The Limp Economic Recovery, Five Years on by John H

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Limp Economic Recovery, Five Years on by John H The Limp Economic Recovery, Five Years On By John H. Makin May 2014 Key Points Economic growth since the end of the 2008 financial crisis has been considerably below the average of other post—World War II recoveries. Weak growth of investments and employment and slow turnaround of consumption spending have contributed to the troubling pace of this recovery. To elevate and sustain growth, the US government must reverse disinflation before it becomes deflation, reduce marginal tax rates on capital accumulation, and provide clear leadership that focuses on building opportunity. Wags have applied the term “electile dysfunction” to characterize John Boehner’s weak performance as House majority leader. But it may be a more apt characterization of the impact of this flaccid economic recovery on Democrats’ reelection chances in the November midterm elections. Talk of better times notwithstanding, a closer examination of this recovery, which will be five years old in June, provides a clear picture of why it has been so disappointing. Weak Growth Growth since the June 2009 trough of this recovery has been considerably below average when compared to post–World War II recoveries. Figure 1 (red line) shows this recovery compared to other recoveries. The black line is the average growth rate during the five years after a trough in business cycles since 1947. The dashed lines are the standard deviation around that average. As is clear from a close look at the red line, growth in the current recovery has been below average for every quarter save two. The red line ends in the first quarter of 2014, which is currently estimated to be at growth of 1 percent. Figure 1. Real Gross Domestic Product Growth Source: US Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis Of course, overall growth is made up of the growth of its components—consumptions, investment, and net imports. It is also important to remember that the subpar growth over the last five years has occurred at the same time that unprecedented monetary and fiscal stimulus has been applied to support the economy. However, since the end of last year, both fiscal and monetary stimulus are being withdrawn. Notwithstanding optimistic forecasts of 3 percent growth starting at the middle of this year, it remains to be seen how robust growth can be without the help of the extraordinary monetary and fiscal stimulus that has characterized the last half- decade. Weak Investment One of the most important characteristics of a robust recovery is robust investment growth. After a typical recession, with inventories depleted and demand rising, most producers wish to add to their capital stock to meet expected higher aggregate demand. The rise in investment often accompanies an improvement in animal spirits, or optimism, among producers and also may lead to further increases in investment through the so-called accelerated effect. This recovery is a disappointing exception to the rule. As figure 2 shows, investment during the recovery, since June 2009, has run far below the average pace shown by the black line and is virtually identical to the dotted line—a full standard deviation below the typical investment growth pattern during a recovery. Figure 2. Real Private Nonresidential Fixed Investment Source: US Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis Explanations for the weak growth in investment abound. Investor uncertainty has risen in the wake of the financial crisis and substantial regulatory changes by the Obama administration, particularly in the areas of health care and financial services. This heightened investor uncertainty has penalized investment growth. Notwithstanding substantial monetary and fiscal stimulus through 2012, growth of aggregate demand has been weak, so investors have not felt the need to add to the capital stock to meet this weak growth both in the US and abroad. The weakness of investment is especially disappointing given that real interest rates, one of the determinants of investment, have been either zero or negative for most of the period since 2009. Normally, extraordinarily low borrowing costs would encourage investors to add to their capital stock. But during this expansion, the level of uncertainty has been high enough and the level of aggregate demand weak enough to discourage investment above minimal levels. Although many analysts, including the Federal Reserve, have been calling for an investment rebound for over a year, as is clear from figure 2, investment continues to crawl along at the bottom of the range for post-WWII recoveries. Of course, another problem for investment is the classic symptom of excess supply that has shown up in the behavior of price level. Inflation has been slowing over the past several years, indicating weak aggregate demand and ample productive capacity that have combined to weaken investment spending. Producers are not eager to add to capacity when the outlook for prices that they can charge for the goods they produce is bleak.1 Figure 3 shows the substandard path of inflation during this recovery. Indeed, deflation may be more of a threat than inflation to the future paths of the US and global economies. Figure 3. Inflation Calculated as the Year-over-Year Change in Monthly Urban Consumer Price Index Source: US Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis Consumption and Wealth Another striking feature of this weak recovery has been the slow recovery of consumption spending by households, especially in view of the substantial increase in wealth that has occurred with the recovery of the stock market and the housing market. Some recovery in the stock market since 2009 and the subsequent rise in house prices since 2011 has increased total household wealth by about $25 trillion over the past several years. Normally, about 4 percent of the rise in household wealth, an important determinant of consumption, is spent. That would mean an increase in spending attributable to the wealth effect equal to about $1 trillion. Spread over five years, that would provide $200 billion per year of extra demand growth, which would show up as stronger consumption spending. Demand growth of $200 billion a year is substantial, as it adds about 1.25 percentage points of growth per year, other things being equal. Given the average growth over the past five years has been about 2.2 percentage points without the wealth effect, growth would have been truly tepid, at about a 1 percent annual pace. Figure 4 shows the path of real consumption expenditures during this expansion. Notwithstanding wealth effects, consumption has been more than a standard deviation below the typical level over most of the expansion, accounting for the widely noted weakness in aggregate demand. The persistence of weak demand growth, even with substantial help from monetary and fiscal stimulus, suggests that the aftermath of the financial crisis has left households with a strong preference for cash and liquid assets. Indeed, part of the weakness of consumption reflects the efforts of households to rebuild balance sheets through extra saving after the devastation of the 2008 financial crisis. Figure 4. Real Personal Consumption Expenditures Source: US Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis The volatile path of the wealth effect is clear from figure 5. After a massive drop in wealth in the midst of the 2008 crisis, the percentage increase in wealth has been substantial and rapid compared to past expansions. The percentage rise in household real net worth since about 2011 has been a brisk 12 percent, leading some to observe that the wealth effect must be growing weaker in the light of the weak consumption growth that has accompanied the rapid increase of wealth. Figure 5. Year-over-Year Change in Real Net Worth of Household and Nonprofit Organizations Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Part of the mystery regarding the weak connection between wealth and consumption is explained in figure 6, which shows the level as opposed to the growth of household real net worth over the past cycle. It is clear that the financial crisis induced a drop of household real net worth of about 25 percent over the two years prior to the cycle trough in 2009. Since then, while wealth has been rising, it just, early in 2014, reattained its precrisis level. The fact that it has required seven full years for households to regain levels of net worth last seen in 2007 probably has left them cautious and helped to account for the weak performance of consumption over this feeble expansion. Figure 6. Real Net Worth of Household and Nonprofit Organizations, Level Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System A Labor-Unfriendly Expansion The recent expansion has been characterized by especially weak growth of employment and persistence of high unemployment, notwithstanding some progress over the past year. (See figure 7.) Companies have been less than eager to add to their capital stock, and they have also been less than eager to restore levels of employment lost during the financial crisis. Part of the reason may be numerous innovations embodied in labor-saving technologies that reduce the need for labor in the production process. The ability to use smartphones and tablets to manage communication and scheduling without a human assistant come to mind. Figure 7. Civilian Unemployment Rate Source: US Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics Surely, unit labor costs, the difference between real wages and productivity growth over the past cycle, have increased at a very slow pace, about equal to a level a full standard deviation below the level that is normal for postwar expansion. (See figure 8.) Labor-saving technology has enabled firms to expand at a pace sufficient to keep up with tepid aggregate demand growth, using the existing capital stock and less labor.
Recommended publications
  • Deflation: a Business Perspective
    Deflation: a business perspective Prepared by the Corporate Economists Advisory Group Introduction Early in 2003, ICC's Corporate Economists Advisory Group discussed the risk of deflation in some of the world's major economies, and possible consequences for business. The fear was that historically low levels of inflation and faltering economic growth could lead to deflation - a persistent decline in the general level of prices - which in turn could trigger economic depression, with widespread company and bank failures, a collapse in world trade, mass unemployment and years of shrinking economic activity. While the risk of deflation is now remote in most countries - given the increasingly unambiguous signs of global economic recovery - its potential costs are very high and would directly affect companies. This issues paper was developed to help companies better understand the phenomenon of deflation, and to give them practical guidance on possible measures to take if and when the threat of deflation turns into reality on a future occasion. What is deflation? Deflation is defined as a sustained fall in an aggregate measure of prices (such as the consumer price index). By this definition, changes in prices in one economic sector or falling prices over short periods (e.g., one or two quarters) do not qualify as deflation. Dec lining prices can be driven by an increase in supply due to technological innovation and rapid productivity gains. These supply-induced shocks are usually not problematic and can even be accompanied by robust growth, as experienced by China. A fall in prices led by a drop in demand - due to a severe economic cycle, tight economic policies or a demand-side shock - or by persistent excess capacity can be much more harmful, and is more likely to lead to persistent deflation.
    [Show full text]
  • This Is the Heritage Society After All – to 1893, and the Shape of This
    1 IRVING HERITAGE SOCIETY PRESENTATION By Maura Gast, Irving CVB October 2010 For tonight’s program, and because this is the Irving Heritage Society, after all, I thought I’d take a departure from my usual routine (which probably everyone in this room has heard too many times) and talk a little bit about the role the CVB plays in an historical context instead. I’m hopeful that as champions of heritage and history in general, that you’ll indulge me on this path tonight, and that you’ll see it all come back home to Irving by the time I’m done. Because there were really three key factors that led to the convention industry as we know it today and to our profession. And they are factors that, coupled with some amazing similarities to what’s going on in our world today, are worth paying attention to. How We as CVBs Came to Be • The Industrial Revolution – And the creation of manufacturing organizations • The Railroad Revolution • The Panic of 1893 One was the industrial revolution and its associated growth of large manufacturing organizations caused by the many technological innovations of that age. The second was the growth of the railroad, and ultimately the Highway system here in the US. And the third was the Panic of 1893. The Concept of “Associations” 2 The idea of “associations” has historically been an American concept – this idea of like‐minded people wanting to gather together in what came to be known as conventions. And when you think about it, there have been meetings and conventions of some kind taking place since recorded time.
    [Show full text]
  • Research & Policy Brief No.47
    Research & Policy Briefs From the World Bank Malaysia Hub No. 47 May 24, 2021 Demand and Supply Dynamics in East Asia during the COVID-19 Recession Ergys Islamaj, Franz Ulrich Ruch, and Eka Vashakmadze The COVID-19 pandemic has devastated lives and damaged economies, requiring strong and decisive policy responses from governments. Developing Public Disclosure Authorized the optimal short-term and long-term policy response to the pandemic requires understanding the demand and supply factors that drive economic growth. The appropriate policy response will depend on the size and duration of demand and supply shocks. This Research & Policy Brief provides a decomposition of demand and supply dynamics at the macroeconomic level for the large developing economies of East Asia. The findings suggest that both demand and supply shocks were important drivers of output fluctuations during the first year of the pandemic. The demand shocks created an environment of deficient demand—reflected in large negative output gaps even after the unprecedented policy response—which is expected to last through 2021. The extant deficient demand is suggestive of continued need to support the economic recovery. Its size should guide policy makers in calibrating responses to ensure that recovery is entrenched, and that short-term supply disruptions do not lead to long-term declines in potential growth. The Pandemic-Induced Shock Low external demand will continue to affect economies reliant on tourism, while sluggish domestic demand will disproportionally affect The pandemic, national lockdowns, and reverberations from the rest economies with large services sectors. Understanding the demand of the world inflicted a massive shock to the East Asia and Pacific and supply factors that drive economic growth is critical for region in 2020 (World Bank 2020a).
    [Show full text]
  • Rebuilding the Public Sector for Economic Recovery and Resilience
    REBUILDING THE PUBLIC SECTOR FOR ECONOMIC RECOVERY AND RESILIENCE Sara Hinkley, Ph.D. March 2021 Executive Summary As the country crests the most devastating wave yet of the COVID-19 pandemic, there is growing optimism that the new administration will act quickly to stem the economic crisis: both by deploying the federal government’s leadership to control the pandemic itself and by using the federal government’s fiscal capacity to mitigate the economic damage caused by the public health crisis. The Biden administration will need to turn around both of these failures quickly in order to prevent further catastrophe for millions of Americans and a sustained recession. But the disaster unfolding now is not just a result of policy failures over the past eleven months; it is the result of decades of disinvestment and austerity, accelerated during the Great Recession, which made us more vulnerable to this crisis. Local, state, and national austerity set the country up for a harsh, prolonged, and profoundly unequal recession. We face a pivotal moment now: we can repeat those mistakes, leaving us more vulnerable to future crises, or we can build back our public sector to make us more economically resilient. groundworkcollaborative.org REBUILDING THE PUBLIC SECTOR FOR ECONOMIC RECOVERY AND RESILIENCE | 1 It is certainly bad luck that the long-predicted1 economic downturn was sparked by a pandemic, but our failure to meet this crisis with an effective public response is the outcome of years of deliberate policy choices. The austerity implemented after the Great Recession decimated both our ability to weather an economic downturn and our ability to handle any crisis requiring a strong public response.
    [Show full text]
  • Demand Composition and the Strength of Recoveries†
    Demand Composition and the Strength of Recoveriesy Martin Beraja Christian K. Wolf MIT & NBER MIT & NBER September 17, 2021 Abstract: We argue that recoveries from demand-driven recessions with ex- penditure cuts concentrated in services or non-durables will tend to be weaker than recoveries from recessions more biased towards durables. Intuitively, the smaller the bias towards more durable goods, the less the recovery is buffeted by pent-up demand. We show that, in a standard multi-sector business-cycle model, this prediction holds if and only if, following an aggregate demand shock to all categories of spending (e.g., a monetary shock), expenditure on more durable goods reverts back faster. This testable condition receives ample support in U.S. data. We then use (i) a semi-structural shift-share and (ii) a structural model to quantify this effect of varying demand composition on recovery dynamics, and find it to be large. We also discuss implications for optimal stabilization policy. Keywords: durables, services, demand recessions, pent-up demand, shift-share design, recov- ery dynamics, COVID-19. JEL codes: E32, E52 yEmail: [email protected] and [email protected]. We received helpful comments from George-Marios Angeletos, Gadi Barlevy, Florin Bilbiie, Ricardo Caballero, Lawrence Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum, Fran¸coisGourio, Basile Grassi, Erik Hurst, Greg Kaplan, Andrea Lanteri, Jennifer La'O, Alisdair McKay, Simon Mongey, Ernesto Pasten, Matt Rognlie, Alp Simsek, Ludwig Straub, Silvana Tenreyro, Nicholas Tra- chter, Gianluca Violante, Iv´anWerning, Johannes Wieland (our discussant), Tom Winberry, Nathan Zorzi and seminar participants at various venues, and we thank Isabel Di Tella for outstanding research assistance.
    [Show full text]
  • Creating the Fastest Economic Recovery
    x Chapter 1 Creating the Fastest Economic Recovery The beginning of 2020 ushered in a strong U.S. economy that was delivering job, income, and wealth gains to Americans of all backgrounds. By February 2020, the unemployment rate had fallen to 3.5 percent—the lowest in 50 years— and unemployment rates for minority groups and historically disadvantaged Americans were at or near their lowest points in recorded history. Wages were rising faster for workers than for managers, income and wealth inequality were on the decline, and median incomes for minority households were experienc- ing especially rapid gains. The fruits of this strong labor market expansion from 2017 to 2019 also included lifting 6.6 million people out of poverty, which is the largest three-year drop to start any presidency since the War on Poverty began in 1964. These accomplishments highlight the success of the Trump Administration’s pro-growth, pro-worker policies. The robust state of the U.S. economy in the three years through 2019 led almost all forecasters to expect continued healthy growth through 2020 and beyond. However, in late 2019 and the early months of 2020, the novel coronavirus that causes COVID-19, with origins in the People’s Republic of China, began spreading around the globe and eventually within the United States, causing a pandemic and bringing with it an unprecedented economic and public health crisis. Both the demand and supply sides of the economy suffered sudden and massive shocks due to the pandemic. During the springtime lockdowns aimed at “flattening the curve,” the labor market lost 22.2 million jobs, and the unemployment rate jumped 11.2 percentage points, to 14.7 percent—the largest monthly changes in the series’ histories.
    [Show full text]
  • Deflation: Economic Significance, Current Risk, and Policy Responses
    Deflation: Economic Significance, Current Risk, and Policy Responses Craig K. Elwell Specialist in Macroeconomic Policy August 30, 2010 Congressional Research Service 7-5700 www.crs.gov R40512 CRS Report for Congress Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress Deflation: Economic Significance, Current Risk, and Policy Responses Summary Despite the severity of the recent financial crisis and recession, the U.S. economy has so far avoided falling into a deflationary spiral. Since mid-2009, the economy has been on a path of economic recovery. However, the pace of economic growth during the recovery has been relatively slow, and major economic weaknesses persist. In this economic environment, the risk of deflation remains significant and could delay sustained economic recovery. Deflation is a persistent decline in the overall level of prices. It is not unusual for prices to fall in a particular sector because of rising productivity, falling costs, or weak demand relative to the wider economy. In contrast, deflation occurs when price declines are so widespread and sustained that they cause a broad-based price index, such as the Consumer Price Index (CPI), to decline for several quarters. Such a continuous decline in the price level is more troublesome, because in a weak or contracting economy it can lead to a damaging self-reinforcing downward spiral of prices and economic activity. However, there are also examples of relatively benign deflations when economic activity expanded despite a falling price level. For instance, from 1880 through 1896, the U.S. price level fell about 30%, but this coincided with a period of strong economic growth.
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Crisis, Whether They Have a Pattern?
    The 2nd ICVHE The 2nd International Conference on Vocational Higher Education (ICVHE) 2017 “The Importance on Advancing Vocational Education to Meet Contemporary Labor Demands” Volume 2018 Conference Paper Economic Crisis, Whether They Have a Pattern?—A Historical Review Rahmat Yuliawan Study Program of Secretary and Office Management, Faculty of Vocational Studies Airlangga University Abstract Purpose: The global economic recession appeared several times and became a dark history and tragedy for the world economy; the global economic crisis emerged at least 15 times, from the Panic of 1797, which lasted for recent years, to the depression in 1807, Panics of 1819, 1837, 1857, 1873, or the most phenomenal economic crisis known as the prolonged depression. This depression sustained for a 23-year period since 1873 to 1896. The collapse of the Vienna Stock Exchange caused the economic depression that spread throughout the world. It is very important to note that this phenomenon is inversely proportional to the incident in the United States, where at this period, the global industrial production is increasing rapidly. In the United States, for Corresponding Author: example, the production growth is over four times. Not to mention the panic in 1893, Rahmat Yuliawan Recession World War I, the Great Depression of 1929, recession in 1953, the Oil Crisis of Received: 8 June 2018 1973, Recession Beginning in 1980, reviewer in the early 1990s, recession, beginning Accepted: 17 July 2018 in 2000, and most recently, namely the Great Depression in 2008 due to several Published: 8 August 2018 factors, including rising oil prices caused rise in the price of food around the world, Publishing services provided by the credit crisis and the bankruptcy of various investor banks, rising unemployment, Knowledge E causing global inflation.
    [Show full text]
  • Recovery from the Great Depression in the United States, Britain and Germany
    Recovery from the Great Depression in the United States, Britain and Germany Donghyu Yang* June 1995 WP 9503 This paper was written while I was visiting the John F. Kennedy Institute for North American Studies, Free University of Berlin. I thank the Alexander von Humboldt Foundation for their support which made my visit possible, and Carl-L. Holtfrerich, Raymond Stokes and Peter Temin for their valuable comments. All remaining errors are mine. Recovery from the Great Depression in the United States, Britain and Germany Abstract This paper examines the process of the recovery from the Great Depression in the United States, Britain and Germany in a comparative perspective. The U.S. and German governments spent more actively, while all three countries manifested monetary ease. This expansionary switch was made possible by currency devaluation (Britain and U.S.) or by exchange control (Germany), though the banking sector remained passive in industrial finance in Germany. Investment allocation, in particular, was more favorable to recovery in the U.S., and perhaps to a larger extent in Germany, where the Motorisierung and rearmament had greater repercussion effect to boost up total industrial production, partly because Britain suffered a long run depression of a more "structural' character. Donghyu Yang Department of Economics John F. Kennedy Intitute Seoul National University Free University of Berlin tel 02-880-6375 tel 030-822-3434 fax 02-888-4454 fax 030-822-8877 I. Issues Since the relative stagnation of the world economy from the mid 1970s, economists have revived their interests in the Great Depression of the 1930s, if only because of its probable relevance to the contemporary problems.
    [Show full text]
  • It's Not Stagflation
    MAY 27, 2021 CAPITAL MARKETS RESEARCH WEEKLY MARKET It’s Not Stagflation OUTLOOK MAY 27, 2021 The U.S. is not currently experiencing stagflation, and it’s not going to over Table of Contents Lead Author the next couple of years. The debate Ryan Sweet about stagflation is going to intensify Top of Mind ...................................... 4 Senior Director-Economic Research over the next few months as growth in 610-235-5213 Week Ahead in Global Economy ... 6 [email protected] consumer prices continues to accelerate. However, there are a ton of Geopolitical Risks ............................ 7 Asia-Pacific temporary factors behind the Katrina Ell acceleration and recent gains in the CPI Economist The Long View are concentrated in the most volatile U.S. ................................................................. 8 Shahana Mukherjee components. This is likely not Europe ......................................................... 10 Economist sustainable; it is attributable to the Asia-Pacific .................................................. 11 reopening of the economy. Europe Ross Cioffi Ratings Roundup ........................... 12 Economist Still, a stagflation debate will occur, and Katrina Pirner there won’t be a consensus. Some Market Data ................................... 15 Economist define stagflation as weaker growth and accelerating inflation. The weaker-than- CDS Movers .................................... 16 U.S. expected job growth in April and string Adam Kamins Issuance .......................................... 18 Economist of disappointing economic data coupled with the April CPI have some believing Steve Shields their criteria for stagflation has been Economist met. Ryan Kelly Data Specialist However, we believe this definition is too loose. Periods of stagflation occur when there is Editor high unemployment and high inflation. Inflation isn’t high. We calculated z-scores—a Reid Kanaley measure of the standard deviations above or below the mean—for the headline and core CPI, and they are the highest since oil prices jumped in 2008.
    [Show full text]
  • The Great Depression: an Overview by David C
    Introduction The Great Depression: An Overview by David C. Wheelock Why should students learn about the Great Depression? Our grandparents and great-grandparents lived through these tough times, but you may think that you should focus on more recent episodes in Ameri- can life. In this essay, I hope to convince you that the Great Depression is worthy of your interest and deserves attention in economics, social studies and history courses. One reason to study the Great Depression is that it was by far the worst economic catastrophe of the 20th century and, perhaps, the worst in our nation’s history. Between 1929 and 1933, the quantity of goods and services produced in the United States fell by one-third, the unemployment rate soared to 25 percent of the labor force, the stock market lost 80 percent of its value and some 7,000 banks failed. At the store, the price of chicken fell from 38 cents a pound to 12 cents, the price of eggs dropped from 50 cents a dozen to just over 13 cents, and the price of gasoline fell from 10 cents a gallon to less than a nickel. Still, many families went hungry, and few could afford to own a car. Another reason to study the Great Depression is that the sheer magnitude of the economic collapse— and the fact that it involved every aspect of our economy and every region of our country—makes this event a great vehicle for teaching important economic concepts. You can learn about inflation and defla- tion, Gross Domestic Product (GDP), and unemployment by comparing the Depression with more recent experiences.
    [Show full text]
  • LESSONS from the GREAT DEPRESSION for ECONOMIC RECOVERY in 2009 Christina D
    LESSONS FROM THE GREAT DEPRESSION FOR ECONOMIC RECOVERY IN 2009 Christina D. Romer Council of Economic Advisers As prepared for presentation at the Brookings Institution, Washington, D.C., March 9, 2009 In the last few months, I have found myself uttering the words "worst since the Great Depression" far too often: the worst twelve month job loss since the Great Depression; the worst financial crisis since the Great Depression; the worst rise in home foreclosures since the Great Depression. In my previous life, as an economic historian at Berkeley, one of the things I studied was the Great Depression. I thought it would be useful to reflect on that episode and what lessons it holds for policymakers today. In particular, what can we learn from the 1930s that will help us to end the worst recession since the Great Depression? To start, let me point out that though the current recession is unquestionably severe, it pales in comparison with what our parents and grandparents experienced in the 1930s. Last Friday’s employment report showed that unemployment in the United States has reached 8.1%—a terrible number that signifies a devastating tragedy for millions of American families. But, at its worst, unemployment in the 1930s reached nearly 25%.1 And, that quarter of American workers had painfully few of the social safety nets that today help families maintain at least the essentials of life during unemployment. Likewise, following last month’s revision of the GDP statistics, we know that real GDP has declined almost 2% from its peak. But, between the peak in 1929 and the trough of the great Depression in 1933, real GDP fell over 25%.2 I don’t give these comparisons to minimize the pain the United States economy is experiencing today, but to provide some crucial perspective.
    [Show full text]