Inter-Ethnic Interaction, Strategic Bargaining Power, and The

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Inter-Ethnic Interaction, Strategic Bargaining Power, and The 1 1 Inter-ethnic Interaction, Strategic Bargaining Power, and the Dynamics of 2 Cultural Norms: A Field Study in an Amazonian Population 3 4 John Andrew Bunce1,2,3 and Richard McElreath1,2 5 6 1Department of Human Behavior, Ecology, and Culture, Max Planck Institute for Evolutionary 7 Anthropology, Leipzig, Germany 8 2Department of Anthropology, University of California, Davis, CA USA 9 3Department of Anthropology, Indiana University, Bloomington, IN USA 10 11 Corresponding author: John Andrew Bunce (tel: +49 341 3550 347, email: 12 [email protected]) 13 14 ORCID 15 John Andrew Bunce: 0000-0003-4092-485X 16 Richard McElreath: 0000-0002-0387-5377 17 18 In press in Human Nature 2 19 ABSTRACT 20 Ethnic groups are universal and unique to human societies. Such groups sometimes have 21 norms of behavior that are adaptively linked to their social and ecological circumstances, and 22 ethnic boundaries may function to protect that variation from erosion by inter-ethnic interaction. 23 However, such interaction is often frequent and voluntary, suggesting that individuals may be 24 able to strategically reduce its costs, allowing adaptive cultural variation to persist in spite of 25 interaction with out-groups with different norms. We examine five mechanisms influencing the 26 dynamics of ethnically-distinct cultural norms, each focused on strategic individual-level choices 27 in inter-ethnic interaction: bargaining, interaction frequency-biased norm adoption, assortment 28 on norms, success-biased inter-ethnic social learning, and childhood socialization. We use 29 Bayesian item response models to analyze patterns of norm variation and inter-ethnic interaction 30 in an ethnically-structured Amazonian population. We show that, among indigenous Matsigenka, 31 inter-ethnic education with colonial Mestizos is more strongly associated with Mestizo-typical 32 norms than is even extensive inter-ethnic experience in commerce and wage labor. Using 33 ethnographic observations, we show that all five of the proposed mechanisms of norm adoption 34 may contribute to this effect. However, of these mechanisms, we argue that changes in relative 35 bargaining power are particularly important for ethnic minorities wishing to preserve distinctive 36 norms while engaging in inter-ethnic interaction in domains such as education. If this mechanism 37 proves applicable in a range of other ethnographic contexts, it would constitute one cogent 38 explanation for when and why ethnically-structured cultural variation can either persist or erode 39 given frequent, and often mutually beneficial, inter-ethnic interaction. 40 41 Keywords: Ethnic boundaries, Cultural evolution, Education, Norms, Indigenous peoples, 42 Amazonia 43 44 1. INTRODUCTION 45 The extent of human cultural variation is unprecedented in nature, and its evolutionary 46 origins remain mysterious. Much human cultural variation is structured in symbolically marked 47 groups, i.e., ethnic groups, which are often associated with different suites of beliefs about what 48 constitutes appropriate behavior in a given context, i.e., cultural norms (Barth 1998[1969]; see 49 also Bicchieri 2006). Life in such groups may have characterized our species for 80,000 years or 50 more (d'Errico et al. 2009; Foley and Lahr 2011). The fact that ethnic groups are nearly universal 51 in human populations at all but the smallest geographic scales, are absent in all other primates, 52 and are highly dynamic presents important puzzles to evolutionary social scientists: What are the 53 psychological and cultural processes that make and remake ethnic groups? What role did such 54 processes play in the adaptive history of humankind? 55 56 1.1. Evolutionary Models of the Norms and Behaviors of Symbolically Marked Groups 57 One idea to explain the maintenance of ethnic groups is that assortment on symbolic 58 markers helps to preserve locally-adaptive norms, knowledge, and beliefs from erosion by 59 admixture (Richerson and Boyd 2005; Henrich and McElreath 2003). For example, McElreath et 60 al. (2003) demonstrate that symbolically marked groups with differences in norms can arise 61 spontaneously under a minimal set of assumptions: benefits to inter-individual interaction 62 depend on norm coordination, interaction partners are chosen on the basis of markers, and norms 63 and markers tend to be acquired from locally successful individuals. Once such marked groups 64 evolve, intra-group coordination interactions yield greater benefits than interaction between 3 65 groups. A similar model by Boyd and Richerson (1987) focuses instead on ecological 66 adaptations rather than norms, but also produces symbolically marked groups that protect 67 adaptive, culturally transmitted behavioral variation from erosion by mixing between residential 68 groups. Once evolved, ethnic groups in these models have salient, and relatively fixed, 69 boundaries (see also Pagel and Mace 2004), and isolating mechanisms attenuate costly inter- 70 group interaction (analogous to reproductive isolating mechanisms in biological species, e.g., 71 Price 2008). 72 A shortcoming of these models is that interaction between groups is exogenously 73 imposed, rather than a result of the strategic decisions of individuals. In these models, there are 74 no benefits to inter-group over intra-group interaction. In contrast, in nearly all ethnographic and 75 historically-described contexts, people voluntarily engage in at least some inter-ethnic interaction 76 (e.g., Wolf 1982). Such interaction sometimes entails the adoption of out-group cultural norms 77 (Nagel 1996; Kopenawa and Albert 2013; Behrens 1992) and is not necessarily viewed by 78 participants as detrimental (Rosengren 2004; Baer 2004). There may be adaptive reasons to 79 interact with other ethnic groups, and even to adopt culturally transmitted behavior from them. 80 Thus, models that exclude such benefits miss a potentially important factor affecting cultural 81 dynamics. 82 One potential resolution to this conflict between models and empirical observation is that 83 individuals strategically adjust how, and with whom, they interact, in order to either reduce costs 84 of norm mis-coordination, or, rather, to preferentially adopt adaptive behavior from members of 85 other groups. The strategic nature of between-group interaction could help explain how, in some 86 contexts, ethnic-typical norms can be maintained for generations despite frequent inter-ethnic 87 interaction (e.g., Fur and Baggara: Haaland 1998 (1969)), while, in other cases, the norms of one 88 ethnic group are rapidly replaced by those of another (e.g., assimilation of some immigrants in 89 the United States: Gans 1979). The lack of mechanistic models of these dynamics represents an 90 important challenge for our understanding of the evolution of cultural norms in ethnically- 91 structured populations. Ultimately we seek a body of theory that can explain the uniqueness of 92 human ethnic variation among primates, contribute to an understanding of the dynamics of 93 historical and contemporary ethnic groups, and enhance the ability of ethnic minority members 94 to reverse or slow the loss of valued cultural norms, should they wish to. 95 96 1.2. Mechanisms of Norm Adoption at Ethnic Boundaries 97 Previous research on ethnic variation has emphasized links between the adoption of out- 98 group cultural norms (e.g., assimilation and marginalization), participation in inter-ethnic 99 interaction (e.g., through social networks), individual personality traits (e.g., attitude toward the 100 out group, bicultural efficacy), and the strategic maintenance or change of ethnic identity 101 (Wimmer 2013; Berry 1997; LaFromboise et al. 1993). However, the mechanistic links between 102 inter-ethnic interaction and norm adoption are often not specified in sufficient detail to facilitate 103 empirical testing. For instance, the pioneering study of Graves (1967) among minority Spanish- 104 speaking Americans and Native Americans in a majority Anglo-American town in the 105 Southwestern U.S., found a strong relationship between inter-ethnic interaction (e.g., in domains 106 such as education, military service, out-group friendships, employment, etc.) and the probability 107 that minority individuals hold majority-typical norms. From this, it is argued that exposure to 108 outgroup norms, identification with the outgroup, and access to resources controlled by the 109 outgroup all play roles in the adoption of outgroup norms. However, the mechanisms underlying 110 such relationships are not well understood, making it difficult to distinguish among them with 4 111 the available data. As an initial step forward, we focus on five theoretically-grounded and 112 previously-published mechanisms whose predictions can be compared using quantitative and 113 ethnographic data at hand. An individual’s adoption of outgroup norms may depend on: 1) 114 differential bargaining power during inter-ethnic interactions, 2) the relative importance (e.g., 115 relative frequency) of inter-ethnic coordination interactions; 3) inter-ethnic assortment on 116 coordination norms, coupled with success-biased social learning among co-ethnics; 4) success- 117 biased inter-ethnic social learning; and 5) favorable exposure to outgroup norms during 118 childhood socialization. These five mechanisms are neither exhaustive nor mutually exclusive. 119 However, they make distinct predictions that we can evaluate using empirical data in order to 120 better understand their roles in the
Recommended publications
  • NEWS MPI-EVA Has a New Director
    Max Planck Institute for Evolutionary Anthropology Max-Planck-Institut für evolutionäre Anthropologie NEWS 04 August 2015 MPI-EVA has a new director Headed by Professor Richard McElreath the Department of Human Behavior, Ecology and Culture is going to start its work at the Max Planck Institute for Evolutionary Anthropology (MPI-EVA) in Leipzig, Germany. Richard McElreath has accepted the call as Director at the Max Planck Institute for Evolutionary Anthropology in Leipzig, Germany, where he is setting up a new department starting in August 2015. Until now, he has been working as a professor at the University of California, Davis, in the USA. The new Department of Human Behavior, Ecology and Culture will investigate the role of culture in human evolution and adaptation. The evolution of fancy social learning in humans accounts for both the nature of human adaptation and the extraordinary scale and variety of human societies. The integration of ethnographic fieldwork with mathematical models and advanced quantitative methods will be the department's methodological focus. McElreath received his Bachelor's degree from Emory University in Atlanta, USA, and his graduate degrees from the University of California, Los Angeles, USA. He did his dissertation research in Tanzania and held a post-doctoral position at the Max Planck Institute for Human Development in Berlin before joining the faculty at University of California, Davis, in 2002. From August 2015 onwards McElreath is a director at the Max Planck Institute for Evolutionary Anthropology in Leipzig. The MPI-EVA’s five departments unite scientists with various backgrounds whose aim is to investigate the history of humankind from an interdisciplinary perspective with the help of comparative analyses of genes, cultures, cognitive abilities and social systems of past and present human populations as well as those of primates closely related to human beings.
    [Show full text]
  • Tribal Social Instincts and the Cultural Evolution of Institutions to Solve Collective Action Problems
    UC Riverside Cliodynamics Title Tribal Social Instincts and the Cultural Evolution of Institutions to Solve Collective Action Problems Permalink https://escholarship.org/uc/item/981121t8 Journal Cliodynamics, 3(1) Authors Richerson, Peter Henrich, Joe Publication Date 2012 DOI 10.21237/C7clio3112453 Peer reviewed eScholarship.org Powered by the California Digital Library University of California Cliodynamics: the Journal of Theoretical and Mathematical History Tribal Social Instincts and the Cultural Evolution of Institutions to Solve Collective Action Problems Peter Richerson University of California-Davis Joseph Henrich University of British Columbia Human social life is uniquely complex and diverse. Much of that complexity and diversity arises from culturally transmitted ideas, values and skills that underpin the operation of social norms and institutions that structure our social life. Considerable theoretical and empirical work has been devoted to the role of cultural evolutionary processes in the evolution of social norms and institutions. The most persistent controversy has been over the role of cultural group selection and gene- culture coevolution in early human populations during Pleistocene. We argue that cultural group selection and related cultural evolutionary processes had an important role in shaping the innate components of our social psychology. By the Upper Paleolithic humans seem to have lived in societies structured by institutions, as do modern populations living in small-scale societies. The most ambitious attempts to test these ideas have been the use of experimental games in field settings to document human similarities and differences on theoretically interesting dimensions. These studies have documented a huge range of behavior across populations, although no societies so far examined follow the expectations of selfish rationality.
    [Show full text]
  • The Evolution of Cultural Evolution
    Evolutionary Anthropology 123 ARTICLES The Evolution of Cultural Evolution JOSEPH HENRICH AND RICHARD McELREATH Humans are unique in their range of environments and in the nature and diversity of attempted to glean as much as they their behavioral adaptations. While a variety of local genetic adaptations exist within could from the aboriginals about nar- our species, it seems certain that the same basic genetic endowment produces arctic doo, an aquatic fern bearing spores foraging, tropical horticulture, and desert pastoralism, a constellation that represents they had observed the aboriginals us- a greater range of subsistence behavior than the rest of the Primate Order combined. ing to make bread. Despite traveling The behavioral adaptations that explain the immense success of our species are along a creek and receiving frequent cultural in the sense that they are transmitted among individuals by social learning and gifts of fish from the locals, they were have accumulated over generations. Understanding how and when such culturally unable to figure out how to catch evolved adaptations arise requires understanding of both the evolution of the psycho- them. Two months after departing logical mechanisms that underlie human social learning and the evolutionary (popu- from their base camp, the threesome lation) dynamics of cultural systems. had become entirely dependent on nardoo bread and occasional gifts of fish from the locals. Despite consum- In 1860, aiming to be the first Euro- three men (King, Wills and Gray) ing what seemed to be sufficient calo- peans to travel south to north across from their base camp in Cooper’s ries, all three became increasingly fa- Australia, Robert Burke led an ex- Creek in central Australia with five tigued and suffered from painful tremely well-equipped expedition of fully loaded camels (specially im- bowel movements.
    [Show full text]
  • Arxiv:1808.10173V2 [Stat.AP] 30 Aug 2020
    AN INTRODUCTION TO INDUCTIVE STATISTICAL INFERENCE FROM PARAMETER ESTIMATION TO DECISION-MAKING Lecture notes for a quantitative–methodological module at the Master degree (M.Sc.) level HENK VAN ELST August 30, 2020 parcIT GmbH Erftstraße 15 50672 Köln Germany ORCID iD: 0000-0003-3331-9547 E–Mail: [email protected] arXiv:1808.10173v2 [stat.AP] 30 Aug 2020 E–Print: arXiv:1808.10173v2 [stat.AP] © 2016–2020 Henk van Elst Dedicated to the good people at Karlshochschule Abstract These lecture notes aim at a post-Bachelor audience with a background at an introductory level in Applied Mathematics and Applied Statistics. They discuss the logic and methodology of the Bayes–Laplace ap- proach to inductive statistical inference that places common sense and the guiding lines of the scientific method at the heart of systematic analyses of quantitative–empirical data. Following an exposition of ex- actly solvable cases of single- and two-parameter estimation problems, the main focus is laid on Markov Chain Monte Carlo (MCMC) simulations on the basis of Hamiltonian Monte Carlo sampling of poste- rior joint probability distributions for regression parameters occurring in generalised linear models for a univariate outcome variable. The modelling of fixed effects as well as of correlated varying effects via multi-level models in non-centred parametrisation is considered. The simulation of posterior predictive distributions is outlined. The assessment of a model’s relative out-of-sample posterior predictive accuracy with information entropy-based criteria WAIC and LOOIC and model comparison with Bayes factors are addressed. Concluding, a conceptual link to the behavioural subjective expected utility representation of a single decision-maker’s choice behaviour in static one-shot decision problems is established.
    [Show full text]
  • Community Structure, Mobility, and the Strength of Norms in an African Society: the Sangu of Tanzania Richard Mcelreath
    11 Community Structure, Mobility, and the Strength of Norms in an African Society: the Sangu of Tanzania Richard McElreath INTRODUCTION Both ethnographic and experimental evidence suggest that a sig- ni®cant number of individuals in many, and probably most, human communities have a tendency to punish individuals who violate local norms, often at a substantial cost to themselves and even when the norm violations do not directly cost the punisher anything (Boyd and Richerson 1985, 1992). The ®rst of these lines of evidence is the widespread observation (typically ethnographic or anecdotal) of `moralistic' punishment, wherein third parties punish violators of social rules. Another, line of evidence has emerged in experimental economics, where human behavior in several economic `games' has generated unexpected and seemingly irrational results (see Kagel and Roth 1995). The Ultimatum Game has been a favorite among these games, and the chapters in this volume indicate that the `non-rational' game behavior is generally cross-cultural, although some societies do approach the standard de®nition of `rational' choice. The Ulti- matum Game involves an anonymous ®rst player (proposer) who splits a pool of money any way she chooses, followed by an anonymous receiving individual (responder) who decides whether to accept her portion of the split, giving the remainder to the ®rst player, or to reject the split, giving both herself and the ®rst player none of the pool of money. The classic prediction is that the rational proposer should offer the lowest nonzero amount possible while the responder should always accept any offer greater than zero. How- ever, not only do proposers commonly offer more than the lowest unit of money (mean offers are usually slightly below 50 percent in 336 Richard McElreath industrialized settings), but responders sometimes reject low offers (Ultimatum Game data chapters here).
    [Show full text]
  • The Structure of Multiplex Networks Predicts Play in Economic Games
    The structure of multiplex networks predicts play in economic games and real-world cooperation Curtis Atkisson1, *: Orcid # 0000-0003-3575-6871 Monique Borgerhoff Mulder1,2: Orcid #0000-0003-1117-5984 (1) Department of Anthropology, University of California Davis, Davis, CA 95616 (2) Department of Human Behavior, Ecology and Culture, Max Planck Institute, Leipzig, Germany 04103 * corresponding author: PO Box 101, North Hartland, VT 05052; 573-746-1804, [email protected] Abstract Explaining why humans cooperate in anonymous contexts is a major goal of human behavioral ecology, cultural evolution, and related fieldsWhat predicts cooperation in anonymous contexts is inconsistent across populations, levels of analysis, and games. For instance, market integration is a key predictor across ethnolinguistic groups but has inconsistent predictive power at the individual level. We adapt an idea from 19th-century sociology: people in societies with greater overlap in ties across domains among community members (Durkheim’s “mechanical” solidarity) will cooperate more with their network partners and less in anonymous contexts than people in societies with less overlap (“organic” solidarity). This hypothesis, which can be tested at the individual and community level, assumes that these two types of societies differ in the importance of keeping existing relationships as opposed to recruiting new partners. Using multiplex networks, we test this idea by comparing cooperative tendencies in both anonymous experimental games and real-life communal labor tasks across 9 Makushi villages in Guyana that vary in the degree of within-village overlap. Average overlap in a village predicts both real- world cooperative and anonymous interactions in the predicted direction; individual overlap also has effects in the expected direction.
    [Show full text]
  • A Long-Form Research Program in Human Behavior, Ecology & Culture
    A Long-form Research Program in Human Behavior, Ecology, and Culture Richard McElreath Ides of March 2017 Objective Human societies display long-form adaptation. Humans adapt behav- iorally, and human behavior requires years to acquire and generations to develop. Long-form behavioral adaptations explain our species’ extraordinary diversity and its ecological success. At the same time, the cognitive mechanisms and population dynamics that make long- form adaptation possible also make possible evolutionarily novel soci- eties and forms of behavior and technology. Humans have co-existed with these evolutionary novelties for long enough that our genes are adapted to them. The study of long-form adaptation will benefit from long-form re- search that is both longitudinal and comparative, allowing it to inform theories of human evolution and the dynamics of human societies. Normal human science lacks the necessary infrastructure. This docu- ment presents a sketch of a research program. The major goal is to develop a coordinated and longitudinal, but relatively decentralized, field research network. This network takes its empirical direction from current theories of human adaptation. But it is primarily an infrastructure project that would improve our ability to study the microevolution of human behavior and culture in ecological context. The goal is absolutely not to create a completely standardized, top-down cross-cultural project. Rather, the network would support and facilitate long-term studies as elected by individual researchers, making use of practical and ethnographic expertise at each site and encouraging innovations to flow in all directions. Topics of research would overlap, both because of the synergies arising from overlap and because of shared interests in the roles of behavior in human adaptation and evolution.
    [Show full text]
  • Biocultural Dialogues: Biology and Culture in Psychological Anthropology DANIEL J
    Biocultural Dialogues: Biology and Culture in Psychological Anthropology DANIEL J. HRUSCHKA DANIEL H. LENDE CAROL M. WORTHMAN INTRODUCTION Psychological anthropology has a long history of integrative, cross- disciplinary research within the social sciences. This holistic tradition has substantially contributed to understanding the relationships between individuals and their cultural environment and to developing more sophis- ticated models of human variation within and between cultures. Whereas these contributions have generally arisen from conversations between psychology and anthropology, research integrating biological and cultural anthropology has become an increasingly established part of other an- thropological subfields, such as medical (Armelagos et al. 1992; Brown et al. 1998; Leatherman 1996; Oths 1998) and biological anthropology (Bogin 1997; Goodman and Leatherman 1998a). This special issue con- tinues psychological anthropology’s commitment to holistic inquiry by examining how dialogues between biological and cultural perspectives can generate new insights when applied to key questions in psychological anthropology. The articles in this volume tackle various issues including the ef- fect of cultural consonance on well-being in Brazil, the biocultural roots of addiction among Colombian youth, the social and psycholog- ical factors implicated in becoming a Candombl´e medium, the pro- cess of coping with political-ecological inequality in Peru, and the biocultural pathways to somatization and suffering in Nepal. Not sur- prisingly, the research presented here has direct links to the biocultural ETHOS,Vol. 33, No. 1, pp. 1–19, ISSN 0091-2131, electronic ISSN 1548-1352. C 2005 by the American Anthro- pological Association. All rights reserved. Please direct all requests for permission to photocopy or reproduce article content through the University of California Press’s Rights and Permissions website, http://www.ucpress.edu/journals/ rights.htm.
    [Show full text]
  • Are Peasants Risk‐Averse Decision Makers? Author(S): Joseph Henrich and Richard Mcelreath Source: Current Anthropology, Vol
    Are Peasants Risk‐Averse Decision Makers? Author(s): Joseph Henrich and Richard McElreath Source: Current Anthropology, Vol. 43, No. 1 (February 2002), pp. 172-181 Published by: The University of Chicago Press on behalf of Wenner-Gren Foundation for Anthropological Research Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/10.1086/338291 . Accessed: 12/10/2015 11:54 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp . JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. The University of Chicago Press and Wenner-Gren Foundation for Anthropological Research are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Current Anthropology. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Mon, 12 Oct 2015 11:54:01 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 172 F current anthropology two standard models of risk preferences that seek to cap- Are Peasants Risk-Averse Decision ture what researchers mean when they describe behavior Makers?1 as “risk-averse.” Second, we introduce the ethnographic field sites where the experimental and ethnographic re- search was performed and describe the methods used. joseph henrich and richard mcelreath Third, we report the basic experimental results. Fourth, Wissenschaftskolleg zu Berlin, Wallotstr.
    [Show full text]
  • Richard Mcelreath
    Curriculum Vitae: Richard McElreath Personal Information Address Department of Anthropology University of California{Davis One Shields Avenue Davis, CA 95616, USA Telephone (530) 752-2660 Fax (530) 752-8885 Email [email protected] WWW arbeit.ucdavis.edu/mcelreath/ Born April 18, 1973 in Landstuhl, Germany Citizenship United States Education and Employment July 2006{now Associate Professor, Department of Anthropology, University of California, Davis 2002{2006 Assistant Professor, Department of Anthropology, University of California, Davis 2001{2002 Post-doctoral researcher, Center for Adaptive Behavior and Cognition, Max Planck Institute for Human Development, Berlin 2001 Ph.D. Anthropology, University of California, Los Angeles Languages Fluent spoken and written modern standard Swahili; some Faroese Professional Activities 2007{ Strategic Planning Committee, UCD Letters and Science 2007{ Field researcher, AHRC Culture and the Mind project 2006{ Trainer, CLIMB (Collaborative Learning at the Intersection of Math and Biol- ogy) undergraduate training program, UC Davis 2006{ Member and PhD advisor, Population Biology Graduate Group, UC Davis 2004{ Chair, Human Ecology Area of Emphasis, Graduate Group in Ecology, UC Davis 2002{ Member, Animal Behavior Graduate Group, UC Davis 2001{ Member, Graduate Group in Ecology, UC Davis 1 Publications PDF copies of most of my publications are available on my website, at http://arbeit.ucdavis.edu/mcelreath/ Book Richard McElreath and Robert Boyd, Mathematical Models of Social Evolution: A Guide for the Perplexed. University of Chicago Press, 2007. Articles Frank W. Marlowe, J. Colette Berbesque, Abigail Barr, Clark Barrett, Alexan- der Bolyanatz, Juan Camilo Cardenas, Jean Ensminger, Michael Gurven, Ed- wins Gwako, Joseph Henrich, Natalie Henrich, Carolyn Lesorogol, Richard McElreath, and David Tracer.
    [Show full text]
  • Shared Norms and the Evolution of Ethnic Markers Author(S): Richard Mcelreath, Robert Boyd, and Peter J
    Shared Norms and the Evolution of Ethnic Markers Author(s): Richard McElreath, Robert Boyd, and Peter J. Richerson Source: Current Anthropology, Vol. 44, No. 1 (February 2003), pp. 122-130 Published by: The University of Chicago Press on behalf of Wenner-Gren Foundation for Anthropological Research Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/10.1086/345689 . Accessed: 14/09/2015 08:25 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp . JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. The University of Chicago Press and Wenner-Gren Foundation for Anthropological Research are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Current Anthropology. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 194.94.96.180 on Mon, 14 Sep 2015 08:25:37 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Reports know where they are housed or because anthropologically Preserving the Anthropological appropriate finding aids are lacking. As a result, the pro- Record: A Decade of CoPAR fession has little control over much of its own legacy. The 1 situation ill serves the long-term interests of anthropology Initiatives and threatens its future health and effectiveness. issues and strategies nancy j. parezo, don d.
    [Show full text]
  • PETER J. RICHERSON LIST of PUBLICATIONS H Index 66 (Google Scholar)
    PETER J. RICHERSON LIST OF PUBLICATIONS h index 66 (Google Scholar) 1.* Peter J. Richerson, and Albert A. Grigarick. 1967. The life history of Stenopelmis rufinasus (Coleoptera: Curculionidae). Annals of American Entomological Society. 602:351-354. 2. Peter J. Richerson 1969. The community ecology of the Lake Tahoe plankton. Dissertation submitted in partial satisfaction of the requirements for Ph.D. in Zoology, University of California, Davis, December. 3.* Peter J. Richerson, Gerald A. Moshiri, and Gordon Godshalk. 1970. Certain ecological aspects of pollen dispersion in Lake Tahoe (California-Nevada). Limnology and Oceanography 15:149-153. 4.* Peter J. Richerson, Richard Armstrong and Charles R. Goldman. 1970. Contemporaneous disequilibrium, a new hypothesis to explain the "paradox of the plankton." Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 67:1710-1714. 5. Charles R. Goldman, James McEvoy and Peter J. Richerson. 1971. Measurement of environmental quality. Report to National Water Commission. Environmental Quality and Water Development. 6. Peter J. Richerson. 1972. The role of zooplankton in the process of eutrophication. In R.L. Brown and M.H. Tunzi (eds.), Proceedings of Seminar on Eutrophication and Biostimulation, California Department of Water Resources, pp. 133-144. 7. Charles R. Goldman, James McEvoy and Peter J. Richerson (eds.). 1973. Environmental Quality and Water Development. William H. Freeman. 510 pp. 8. John G Coy, Robert A. Johnston and Peter J. Richerson. 1973. Critique of Water Resources Council's proposed principles and standards for planning water and related land resources. In Environmental Quality and Water Development, C.R. Goldman, J. McEvoy and P.J. Richerson (eds.), W.H.
    [Show full text]