Richard Mcelreath

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Richard Mcelreath Curriculum Vitae: Richard McElreath Personal Information Address Department of Anthropology University of California{Davis One Shields Avenue Davis, CA 95616, USA Telephone (530) 752-2660 Fax (530) 752-8885 Email [email protected] WWW arbeit.ucdavis.edu/mcelreath/ Born April 18, 1973 in Landstuhl, Germany Citizenship United States Education and Employment July 2006{now Associate Professor, Department of Anthropology, University of California, Davis 2002{2006 Assistant Professor, Department of Anthropology, University of California, Davis 2001{2002 Post-doctoral researcher, Center for Adaptive Behavior and Cognition, Max Planck Institute for Human Development, Berlin 2001 Ph.D. Anthropology, University of California, Los Angeles Languages Fluent spoken and written modern standard Swahili; some Faroese Professional Activities 2007{ Strategic Planning Committee, UCD Letters and Science 2007{ Field researcher, AHRC Culture and the Mind project 2006{ Trainer, CLIMB (Collaborative Learning at the Intersection of Math and Biol- ogy) undergraduate training program, UC Davis 2006{ Member and PhD advisor, Population Biology Graduate Group, UC Davis 2004{ Chair, Human Ecology Area of Emphasis, Graduate Group in Ecology, UC Davis 2002{ Member, Animal Behavior Graduate Group, UC Davis 2001{ Member, Graduate Group in Ecology, UC Davis 1 Publications PDF copies of most of my publications are available on my website, at http://arbeit.ucdavis.edu/mcelreath/ Book Richard McElreath and Robert Boyd, Mathematical Models of Social Evolution: A Guide for the Perplexed. University of Chicago Press, 2007. Articles Frank W. Marlowe, J. Colette Berbesque, Abigail Barr, Clark Barrett, Alexan- der Bolyanatz, Juan Camilo Cardenas, Jean Ensminger, Michael Gurven, Ed- wins Gwako, Joseph Henrich, Natalie Henrich, Carolyn Lesorogol, Richard McElreath, and David Tracer. More `altruistic' punishment in larger societies. Proceedings of the Royal Society B, 275:587{590, 2008. C Efferson, R Lalive, P J Richerson, R McElreath, and M Lubell. Conformists and mavericks: The empirics of frequency-dependent cultural transmission. Evolution and Human Behavior, 29:56{64, 2008. Richard McElreath and Pontus Strimling. When natural selection favors learn- ing from parents. Current Anthropology, in press. Charles Efferson, Masanori Takezawa, and Richard McElreath. New methods in quantitative ethnography: Economic experiments and variation in the price of equality. Current Anthropology, 48:912{919, 2007. C Cordes, P J Richerson, R McElreath, and P. Strimling. A naturalistic ap- proach to the theory of the firm: The role of cooperation. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, in press. L. Newson, T. Postmes, S. E. G. Lea, P. J. Richerson, and R. McElreath. Influences on communication about reproduction: The cultural evolution of low fertility. Evolution and Human Behavior, 28:199{210, 2007. C. T. Dawes, J. H. Fowler, T. Johnson, R. McElreath, and O. Smirnov. Egali- tarian motives in humans. Nature, 446:794{796, 2007. Charles Efferson, Peter J. Richerson, Richard McElreath, Mark Lubell, Ed Ed- sten, Timothy M. Waring, Brian Paciotti, and William Baum. Learning, pro- ductivity, noise: An experimental study of cultural transmission on the Bolivian Altiplano. Evolution and Human Behavior, 28:11{17, 2007. Richard McElreath and Pontus Strimling. How noisy information and individual asymmetries can make "personality" an adaptation: A simple model. Animal Behaviour, 72:1135{1139, 2006. Joseph Henrich, Richard McElreath, Abigail Barr, Jean Ensminger, Clark Bar- rett, Alexander Bolyanatz, Juan Camilo Cardenas, Michael Gurven, Edwins Gwako, Natalie Henrich, Carolyn Lesorogol, Frank Marlowe, David Tracer, and John Ziker. Costly punishment across human societies. Science, 312:1767{1770, 2006. 2 Robert Bettinger, Bruce Winterhalder, and Richard McElreath. A simple model of technological intensification. Journal of Archaeological Science, 33(4):538{ 545, 2006. Judy Stamps, Richard McElreath, and Perri Eason. Alternative models of conspecific attraction in flies and crabs. Behavioral Ecology, 16:974{980, 2005. Richard McElreath, Mark Lubell, Peter J. Richerson, Timothy Waring, William Baum, Edward Edsten, Charles Efferson, and Brian Paciotti. Applying evolu- tionary models to the laboratory study of social learning. Evolution and Human Behavior, 26:483{508, 2005. Joseph Henrich, Robert Boyd, Samuel Bowles, Colin Camerer, Ernst Fehr, Herb Gintis, Richard McElreath, Michael Alvard, Abigail Barr, Jean Ensminger, Na- talie Smith Henrich, Kim Hill, Francisco Gil-White, Michael Gurven, Frank Marlowe, John Q. Patton, and David Tracer. Economic man in cross-cultural perspective: Behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 28:795{855, 2005. Richard McElreath. Social learning and the maintenance of cultural variation: An evolutionary model and data from East Africa. American Anthropologist, 106(2):308{321, 2004. Joseph Henrich and Richard McElreath. The evolution of cultural evolution. Evolutionary Anthropology, 12:123{135, 2003. Richard McElreath, Robert Boyd, and Peter J. Richerson. Shared norms and the evolution of ethnic markers. Current Anthropology, 44(1):122{129, 2003. Richard McElreath. Reputation and the evolution of conflict. Journal of The- oretical Biology, 220(3):345{357, 2003. Joseph Henrich and Richard McElreath. Are peasants risk averse decision- makers? Current Anthropology, 43(1):172{181, 2002. Joseph Soltis and Richard McElreath. Can females gain additional paternal investment by mating with multiple males? a game theoretic approach. The American Naturalist, 158(5):1519{529, 2001. Joseph Henrich, Robert Boyd, Samuel Bowles, Colin Camerer, Ernst Fehr, Herb Gintis, and Richard McElreath. In search of homo oeconomicus: Behavioral experiments in 15 small scale societies. American Economic Review, 91(2):73{ 78, 2001. Chapters Richard McElreath, Robert Boyd, Gerd Gigerenzer, Andreas Gl¨ockner, Peter Hammerstein, Robert Kurzban, Stefan Magen, Peter J. Richerson, Arthur Rob- son, and Jeffery R. Stevens. Individual decision making and the evolutionary roots of institutions. In C Engel and W Singer, editors, Better Than Con- scious? Implications for Performance and Institutional Analysis, Str¨ungmann Forum Report 1, chapter 15, pages 302{318. MIT Press, in press. 3 J. Henrich and R. McElreath. Dual inheritance theory: The evolution of human cultural capacities and cultural evolution. In R. Dunbar and L. Barrett, editors, Oxford Handbook of Evolutionary Psychology, chapter 38. Oxford Univ Press, 2007. R. McElreath and J. Henrich. Modeling cultural evolution. In R. Dunbar and L. Barrett, editors, Oxford Handbook of Evolutionary Psychology, chapter 39. Oxford Univ Press, 2007. J. Eerkens, R. L. Bettinger, and R. McElreath. Cultural transmission, phylo- genetics, and the archaeological record. In C. Lipo, M. J. O'Brien, M. Collard, and S. J. Shennan, editors, Mapping Our Ancestors, pages 169{183. Aldine- Transaction, 2006. R. McElreath, T.H. Clutton-Brock, E. Fehr, D.M.T. Fessler, E.H. Hagen, P. Hammerstein, M. Kosfeld, M. Milinski, J. Silk, J. Tooby, and M.I. Wilson. The role of cognition and emotion in cooperation. In P. Hammerstein, editor, The Genetic and Cultural Evolution of Cooperation, pages 125{152. MIT Press, Cambridge, 2003. R. McElreath. Community structure, mobility and the strength of norms in an african society, the sangu of tanzania. In J. Henrich, R. Boyd, S. Bowles, C. Camerer, E. Fehr, and H. Gintis, editors, Foundations of Human Social- ity: Ethnography and Experiments in 15 Small-scale Societies, pages 335{355. Oxford University Press, Oxford, 2004. R. McElreath and C. Camerer. Appendix: Estimating risk-aversion. In J. Hen- rich, R. Boyd, S. Bowles, C. Camerer, E. Fehr, and H. Gintis, editors, Foun- dations of Human Sociality: Ethnography and Experiments in 15 Small-scale Societies, pages 436{438. Oxford University Press, Oxford, 2004. J. Henrich, R. Boyd, S. Bowles, C.F. Camerer, E. Fehr, H. Gintis, and R. McEl- reath. Overview and synthesis. In J. Henrich, R. Boyd, S. Bowles, C. Camerer, E. Fehr, and H. Gintis, editors, Foundations of Human Sociality: Ethnography and Experiments in 15 Small-scale Societies, pages 8{54. Oxford University Press, Oxford, 2004. Comments Richard McElreath, Barney Luttbeg, Sean P. Fogarty, Tomas Brodin, and An- drew Sih. Communication arising: Evolution of animal personalities. Nature, 450:E5{E6, 2007. R. McElreath. Perspectives on diamond's collapse: How societies choose to fail or succeed. Current Anthropology, 46:S71{S90, 2005. Gerd Gigerenzer and Richard McElreath. Social intelligence in games. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 159(1):188{194, 2003. Joseph Henrich and Richard McElreath. On risk-prone peasants. Current An- thropology, 43(5):787{789, 2002. 4 Grants and Awards 2007 Elected 2007{2012 UCD Chancellor's Fellow, $25,000 research award. 2005 Small grant in aid of research, Committee on Research, UC Davis, $2000. 2005 Studying cultural dynamics in laboratory microsocieties, NSF, ($140,000; Co- PIs Peter J. Richerson and Mark Lubell) 2004 Empirical Implications of Theoretical Models: Studying cultural evolution in laboratory microsocieties, NSF, ($80,000; Co-PIs Peter J. Richerson and Mark Lubell) 2003 Junior faculty research improvement grant, $3000. 2002-2005 NSF grant, Foundations of human sociality, supporting ethnographic work ($8500) 2001-2002 Max Planck Institute post-doctoral fellowship, MPI for Human Development, Center for Adaptive Behavior and Cognition, Berlin 2000-2001
Recommended publications
  • NEWS MPI-EVA Has a New Director
    Max Planck Institute for Evolutionary Anthropology Max-Planck-Institut für evolutionäre Anthropologie NEWS 04 August 2015 MPI-EVA has a new director Headed by Professor Richard McElreath the Department of Human Behavior, Ecology and Culture is going to start its work at the Max Planck Institute for Evolutionary Anthropology (MPI-EVA) in Leipzig, Germany. Richard McElreath has accepted the call as Director at the Max Planck Institute for Evolutionary Anthropology in Leipzig, Germany, where he is setting up a new department starting in August 2015. Until now, he has been working as a professor at the University of California, Davis, in the USA. The new Department of Human Behavior, Ecology and Culture will investigate the role of culture in human evolution and adaptation. The evolution of fancy social learning in humans accounts for both the nature of human adaptation and the extraordinary scale and variety of human societies. The integration of ethnographic fieldwork with mathematical models and advanced quantitative methods will be the department's methodological focus. McElreath received his Bachelor's degree from Emory University in Atlanta, USA, and his graduate degrees from the University of California, Los Angeles, USA. He did his dissertation research in Tanzania and held a post-doctoral position at the Max Planck Institute for Human Development in Berlin before joining the faculty at University of California, Davis, in 2002. From August 2015 onwards McElreath is a director at the Max Planck Institute for Evolutionary Anthropology in Leipzig. The MPI-EVA’s five departments unite scientists with various backgrounds whose aim is to investigate the history of humankind from an interdisciplinary perspective with the help of comparative analyses of genes, cultures, cognitive abilities and social systems of past and present human populations as well as those of primates closely related to human beings.
    [Show full text]
  • Tribal Social Instincts and the Cultural Evolution of Institutions to Solve Collective Action Problems
    UC Riverside Cliodynamics Title Tribal Social Instincts and the Cultural Evolution of Institutions to Solve Collective Action Problems Permalink https://escholarship.org/uc/item/981121t8 Journal Cliodynamics, 3(1) Authors Richerson, Peter Henrich, Joe Publication Date 2012 DOI 10.21237/C7clio3112453 Peer reviewed eScholarship.org Powered by the California Digital Library University of California Cliodynamics: the Journal of Theoretical and Mathematical History Tribal Social Instincts and the Cultural Evolution of Institutions to Solve Collective Action Problems Peter Richerson University of California-Davis Joseph Henrich University of British Columbia Human social life is uniquely complex and diverse. Much of that complexity and diversity arises from culturally transmitted ideas, values and skills that underpin the operation of social norms and institutions that structure our social life. Considerable theoretical and empirical work has been devoted to the role of cultural evolutionary processes in the evolution of social norms and institutions. The most persistent controversy has been over the role of cultural group selection and gene- culture coevolution in early human populations during Pleistocene. We argue that cultural group selection and related cultural evolutionary processes had an important role in shaping the innate components of our social psychology. By the Upper Paleolithic humans seem to have lived in societies structured by institutions, as do modern populations living in small-scale societies. The most ambitious attempts to test these ideas have been the use of experimental games in field settings to document human similarities and differences on theoretically interesting dimensions. These studies have documented a huge range of behavior across populations, although no societies so far examined follow the expectations of selfish rationality.
    [Show full text]
  • The Evolution of Cultural Evolution
    Evolutionary Anthropology 123 ARTICLES The Evolution of Cultural Evolution JOSEPH HENRICH AND RICHARD McELREATH Humans are unique in their range of environments and in the nature and diversity of attempted to glean as much as they their behavioral adaptations. While a variety of local genetic adaptations exist within could from the aboriginals about nar- our species, it seems certain that the same basic genetic endowment produces arctic doo, an aquatic fern bearing spores foraging, tropical horticulture, and desert pastoralism, a constellation that represents they had observed the aboriginals us- a greater range of subsistence behavior than the rest of the Primate Order combined. ing to make bread. Despite traveling The behavioral adaptations that explain the immense success of our species are along a creek and receiving frequent cultural in the sense that they are transmitted among individuals by social learning and gifts of fish from the locals, they were have accumulated over generations. Understanding how and when such culturally unable to figure out how to catch evolved adaptations arise requires understanding of both the evolution of the psycho- them. Two months after departing logical mechanisms that underlie human social learning and the evolutionary (popu- from their base camp, the threesome lation) dynamics of cultural systems. had become entirely dependent on nardoo bread and occasional gifts of fish from the locals. Despite consum- In 1860, aiming to be the first Euro- three men (King, Wills and Gray) ing what seemed to be sufficient calo- peans to travel south to north across from their base camp in Cooper’s ries, all three became increasingly fa- Australia, Robert Burke led an ex- Creek in central Australia with five tigued and suffered from painful tremely well-equipped expedition of fully loaded camels (specially im- bowel movements.
    [Show full text]
  • Arxiv:1808.10173V2 [Stat.AP] 30 Aug 2020
    AN INTRODUCTION TO INDUCTIVE STATISTICAL INFERENCE FROM PARAMETER ESTIMATION TO DECISION-MAKING Lecture notes for a quantitative–methodological module at the Master degree (M.Sc.) level HENK VAN ELST August 30, 2020 parcIT GmbH Erftstraße 15 50672 Köln Germany ORCID iD: 0000-0003-3331-9547 E–Mail: [email protected] arXiv:1808.10173v2 [stat.AP] 30 Aug 2020 E–Print: arXiv:1808.10173v2 [stat.AP] © 2016–2020 Henk van Elst Dedicated to the good people at Karlshochschule Abstract These lecture notes aim at a post-Bachelor audience with a background at an introductory level in Applied Mathematics and Applied Statistics. They discuss the logic and methodology of the Bayes–Laplace ap- proach to inductive statistical inference that places common sense and the guiding lines of the scientific method at the heart of systematic analyses of quantitative–empirical data. Following an exposition of ex- actly solvable cases of single- and two-parameter estimation problems, the main focus is laid on Markov Chain Monte Carlo (MCMC) simulations on the basis of Hamiltonian Monte Carlo sampling of poste- rior joint probability distributions for regression parameters occurring in generalised linear models for a univariate outcome variable. The modelling of fixed effects as well as of correlated varying effects via multi-level models in non-centred parametrisation is considered. The simulation of posterior predictive distributions is outlined. The assessment of a model’s relative out-of-sample posterior predictive accuracy with information entropy-based criteria WAIC and LOOIC and model comparison with Bayes factors are addressed. Concluding, a conceptual link to the behavioural subjective expected utility representation of a single decision-maker’s choice behaviour in static one-shot decision problems is established.
    [Show full text]
  • Community Structure, Mobility, and the Strength of Norms in an African Society: the Sangu of Tanzania Richard Mcelreath
    11 Community Structure, Mobility, and the Strength of Norms in an African Society: the Sangu of Tanzania Richard McElreath INTRODUCTION Both ethnographic and experimental evidence suggest that a sig- ni®cant number of individuals in many, and probably most, human communities have a tendency to punish individuals who violate local norms, often at a substantial cost to themselves and even when the norm violations do not directly cost the punisher anything (Boyd and Richerson 1985, 1992). The ®rst of these lines of evidence is the widespread observation (typically ethnographic or anecdotal) of `moralistic' punishment, wherein third parties punish violators of social rules. Another, line of evidence has emerged in experimental economics, where human behavior in several economic `games' has generated unexpected and seemingly irrational results (see Kagel and Roth 1995). The Ultimatum Game has been a favorite among these games, and the chapters in this volume indicate that the `non-rational' game behavior is generally cross-cultural, although some societies do approach the standard de®nition of `rational' choice. The Ulti- matum Game involves an anonymous ®rst player (proposer) who splits a pool of money any way she chooses, followed by an anonymous receiving individual (responder) who decides whether to accept her portion of the split, giving the remainder to the ®rst player, or to reject the split, giving both herself and the ®rst player none of the pool of money. The classic prediction is that the rational proposer should offer the lowest nonzero amount possible while the responder should always accept any offer greater than zero. How- ever, not only do proposers commonly offer more than the lowest unit of money (mean offers are usually slightly below 50 percent in 336 Richard McElreath industrialized settings), but responders sometimes reject low offers (Ultimatum Game data chapters here).
    [Show full text]
  • Inter-Ethnic Interaction, Strategic Bargaining Power, and The
    1 1 Inter-ethnic Interaction, Strategic Bargaining Power, and the Dynamics of 2 Cultural Norms: A Field Study in an Amazonian Population 3 4 John Andrew Bunce1,2,3 and Richard McElreath1,2 5 6 1Department of Human Behavior, Ecology, and Culture, Max Planck Institute for Evolutionary 7 Anthropology, Leipzig, Germany 8 2Department of Anthropology, University of California, Davis, CA USA 9 3Department of Anthropology, Indiana University, Bloomington, IN USA 10 11 Corresponding author: John Andrew Bunce (tel: +49 341 3550 347, email: 12 [email protected]) 13 14 ORCID 15 John Andrew Bunce: 0000-0003-4092-485X 16 Richard McElreath: 0000-0002-0387-5377 17 18 In press in Human Nature 2 19 ABSTRACT 20 Ethnic groups are universal and unique to human societies. Such groups sometimes have 21 norms of behavior that are adaptively linked to their social and ecological circumstances, and 22 ethnic boundaries may function to protect that variation from erosion by inter-ethnic interaction. 23 However, such interaction is often frequent and voluntary, suggesting that individuals may be 24 able to strategically reduce its costs, allowing adaptive cultural variation to persist in spite of 25 interaction with out-groups with different norms. We examine five mechanisms influencing the 26 dynamics of ethnically-distinct cultural norms, each focused on strategic individual-level choices 27 in inter-ethnic interaction: bargaining, interaction frequency-biased norm adoption, assortment 28 on norms, success-biased inter-ethnic social learning, and childhood socialization. We use 29 Bayesian item response models to analyze patterns of norm variation and inter-ethnic interaction 30 in an ethnically-structured Amazonian population.
    [Show full text]
  • The Structure of Multiplex Networks Predicts Play in Economic Games
    The structure of multiplex networks predicts play in economic games and real-world cooperation Curtis Atkisson1, *: Orcid # 0000-0003-3575-6871 Monique Borgerhoff Mulder1,2: Orcid #0000-0003-1117-5984 (1) Department of Anthropology, University of California Davis, Davis, CA 95616 (2) Department of Human Behavior, Ecology and Culture, Max Planck Institute, Leipzig, Germany 04103 * corresponding author: PO Box 101, North Hartland, VT 05052; 573-746-1804, [email protected] Abstract Explaining why humans cooperate in anonymous contexts is a major goal of human behavioral ecology, cultural evolution, and related fieldsWhat predicts cooperation in anonymous contexts is inconsistent across populations, levels of analysis, and games. For instance, market integration is a key predictor across ethnolinguistic groups but has inconsistent predictive power at the individual level. We adapt an idea from 19th-century sociology: people in societies with greater overlap in ties across domains among community members (Durkheim’s “mechanical” solidarity) will cooperate more with their network partners and less in anonymous contexts than people in societies with less overlap (“organic” solidarity). This hypothesis, which can be tested at the individual and community level, assumes that these two types of societies differ in the importance of keeping existing relationships as opposed to recruiting new partners. Using multiplex networks, we test this idea by comparing cooperative tendencies in both anonymous experimental games and real-life communal labor tasks across 9 Makushi villages in Guyana that vary in the degree of within-village overlap. Average overlap in a village predicts both real- world cooperative and anonymous interactions in the predicted direction; individual overlap also has effects in the expected direction.
    [Show full text]
  • A Long-Form Research Program in Human Behavior, Ecology & Culture
    A Long-form Research Program in Human Behavior, Ecology, and Culture Richard McElreath Ides of March 2017 Objective Human societies display long-form adaptation. Humans adapt behav- iorally, and human behavior requires years to acquire and generations to develop. Long-form behavioral adaptations explain our species’ extraordinary diversity and its ecological success. At the same time, the cognitive mechanisms and population dynamics that make long- form adaptation possible also make possible evolutionarily novel soci- eties and forms of behavior and technology. Humans have co-existed with these evolutionary novelties for long enough that our genes are adapted to them. The study of long-form adaptation will benefit from long-form re- search that is both longitudinal and comparative, allowing it to inform theories of human evolution and the dynamics of human societies. Normal human science lacks the necessary infrastructure. This docu- ment presents a sketch of a research program. The major goal is to develop a coordinated and longitudinal, but relatively decentralized, field research network. This network takes its empirical direction from current theories of human adaptation. But it is primarily an infrastructure project that would improve our ability to study the microevolution of human behavior and culture in ecological context. The goal is absolutely not to create a completely standardized, top-down cross-cultural project. Rather, the network would support and facilitate long-term studies as elected by individual researchers, making use of practical and ethnographic expertise at each site and encouraging innovations to flow in all directions. Topics of research would overlap, both because of the synergies arising from overlap and because of shared interests in the roles of behavior in human adaptation and evolution.
    [Show full text]
  • Biocultural Dialogues: Biology and Culture in Psychological Anthropology DANIEL J
    Biocultural Dialogues: Biology and Culture in Psychological Anthropology DANIEL J. HRUSCHKA DANIEL H. LENDE CAROL M. WORTHMAN INTRODUCTION Psychological anthropology has a long history of integrative, cross- disciplinary research within the social sciences. This holistic tradition has substantially contributed to understanding the relationships between individuals and their cultural environment and to developing more sophis- ticated models of human variation within and between cultures. Whereas these contributions have generally arisen from conversations between psychology and anthropology, research integrating biological and cultural anthropology has become an increasingly established part of other an- thropological subfields, such as medical (Armelagos et al. 1992; Brown et al. 1998; Leatherman 1996; Oths 1998) and biological anthropology (Bogin 1997; Goodman and Leatherman 1998a). This special issue con- tinues psychological anthropology’s commitment to holistic inquiry by examining how dialogues between biological and cultural perspectives can generate new insights when applied to key questions in psychological anthropology. The articles in this volume tackle various issues including the ef- fect of cultural consonance on well-being in Brazil, the biocultural roots of addiction among Colombian youth, the social and psycholog- ical factors implicated in becoming a Candombl´e medium, the pro- cess of coping with political-ecological inequality in Peru, and the biocultural pathways to somatization and suffering in Nepal. Not sur- prisingly, the research presented here has direct links to the biocultural ETHOS,Vol. 33, No. 1, pp. 1–19, ISSN 0091-2131, electronic ISSN 1548-1352. C 2005 by the American Anthro- pological Association. All rights reserved. Please direct all requests for permission to photocopy or reproduce article content through the University of California Press’s Rights and Permissions website, http://www.ucpress.edu/journals/ rights.htm.
    [Show full text]
  • Are Peasants Risk‐Averse Decision Makers? Author(S): Joseph Henrich and Richard Mcelreath Source: Current Anthropology, Vol
    Are Peasants Risk‐Averse Decision Makers? Author(s): Joseph Henrich and Richard McElreath Source: Current Anthropology, Vol. 43, No. 1 (February 2002), pp. 172-181 Published by: The University of Chicago Press on behalf of Wenner-Gren Foundation for Anthropological Research Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/10.1086/338291 . Accessed: 12/10/2015 11:54 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp . JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. The University of Chicago Press and Wenner-Gren Foundation for Anthropological Research are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Current Anthropology. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Mon, 12 Oct 2015 11:54:01 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 172 F current anthropology two standard models of risk preferences that seek to cap- Are Peasants Risk-Averse Decision ture what researchers mean when they describe behavior Makers?1 as “risk-averse.” Second, we introduce the ethnographic field sites where the experimental and ethnographic re- search was performed and describe the methods used. joseph henrich and richard mcelreath Third, we report the basic experimental results. Fourth, Wissenschaftskolleg zu Berlin, Wallotstr.
    [Show full text]
  • Shared Norms and the Evolution of Ethnic Markers Author(S): Richard Mcelreath, Robert Boyd, and Peter J
    Shared Norms and the Evolution of Ethnic Markers Author(s): Richard McElreath, Robert Boyd, and Peter J. Richerson Source: Current Anthropology, Vol. 44, No. 1 (February 2003), pp. 122-130 Published by: The University of Chicago Press on behalf of Wenner-Gren Foundation for Anthropological Research Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/10.1086/345689 . Accessed: 14/09/2015 08:25 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp . JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. The University of Chicago Press and Wenner-Gren Foundation for Anthropological Research are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Current Anthropology. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 194.94.96.180 on Mon, 14 Sep 2015 08:25:37 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Reports know where they are housed or because anthropologically Preserving the Anthropological appropriate finding aids are lacking. As a result, the pro- Record: A Decade of CoPAR fession has little control over much of its own legacy. The 1 situation ill serves the long-term interests of anthropology Initiatives and threatens its future health and effectiveness. issues and strategies nancy j. parezo, don d.
    [Show full text]
  • PETER J. RICHERSON LIST of PUBLICATIONS H Index 66 (Google Scholar)
    PETER J. RICHERSON LIST OF PUBLICATIONS h index 66 (Google Scholar) 1.* Peter J. Richerson, and Albert A. Grigarick. 1967. The life history of Stenopelmis rufinasus (Coleoptera: Curculionidae). Annals of American Entomological Society. 602:351-354. 2. Peter J. Richerson 1969. The community ecology of the Lake Tahoe plankton. Dissertation submitted in partial satisfaction of the requirements for Ph.D. in Zoology, University of California, Davis, December. 3.* Peter J. Richerson, Gerald A. Moshiri, and Gordon Godshalk. 1970. Certain ecological aspects of pollen dispersion in Lake Tahoe (California-Nevada). Limnology and Oceanography 15:149-153. 4.* Peter J. Richerson, Richard Armstrong and Charles R. Goldman. 1970. Contemporaneous disequilibrium, a new hypothesis to explain the "paradox of the plankton." Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 67:1710-1714. 5. Charles R. Goldman, James McEvoy and Peter J. Richerson. 1971. Measurement of environmental quality. Report to National Water Commission. Environmental Quality and Water Development. 6. Peter J. Richerson. 1972. The role of zooplankton in the process of eutrophication. In R.L. Brown and M.H. Tunzi (eds.), Proceedings of Seminar on Eutrophication and Biostimulation, California Department of Water Resources, pp. 133-144. 7. Charles R. Goldman, James McEvoy and Peter J. Richerson (eds.). 1973. Environmental Quality and Water Development. William H. Freeman. 510 pp. 8. John G Coy, Robert A. Johnston and Peter J. Richerson. 1973. Critique of Water Resources Council's proposed principles and standards for planning water and related land resources. In Environmental Quality and Water Development, C.R. Goldman, J. McEvoy and P.J. Richerson (eds.), W.H.
    [Show full text]