Corporate Managers, Agency Costs, and the Rise of Double Taxation

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Corporate Managers, Agency Costs, and the Rise of Double Taxation William & Mary Law Review Volume 44 (2002-2003) Issue 1 Article 4 October 2002 Corporate Managers, Agency Costs, and the Rise of Double Taxation Steven A. Bank Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.wm.edu/wmlr Part of the Business Organizations Law Commons, and the Tax Law Commons Repository Citation Steven A. Bank, Corporate Managers, Agency Costs, and the Rise of Double Taxation, 44 Wm. & Mary L. Rev. 167 (2002), https://scholarship.law.wm.edu/wmlr/vol44/iss1/4 Copyright c 2002 by the authors. This article is brought to you by the William & Mary Law School Scholarship Repository. https://scholarship.law.wm.edu/wmlr CORPORATE MANAGERS, AGENCY COSTS, AND THE RISE OF DOUBLE TAXATION STEVEN A. BANK* TABLE OF CONTENTS INTRODUCTION ....................................... 169 I. THE ORIGINS OF A SEPARATE CORPORATE INCOME TAX ..... 173 A. Civil War and Reconstruction ...................... 173 B. State Law Developments in the Taxation of Corporations ................................ 176 C. FederalAdoption of a Separate CorporateIncome Tax . 178 II. THE ADOPTION OF AN UNDISTRIBUTED PROFITS TAX ...... 183 A. Campaign of 1932 .............................. 183 B. 1936 and the Revival of the UndistributedProfits Tax ....................... 192 III. DOUBLE TAXATION AS A TOOL IN THE ATTACK ON THE UNDISTRIBUTED PROFITS TAX .................... 198 A. Prelude to the Revenue Act of 1936 ................. 198 B. The Campaign to Defeat the Tax in the Revenue Act of 1936 ............................ 204 1. H ouse ...................................... 204 2. Senate ..................................... 213 3. Conference .................................. 226 * Visiting Professor, UCLA School of Law (2002-2003); Associate Professor, Florida State University College of Law. B.A. 1991, University of Pennsylvania; J.D. 1994, University of Chicago. Thanks to Barbara Banoff, Joseph Dodge, Christopher Hanna, Carolyn Jones, Peter Oh, and Daniel Schneider for their comments and suggestions. Previous versions of this paper were presented at the 2001 Annual Meeting of the Central States Law School Association at Michigan State University-Detroit College of Law and at a Florida State University College of Law Faculty Colloquium. Thanks to participants for all of their comments. Thanks also to Paul Berk (Ph.D. candidate, FSU History Department) and Michael Barry (J.D. 2001) for their research assistance and to the archivists at the Hoover Institution Library and Archives at Stanford University and the Center for American History at the University of Texas for their hospitality and help in locating documents. This project benefitted from a summer research grant from Florida State University College of Law. 167 168 WILLIAM AND MARY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 44:167 C. The Rise and Fall of the UndistributedProfits Tax .... 229 1. The Aftermath of the Revenue Act of 1936 ........ 229 2. 1937 Economic Downturn ..................... 234 3. Revenue Act of 1938 .......................... 239 a. Subcommittee Plan ........................ 239 b. H ouse ................................... 242 c. Senate ................................... 246 d. Conference ............................... 252 4. Revenue Act of 1939 .......................... 255 CONCLUSION . ........................................ 259 2002] THE RISE OF DOUBLE TAXATION 169 INTRODUCTION Corporate income is currently taxed twice-first to the cor- poration when earned and a second time to the shareholder when distributed as dividends.1 This "double taxation" is a much reviled, but stubbornly persistent feature of our current system.2 Few, if any, commentators suggest that we would consciously adopt it if we were working from a blank slate,' and most openly recommend double taxation's demise.' Even the nineteenth-century movement to personify the corporation as a separate entity, which is often considered the foundation for the separate corporate income tax and, by implication, double taxation,5 was followed by an income tax act carefully crafted to avoid imposing a second layer of tax on 1. I.R.C. § 11 (2000) (imposing a tax on corporate income); id. §§ 301, 316 (imposing a shareholder-level tax on distributions in the form of dividends). This is sometimes referred to as the "classical" system because it still treats the corporation and shareholder as separate taxpayers rather than integrating the corporate and shareholder-level taxes. See Michael J. Graetz & Alvin C. Warren, Jr., Integration of Corporate and Individual Income Taxes: An Introduction,84 TAX NOTES 1767, 1768 (1999). As Graetz and Warren point out, the classical system does not always result in double taxation. For example, corporate income is not taxed twice when a shareholder is exempt from tax or when corporate income is paid out as deductible interest payments. In fact, it is not even taxed once when it is paid out as deductible interest to a foreign or other tax-exempt holder of corporate debt. Id. at 1768. 2. See, e.g., CHARLES E. MCLURE, JR., MUST CORPORATE INCOME BE TAXED TwiCE? 2-3 (1979); Alvin Warren, The Relation andIntegration of Individual andCorporate Income Taxes, 94 HARV. L. REV. 719, 720 (1981). 3. For one of the few defenses of double taxation, see Jeffrey L. Kwall, The Uncertain Case Against the Double Taxation of CorporateIncome, 68 N.C. L. REv. 613 (1990) (arguing that double taxation protects the progressivity of the income tax). 4. See AMERICAN LAW INSITUTE, FEDERAL INCOME TAX PROJECT- INTEGRATION OF THE INDIVIDUAL AND CORPORATE INCOME TAXES - REPORTER'S STUDY OF CORPORATE TAx INTEGRATION (1993); U.S. DEP T OF TREAStmY, INTEGRATION OF THE INDIVIDUAL AND CORPORATE TAX SYSTEMS: TAXING BUSINESS INCOME ONCE (1992); Joseph M. Dodge, A Combined Mark.to-Market and Pass-Through Corporate-ShareholderIntegration Proposal, 50 TAX L. REV. 265 (1995); John K McNulty, CorporateIncome Tax Reform in the United States: Proposals for Integration of the Corporate and Individual Income Taxes, and InternationalAspects, 12 INTL TAX & Bus. L. 161 (1994); George K. Yin, Corporate Tax Integrationand the Search for the PragmaticIdeal, 47 TAX L. REV. 431 (1992). 5. See, e.g., AMERICAN LAW INSTITUTE, FEDERAL INCOME TAX PROJECT, TAXATION OF PRIVATE BUSINESS ENTERUISES: REPOltTER'S STUDY 35-36 (1999); Maijorie E. Kornhauser, CorporateRegulation and the Originsof the CorporateIncome Tax, 66 IND. L.J. 53,136 (1990); cf. RICHARD GOODE, THE CORPORATION INCOME TAX 24-25 (1951) ("In the legal sense, of course, the corporate and individual income taxes do not result in double taxation. The corporation and its stockholders are different legal persons and have separate incomes.*). WILLIAM AND MARY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 44:167 corporate income.6 Not until 1936 was corporate income fully subject to two layers of tax. Double taxation's origins, therefore, have remained a mystery for modem observers. This Article seeks to resolve this mystery by examining the circumstances leading to the imposition of the full double tax in 1936. Although the corporate-level tax traces its roots to the nineteenth century,7 and the corporate and shareholder-level taxes have coexisted since the first post-Sixteenth Amendment revenue act was adopted in 1913," double taxation was at least partially or fully alleviated during the early years of the income tax. In the Revenue Act of 1936,' however, President Roosevelt introduced a radical plan to combat corporate "hoarding" of earnings by replacing the corporate income tax with an undistributed profits tax and a repeal of the exemption for dividends from the "normal" individual income tax.' If distributed as dividends, corporate income would only be subject to the individual income tax. 1 If retained, however, corporate income would be subject to a punitive undistributed profits tax and, upon distribution in later years, the individual income tax as well.' Managers bitterly fought the proposal, claiming that its coercive undistributed profits tax constituted a dangerous and unwarranted governmental interference with the operation of their businesses." As part of an ill-fated compromise, Congress retained the corporate income tax, along with a more 6. See Tariff Act of 1894, ch. 349, § 28,28 Stat. 509,554. For a more complete description of the circumstances giving rise to the adoption of the first separate corporate income tax, and a refutation of the traditional view that the separate corporate income tax arose because of developments in entity theory, see Steven A. Bank, Entity Theory as Myth in the Origins of the CorporateIncome Tax, 43 WM. & MARY L. REV. 447, 462 (2001). 7. See Bank, supra note 6, at 462. 8. Tariff Act of 1913, ch. 16, 38 Stat. 114. 9. Revenue Act of 1936, Pub. L. No. 74-740, 49 Stat. 1648. 10. At the time, all individual income was subject to a *normal,* or base flat rate tax. When income reached a certain point, an additional surtax was applied at rogressive rates. Dividends were exempt from the normal tax, but not the surtax rates. See infra text accompanying notes 58-73. 11. See Revenue Act of 1936, Pub. L. No. 74-740, 49 Stat. 1648. 12. See id. 13. Corporations had been subject to an accumulated earnings tax since the first post- Sixteenth Amendment income tax in 1913, but it only applied in the event that a corporation retained income with the purpose of evading the high surtax rates. This intent requirement was difficult to prove. Under Roosevelt's proposal, by contrast, the undistributed profits tax applied regardless of the purpose for the retention. See infra text accompanying notes 170-7
Recommended publications
  • A Brief Description of Federal Taxes
    A BRIEF DESCRIFTION OF FEDERAL TAXES ON CORPORATIONS SINCE i86i WMUAu A. SU. ND* The cost to the federal government of financing the Civil War created a need for increased revenue, and Congress in seeking new sources tapped theretofore un- touched corporate and individual profits. The Act of July x, x862, amending the Act of August 5, x86i, is the first law under which any federal income tax was collected and is considered to be largely the basis of our present system of income taxation. The tax acts of the Civil War period contained provisions imposing graduated taxes upon the gain, profits, or income of every person2 and providing that corporate profits, whether divided or not, should be taxed to the stockholders. Certain specified corporations, such as banks, insurance companies and transportation companies, were taxed at the rate of 5%, and their stockholders were not required to include in income their pro rata share of the profits. There were several tax acts during and following the War, but a description of the Act of 1864 will serve to show the general extent of the coiporate taxes of that period. The tax or "duty" was imposed upon all persons at the rate of 5% of the amount of gains, profits and income in excess of $6oo and not in excess of $5,000, 7Y2/ of the amount in excess of $5,ooo and not in excess of -$o,ooo, and io% of the amount in excess of $Sxooo.O This tax was continued through the year x87i, but in the last two years of its existence was reduced to 2/l% upon all income.
    [Show full text]
  • The Disclosure of State Corporate Income Tax Data: Turning the Clock Back to the Future Richard Pomp University of Connecticut School of Law
    University of Connecticut OpenCommons@UConn Faculty Articles and Papers School of Law Spring 1993 The Disclosure of State Corporate Income Tax Data: Turning the Clock Back to the Future Richard Pomp University of Connecticut School of Law Follow this and additional works at: https://opencommons.uconn.edu/law_papers Part of the Taxation-Federal Commons, and the Taxation-State and Local Commons Recommended Citation Pomp, Richard, "The Disclosure of State Corporate Income Tax Data: Turning the Clock Back to the Future" (1993). Faculty Articles and Papers. 121. https://opencommons.uconn.edu/law_papers/121 +(,121/,1( Citation: 22 Cap. U. L. Rev. 373 1993 Content downloaded/printed from HeinOnline (http://heinonline.org) Mon Aug 15 17:19:23 2016 -- Your use of this HeinOnline PDF indicates your acceptance of HeinOnline's Terms and Conditions of the license agreement available at http://heinonline.org/HOL/License -- The search text of this PDF is generated from uncorrected OCR text. -- To obtain permission to use this article beyond the scope of your HeinOnline license, please use: https://www.copyright.com/ccc/basicSearch.do? &operation=go&searchType=0 &lastSearch=simple&all=on&titleOrStdNo=0198-9693 THE DISCLOSURE OF STATE CORPORATE INCOME TAX DATA: TURNING THE CLOCK BACK TO THE FUTURE RICHARD D. POMP* INTRODUCTION .............................................. 374 I. THE DISCLOSURE OF INCOME TAX INFORMATION AT THE FEDERAL LEVEL: AN HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE .......... 378 A. The Civil War Income Taxes: 1861-1872 ............... 379 B. The 1894 Income Tax ................................ 384 C. The Tariff Act of 1909 ............................... 386 D . 1913-1923 .......................................... 389 E. The 1924 and 1926 Acts ............................... 391 F. The Pink Slip Provisions: 1934-1935 ................
    [Show full text]
  • Ways and Means Committee's Request for the Former President's
    (Slip Opinion) Ways and Means Committee’s Request for the Former President’s Tax Returns and Related Tax Information Pursuant to 26 U.S.C. § 6103(f )(1) Section 6103(f )(1) of title 26, U.S. Code, vests the congressional tax committees with a broad right to receive tax information from the Department of the Treasury. It embod- ies a long-standing judgment of the political branches that the tax committees are uniquely suited to receive such information. The committees, however, cannot compel the Executive Branch to disclose such information without satisfying the constitutional requirement that the information could serve a legitimate legislative purpose. In assessing whether requested information could serve a legitimate legislative purpose, the Executive Branch must give due weight to Congress’s status as a co-equal branch of government. Like courts, therefore, Executive Branch officials must apply a pre- sumption that Legislative Branch officials act in good faith and in furtherance of legit- imate objectives. When one of the congressional tax committees requests tax information pursuant to section 6103(f )(1), and has invoked facially valid reasons for its request, the Executive Branch should conclude that the request lacks a legitimate legislative purpose only in exceptional circumstances. The Chairman of the House Ways and Means Committee has invoked sufficient reasons for requesting the former President’s tax information. Under section 6103(f )(1), Treasury must furnish the information to the Committee. July 30, 2021 MEMORANDUM OPINION FOR THE ACTING GENERAL COUNSEL DEPARTMENT OF THE TREASURY The Internal Revenue Code requires the Department of the Treasury (“Treasury”) and the Internal Revenue Service (“IRS”) to keep tax returns and related information confidential, 26 U.S.C.
    [Show full text]
  • RESTORING the LOST ANTI-INJUNCTION ACT Kristin E
    COPYRIGHT © 2017 VIRGINIA LAW REVIEW ASSOCIATION RESTORING THE LOST ANTI-INJUNCTION ACT Kristin E. Hickman* & Gerald Kerska† Should Treasury regulations and IRS guidance documents be eligible for pre-enforcement judicial review? The D.C. Circuit’s 2015 decision in Florida Bankers Ass’n v. U.S. Department of the Treasury puts its interpretation of the Anti-Injunction Act at odds with both general administrative law norms in favor of pre-enforcement review of final agency action and also the Supreme Court’s interpretation of the nearly identical Tax Injunction Act. A 2017 federal district court decision in Chamber of Commerce v. IRS, appealable to the Fifth Circuit, interprets the Anti-Injunction Act differently and could lead to a circuit split regarding pre-enforcement judicial review of Treasury regulations and IRS guidance documents. Other cases interpreting the Anti-Injunction Act more generally are fragmented and inconsistent. In an effort to gain greater understanding of the Anti-Injunction Act and its role in tax administration, this Article looks back to the Anti- Injunction Act’s origin in 1867 as part of Civil War–era revenue legislation and the evolution of both tax administrative practices and Anti-Injunction Act jurisprudence since that time. INTRODUCTION .................................................................................... 1684 I. A JURISPRUDENTIAL MESS, AND WHY IT MATTERS ...................... 1688 A. Exploring the Doctrinal Tensions.......................................... 1690 1. Confused Anti-Injunction Act Jurisprudence .................. 1691 2. The Administrative Procedure Act’s Presumption of Reviewability ................................................................... 1704 3. The Tax Injunction Act .................................................... 1707 B. Why the Conflict Matters ....................................................... 1712 * Distinguished McKnight University Professor and Harlan Albert Rogers Professor in Law, University of Minnesota Law School.
    [Show full text]
  • The Joint Committee on Taxation and Codification of the Tax Laws
    The Joint Committee on Taxation and Codification of the Tax Laws George K. Yin Edwin S. Cohen Distinguished Professor of Law and Taxation University of Virginia Former Chief of Staff, Joint Committee on Taxation February 2016 Draft prepared for the United States Capitol Historical Society’s program on The History and Role of the Joint Committee: the Joint Committee and Tax History Comments welcome. THE UNITED STATES CAPITOL HISTORICAL SOCIETY THE JCT@90 WASHINGTON, DC FEBRUARY 25, 2016 The Joint Committee on Taxation and Codification of the Tax Laws George K. Yin* February 11, 2016 preliminary draft [Note to conference attendees and other readers: This paper describes the work of the staff of the Joint Committee on Internal Revenue Taxation (JCT)1 that led to codification of the tax laws in 1939. I hope eventually to incorporate this material into a larger project involving the “early years” of the JCT, roughly the period spanning the committee’s creation in 1926 and the retirement of Colin Stam in 1964. Stam served on the staff for virtually this entire period; he was first hired (on a temporary basis) in 1927 as assistant counsel, became staff counsel in 1929, and then served as Chief of Staff from 1938 until 1964. He is by far the longest‐serving Chief of Staff the committee has ever had. The conclusions in this draft are still preliminary as I have not yet completed my research. I welcome any comments or questions.] Possibly the most significant accomplishment of the JCT and its staff during the committee’s “early years” was the enactment of the Internal Revenue Code of 1939.
    [Show full text]
  • Report No. 82-156 Gov Major Acts of Congress And
    REPORT NO. 82-156 GOV MAJOR ACTS OF CONGRESS AND TREATIES APPROVED BY THE SENATE 1789-1980 Christopher Dell Stephen W. Stathis Analysts in American National Governent Government Division September 1982 CONmGHnItNA^l JK 1000 B RE filmH C SE HVICA^^ ABSTRACT During the nearly two centuries since the framing of the Constitution, more than 41,000 public bills have been approved by Congress, submitted to the President for his approval and become law. The seven hundred or so acts summarized in this compilation represent the major acts approved by Congress in its efforts to determine national policies to be carried out by the executive branch, to authorize appropriations to carry out these policies, and to fulfill its responsibility of assuring that such actions are being carried out in accordance with congressional intent. Also included are those treaties considered to be of similar importance. An extensive index allows each entry in this work to be located with relative ease. The authors wish to credit Daphine Lee, Larry Nunley, and Lenora Pruitt for the secretarial production of this report. CONTENTS ABSTRACT.................................................................. 111 CONGRESSES: 1st (March 4, 1789-March 3, 1791)..................................... 3 2nd (October 24, 1791-March 2, 1793)................................... 7 3rd (December 2, 1793-March 3, 1795).................................. 8 4th (December 7, 1795-March 3, 1797).................................. 9 5th (May 15, 1797-March 3, 1799)....................................... 11 6th (December 2, 1799-March 3, 1801)................................... 13 7th (December 7, 1801-Marh 3, 1803)................................... 14 8th (October 17, 1803-March 3, 1805)....... ........................... 15 9th (December 2, 1805-March 3, 1807)................................... 16 10th (October 26, 1807-March 3, 1809)..................................
    [Show full text]
  • Real Property Like-Kind Exchanges Since 1921, the Internal Revenue
    Real Property Like-kind Exchanges Since 1921, the Internal Revenue Code has recognized that the exchange of one property held for investment or business use for another property of a like-kind results in no change in the economic position of the taxpayer and therefore should not result in the imposition of tax. This concept is codified today in section 1031 of the Internal Revenue Code with respect to the exchange of real and personal property, and it is one of many nonrecognition provisions in the Code that provide for deferral of gains. The Obama Administration’s fiscal year 2015 budget targets section 1031 by substantially repealing the provision with respect to real property by limiting the amount of gain that may be deferred to $1 million annually. This proposal could have a significant negative impact on the real estate sector with real implications for the broader economy. Background The original like-kind exchange rule goes all the way back to the Revenue Act of 1921 when Congress created section 202(c), which allowed investors to exchange securities and property that did not have a “readily realized market value.” This rather broad rule was eliminated in 1924 and replaced with section 112(b) in the Revenue Act of 1928, which permitted the deferral of gain on the like-kind exchange of similar property. With limited exceptions, generally related to narrowing the provision, Congress has largely left the like-kind rule unchanged since 1928.1 Section 1031 permits taxpayers to exchange assets used for investment or business purposes for other like-kind assets without the recognition of gain.
    [Show full text]
  • Legal Status of Capital Gains
    LEGAL STATUS OF CAPITAL GAINS PREPARED BY THE STAFF OF THE JOINT COMMITTEE ON INTERNAL REVENUE TAXATION DECEMBER 4, 1959 UNITED STATES GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE 48572 WASHINGTON : 1959 J0810-59 LEGAL STATUS OF CAPITAL GAINS HISTORICAL PERIOD PRIOR TO THE 16TH AMENDMENT The power of the CQngress to subject capital gains to an income tax is now fully established by decisions of the Suprenle Court. Even in our first inconle tax statute (act of 1861, 12 Stat. 292) Congress used language broad enough to warrant the taxation of "annual cap­ ital gains." This first act levied on income tax to be paid upon the "annual income" deriyecl fronl certain sources, including income "deriyed from an:r kind of property" and contained a catchall provi­ sion s,,~eeping in "income derived fronl any other source whatever" with certain exceptions having no relation to capital gains. This act was neYer put into effect and was superseded by- the act of 1862 (12 Stat. 432), ,,~hich was similar in this respect to the 1861 act except that the basis of the tax was changed fronl "annual income" to the longer nhrase "annual gains, profits, or income." It \vas not until the act of 1864 (13 Stat. 223) that income derived fronl sales of prop­ erty was specifically mentioned. This last act contained the same general definition of income referred to in the prior acts, with an additional proviso- that net profits realized by sales of real estate purchased within the year for which income is estimated, shall be chargeable as income; and losses on sales of real estate purchased within the year for which income is estimated, shall be deducted from the income of such year.
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Mobility Behaviors Due to Earned Income Tax Credit Policy: a Case Study of a Southern California Population
    Pepperdine University Pepperdine Digital Commons Theses and Dissertations 2013 Economic mobility behaviors due to earned income tax credit policy: a case study of a southern California population Eugene J. Anton Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.pepperdine.edu/etd Recommended Citation Anton, Eugene J., "Economic mobility behaviors due to earned income tax credit policy: a case study of a southern California population" (2013). Theses and Dissertations. 415. https://digitalcommons.pepperdine.edu/etd/415 This Dissertation is brought to you for free and open access by Pepperdine Digital Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Theses and Dissertations by an authorized administrator of Pepperdine Digital Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected], [email protected], [email protected]. i Pepperdine University Graduate School of Education and Psychology ECONOMIC MOBILITY BEHAVIORS DUE TO EARNED INCOME TAX CREDIT POLICY: A CASE STUDY OF A SOUTHERN CALIFORNIA POPULATION A dissertation submitted in partial satisfaction of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Education in Organizational Leadership by Eugene J. Anton November, 2013 Kent Rhodes, Ed.D. – Dissertation Chairperson ii This dissertation, written by Eugene J. Anton under the guidance of a Faculty Committee and approved by its members, has been submitted to and accepted by the Graduate Faculty in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF EDUCATION Doctoral Committee: Kent Rhodes, Ed.D., Chairperson Leo Mallette, Ed.D. James Dellaneve, Ed.D. iii © Copyright by Eugene J. Anton (2013) All Rights Reserved iv TABLE OF CONTENTS Page TABLE OF CONTENTS ............................................................................................................... iv LIST OF TABLES ........................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Table of Contents
    Table of Contents Preface ..................................................................................................... ix Introductory Notes to Tables ................................................................. xi Chapter A: Selected Economic Statistics ............................................... 1 A1. Resident Population of the United States ............................................................................3 A2. Resident Population by State ..............................................................................................4 A3. Number of Households in the United States .......................................................................6 A4. Total Population by Age Group............................................................................................7 A5. Total Population by Age Group, Percentages .......................................................................8 A6. Civilian Labor Force by Employment Status .......................................................................9 A7. Gross Domestic Product, Net National Product, and National Income ...................................................................................................10 A8. Gross Domestic Product by Component ..........................................................................11 A9. State Gross Domestic Product...........................................................................................12 A10. Selected Economic Measures, Rates of Change...............................................................14
    [Show full text]
  • International Tax Policy for the 21St Century
    NFTC1a Volume1_part2Chap1-5.qxd 12/17/01 4:23 PM Page 147 The NFTC Foreign Income Project: International Tax Policy for the 21st Century Part Two Relief of International Double Taxation NFTC1a Volume1_part2Chap1-5.qxd 12/17/01 4:23 PM Page 148 NFTC1a Volume1_part2Chap1-5.qxd 12/17/01 4:23 PM Page 149 Origins of the Foreign Tax Credit Chapter 1 Origins of the Foreign Tax Credit I. Introduction The United States’ current system for taxing international income was creat- ed during the period from 1918 through 1928.1 From the introduction of 149 the income tax (in 1913 for individuals and in 1909 for corporations) until 1918, foreign taxes were deducted in the same way as any other business expense.2 In 1918, the United States enacted the foreign tax credit,3 a unilat- eral step taken fundamentally to redress the unfairness of “double taxation” of foreign-source income. By way of contrast, until the 1940s, the United Kingdom allowed a credit only for foreign taxes paid within the British 1 For further description and analysis of this formative period of U.S. international income tax policy, see Michael J. Graetz & Michael M. O’Hear, The ‘Original Intent’ of U.S. International Taxation, 46 DUKE L.J. 1021, 1026 (1997) [hereinafter “Graetz & O’Hear”]. The material in this chapter is largely taken from this source. 2 The reasoning behind the international tax aspects of the 1913 Act is difficult to discern from the historical sources. One scholar has concluded “it is quite likely that Congress gave little or no thought to the effect of the Revenue Act of 1913 on the foreign income of U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • The Revenue Act of 1934
    March, 1935 THE REVENUE ACT OF 1934 GEORGE GRAYSON TYLER t AND JOHN P. OHL X Congress, probably inspired by the disclosures of the investigations of the Banking and Currency Committee, passed House Resolution 183, on June 9, 1933, thereby authorizing the Ways and Means Committee to in- vestigate methods of preventing the evasion and avoidance of taxes, means of simplifying the revenue laws and possible new sources of revenue. Pur- suant to this Resolution, a Subcommittee of the Committee on \Ways and Means conducted an inquiry prior to the convening of the second session of the 73d Congress. The Subcommittee filed "A Preliminary Report" ' on December 4, 1933, upon the subjects, of tax avoidance, evasion and sim- plification. In response to the Subcommittee's recommendations, the then Acting Secretary of the Treasury, Henry Morgenthau, Jr., issued a state- ment 2 differing in many important particulars from the conclusions reached by the Subcommittee. As a result of the above investigations, H. R. 7835 was introduced in the House and referred to the Committee on Ways and Means. After extensive hearings 3 the bill was reported out with amendments by the Com- 4 mittee and a report was submitted thereon. On February 21, 1934, the House passed the bill with minor committee amendments. 5 Then, having been introduced in the Senate, the bill was referred to the Finance Com- mittee, which, after further hearings,0 reported it 7 with substantial amend- ments. Further material changes were made on the floor of the Senate s before passage. Thereafter, the Conference Committee on the disagreeing votes of the two Houses made its recommendations reconciling the differ- j- Formerly assistant to Professor Roswell Magill, former assistant to the Secretary of the Treasury; member of the New York Bar.
    [Show full text]