Los Angeles, CA, USA Email: [email protected] Version: Dec 29. 2009 (draft entry for Mark Tadajewski, Pauline Maclaren, Martin Parker and Liz Parsons (eds), Key Concepts in Critical Management Studies, London: Sage, forthcoming) Definition “Political economy” refers to the combined and interacting effects of economic and political structures or processes, and by extension, to the scholarly study of this domain. The term originated in the 17th and 18th centuries to refer to economic policies of the nation-states that were then consolidating. The writings of that period (such as by the Physiocrats and Mercantalists) focused on taxes and trade policy. The meaning of the term was broadened in the 19th century to refer to the manifold ways in which capitalist economic structures and market processes influenced and were influenced by political power at local, national, and international levels. The great theorists of that period were Adam Smith, David Ricardo, Richard Malthus, John Stuart Mill, Karl Marx. Starting in the late 19th century, political economy as a scholarly field was increasing displaced by economics. This shift reflected the celebration of the market as an autonomous mechanism for spontaneous coordination that ostensibly neither required nor induced any political structuring. The displacement was facilitated by the development of increasingly elegant mathematical models; in contrast, the study of political economy is by nature more context
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter Eleven Theories of the Capitalist World-System Rémy Herrera
    Chapter Eleven Theories of the Capitalist World-System Rémy Herrera The national structures of capitalism operate and are reproduced locally in the rst instance, through a combination of a domestic market, where com- modities, capital and labour are mobile, and a corre- sponding set of state apparatuses. By contrast, what de nes the capitalist world-system is the dichotomy between the existence of a world market, integrated in all aspects except for labour (which is forced into an international quasi-immobility), and the absence of a single political order at a global level that is more than a multiplicity of state bodies governed by public international law and/or the violence of the balance of forces. It is the causes, mechanisms, and consequences of this asymmetry at work in the accu- mulation of capital, in terms of unequal relations of domination between nations and of exploitation between classes in particular, that the theoreticians of this capitalist world-system endeavour to con- ceptualise. The latter have in fact produced a com- prehensive theory whose object and concept is the modern world as a concrete socio-historical entity forming a system – that is to say, an assemblage (Greek systema), structured by complex relations of interdependence, of several elements of reality into a coherent, autonomous totality that situates them and gives them meaning. BIDET2_f12_208-224.indd 209 10/29/2007 4:45:22 PM 210 • Rémy Herrera Among the representatives of this intellectual current, I shall (to restrict myself to the essentials) select four major authors: Samir Amin, Immanuel Wallerstein, Giovanni Arrighi and André Gunder Frank.
    [Show full text]
  • Giovanni Arrighi
    giovanni arrighi Of the minds produced by the international left in the second half of the twentieth century, few have been the equal, in historical imagination, archi- tectonic scope and conceptual clarity, to Giovanni Arrighi, whose work will be read and reflected on for the rest of this century. We publish below a tribute to him from a pupil, Tom Reifer, which gives a measure of his achievement. A thinker of exceptional warmth, integrity and largeness of spirit, Arrighi drew on personal experience of struggles in both the Third and First Worlds—the movements for national liberation in Africa, and the great labour insurgencies of Italy—in the sixties, and subsequent deep engagement with the trajectory of the two leading powers of the present global order, America and China. His texts in nlr are so many landmarks in the history of the journal. Scanning one decade after another came ‘The Political Economy of Rhodesia’ in the mid sixties (nlr i/39); ‘Towards a Theory of Capitalist Crisis’ in the sev- enties (nlr i/111); the arresting paradoxes of ‘Marxist Century, American Century’ at the close of the eighties (nlr i/179); his famous analysis of ‘World Income Inequalities and the Future of Socialism’ in the nineties (nlr i/189); and his return to the fate of Africa in this decade (‘The African Crisis’, nlr 15), when ‘Political Economy of Global Turbulence’ (nlr 20) and ‘Hegemony Unravelling’ (nlr 32 and 33) became central parts of his last book, Adam Smith in Beijing. Personal friendship and political loyalty were unshake- able values for him.
    [Show full text]
  • The Global Market Giovanni Arrighi
    The Global Market Giovanni Arrighi Keywords: The global market under British hegemony. Crisis and belle epoque: the Edwardian era. The demise of the British-centered global market. The reconstruction of the global market under US hegemony. Crisis and belle epoque: the Reagan era. The future of the global market. y most accounts, the twentieth century has been one of the most revo- Blutionary periods in world history, not just politically but economically and socially as well. In one key respect, however, the end of the century resembles its beginning. The entire world appears to us, as it did a century ago, to be integrated in a single market in which states are said to have no choice but compete intensely with one another for increasingly mobile capi- tal. Over the last ten years this perception has translated into the notion of “globalization” as a new process driven by major technological advances in the transmission, storage and processing of information. As critics of the notion have pointed out, however, the newness of the railroad, the steamship and the automobile, of the telegraph, the radio and the telephone in their days was no less impressive than the newness of the so-called “information revolution” is today (Harvey, 1995). Even the “virtualization of economic activity” is not as new as it may appear at fi rst sight. A world-encompassing economy sharing close to real-time information fi rst came into existence not in the 1970s but in the 1870s, when a system of submarine telegraph cables began to integrate fi nancial and other major markets across the globe in a way not fundamentally different from today’s satellite-linked markets (Hirst and Thompson, 1996).
    [Show full text]
  • Postcolonial Cosmopolitanism: Making Place for Nationalism
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE Contents c provided165 by SOAS Research Online 6 Postcolonial Cosmopolitanism: Making Place for Nationalism Rahul Rao J å Cosmopolitanism, Communitarianism and the Subaltern his essay takes as its point of departure, the debate between Tcosmopolitanism and communitarianism in international normative theory. It expresses several dissatisfactions with this debate, criticizing its inattention to politics and history, its Eurocentrism, and the simplistic imageries of threat on which attitudes towards boundaries in the debate are premised. In attempting to remedy these problems, it recasts the figure of the subaltern that haunts this debate — hitherto imagined as a passive recipient of Western largesse — as an active agent struggling for emancipation, and contrasts the potentials of cosmopolitanism and communitarianism to function as vocabularies in which such struggles might be articulated. The chapter then turns to the writings of two proto-postcolonial thinkers — James Joyce and Rabindranath Tagore — who reject the conventional opposition between cosmopolitanism and communitarianism. Through a selective reading of their thought, it argues that rather than resolving the cosmopolitan/communitarian impasse, the tension between these normative worldviews running through their oeuvres, offers a protest sensibility that is better suited to the exigencies of subaltern struggle in the contemporary conjuncture. International normative theory has been the site of a vigorous debate on the scope of justice. Those who regard this as universal 166 ³ Rahul Rao — ‘cosmopolitans’ — weigh equally the claims of all individuals who would be affected by policies or institutional arrangements, out of a belief in the equal worth of humanity in all persons.1 Their critics are diverse, but one influential subset — ‘communitarians’ — argue that norms of justice can only arise from within bounded communities.
    [Show full text]
  • Globalization and Historical Macrosociology
    GLOBALIZATION AND HISTORICAL MACROSOCIOLOGY Giovanni Arrighi Published in Janet Abu-Lughod, ed., Sociology for the Twenty-First Century. Continuities and Cutting Edges. Chicago:Chicago University Press 2000, pp. 117-133. An earlier version of the paper was presented at the ASA/ISA North American Conference, "Millennial Milestone. The Heritage and Future of Sociology," Toronto, Canada, August 7-8, 1997. Globalization and Its Contents History continually makes untidy the neat conceptual frameworks and theoretical speculations with which we endeavor to understand the past and forecast the future of the world we live in. In our attempt to cope with the "chaos of existential judgements" (Max Weber's phrase) engendered by events and processes that challenge our understanding of the world, we tend to deny or exaggerate the novelty of what is actually happening. Denial leads to changes in the familiar meaning of words. Exaggeration leads to the coinage of new words of uncertain meaning. Either way, to paraphrase John Ruggie (1994, p. 553), "[t]imes of change are also times of confusion." Some twenty-to-thirty years ago the main source of confusion in the study of the global political economy was the persistent use of the term "imperialism" to designate tendencies that in key respects were antithetical to the tendencies that had been the object of classical theories of imperialism, both liberal and Marxist. In a critique of this anachronistic use of the term, I underscored how the establishment of US hegemony after the Second World War had dissolved the very explicandum of classical theories of imperialism, namely, the tendency of intercapitalist competition to translate into open and generalized warfare.
    [Show full text]
  • Postcolonial Cosmopolitanism: Making Place for Nationalism
    Contents c 165 6 Postcolonial Cosmopolitanism: Making Place for Nationalism Rahul Rao J å Cosmopolitanism, Communitarianism and the Subaltern his essay takes as its point of departure, the debate between Tcosmopolitanism and communitarianism in international normative theory. It expresses several dissatisfactions with this debate, criticizing its inattention to politics and history, its Eurocentrism, and the simplistic imageries of threat on which attitudes towards boundaries in the debate are premised. In attempting to remedy these problems, it recasts the figure of the subaltern that haunts this debate — hitherto imagined as a passive recipient of Western largesse — as an active agent struggling for emancipation, and contrasts the potentials of cosmopolitanism and communitarianism to function as vocabularies in which such struggles might be articulated. The chapter then turns to the writings of two proto-postcolonial thinkers — James Joyce and Rabindranath Tagore — who reject the conventional opposition between cosmopolitanism and communitarianism. Through a selective reading of their thought, it argues that rather than resolving the cosmopolitan/communitarian impasse, the tension between these normative worldviews running through their oeuvres, offers a protest sensibility that is better suited to the exigencies of subaltern struggle in the contemporary conjuncture. International normative theory has been the site of a vigorous debate on the scope of justice. Those who regard this as universal 166 ³ Rahul Rao — ‘cosmopolitans’ — weigh equally the claims of all individuals who would be affected by policies or institutional arrangements, out of a belief in the equal worth of humanity in all persons.1 Their critics are diverse, but one influential subset — ‘communitarians’ — argue that norms of justice can only arise from within bounded communities.
    [Show full text]