Capital Accumulation on the Transition Path in a Monetary Optimizing Model

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Capital Accumulation on the Transition Path in a Monetary Optimizing Model Capital Accumulation on the Transition Path in a Monetary Optimizing Model Stanley Fischer Econometrica, Vol. 47, No. 6. (Nov., 1979), pp. 1433-1439. Stable URL: http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0012-9682%28197911%2947%3A6%3C1433%3ACAOTTP%3E2.0.CO%3B2-N Econometrica is currently published by The Econometric Society. Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/about/terms.html. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at http://www.jstor.org/journals/econosoc.html. Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. The JSTOR Archive is a trusted digital repository providing for long-term preservation and access to leading academic journals and scholarly literature from around the world. The Archive is supported by libraries, scholarly societies, publishers, and foundations. It is an initiative of JSTOR, a not-for-profit organization with a mission to help the scholarly community take advantage of advances in technology. For more information regarding JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. http://www.jstor.org Wed Oct 3 08:43:20 2007 Econornetrica, Vol. 47, No. 6 (November, 1979) CAPITAL ACCUMULATION ON THE TRANSITION PATH IN A MONETARY OPTIMIZING MODEL It is well known that in the Sidrauski monetary intertemporal optimizing model the steady state capital stock is invariant to the rate of inflation. This paper shows that the rate of accumulation of capital is not invariant to the rate of inflation and that, for the constant relative risk aversion family of utility functions (except logarithmic), the rate of capital accumulation is faster the higher the growth rate of money. Money is thus not neutral on transition paths. THE EFFECTS of anticipated inflation on capital accumulation are central to a number of papers, including those of Tobin [9] and Sidrauski [8].' However, the theoretical validity of the link between inflation and capital accumulation was called into question by Sidrauski's [7] demonstration that money is superneutral (the growth rate of money affects no real variables other than real balances) in his model in which infinitely lived families maximize an intertemporal utility function. In particular, Sidrauski showed that the steady state capital stock for such families is determined by the modified golden rule: the steady state capital stock is such that the real interest rate is equal to the rate of population growth plus the rate of time preference. The rate of inflation or the growth rate of money affects only the steady state level of real balances, but not the per capita steady state levels of the capital stock or consumption. The Sidrauski superneutrality result depends on the infinite horizon assump- tion, since superneutrality does not generally obtain in overlapping generations models in which money and capital are the only assek3 Further, even in the infinite horizon case, relatively simple changes such as including money in the production function, as shorthand for the fact that larger holdings of real balances facilitate transaction^,^ or the inclusion of an endogenous labor supply (Brock [I]), remove the superneutrality result. This note focuses on the transition to the steady state, rather than on the properties of the steady state itself. It shows that even in the original Sidrauski maximizing model, the path the economy takes to the steady state is not in general independent of the growth rate of money. The rate of capital accumulation may be affected by the rate of inflation everywhere but in steady state. The model and the first order conditions are set out in Section 1.Section 2 then shows that there is a unique convergent equilibrium path. Section 3 shows that the conventional 'I am grateful to Andrew Abel, Guillermo Calvo, Rudiger Dornbusch, Robert Solow, and the referees for their comments. Research support from the NSF is acknowledged with thanks. See Dornbusch and Frenkel [3]; recently Lucas [6] and Fischer [5] have explored this effect in rational expectations models. See Drazen [4]. Though this change does not generally imply that a higher capital stock accompanies a higher inflation rate in steady state. 1434 STANLEY FISCHER presumption-that more rapid monetary growth produces more rapid capital accumulation-holds true if utility functions belong to the constant relative risk aversion family. 1. THE MODEL Detailed assumptions are spelled out in Sidrauski [7]. A family, whose membership grows at rate n, maximizes an additive utility function where ct is per capita consumption, m,is per capita real balances, and 6 >0 is the rate of time discount. The instantaneous utility function u()is concave, with ul,2.42 >0 and ull, u22 <0. The family can hold either money or capital; money is introduced into the system through lump sum taxes or transfers. There is a neoclassical production function where k,is the per capita capital stock. Letting 17 be the expected rate of inflation we can write the first order conditions for an optimal path as: Equation (5')is the budget constraint that the household faces: x is the per capita rate of real money transfers which are assumed by each household to be independent of its own holdings of money.' In steady state C = 0 = m ;substituting (4)into (3)we obtain the superneutrality result: On any path on which the actual rate of inflation (@/p)is continuous, and assuming a constant growth rate of money, 8, we have: We shall be working with perfect foresight equilibrium paths where If the household regarded x as interest payments on money, and we wrote x = Om,where B is the growth rate of money, then money would be superneutral. Under this assumption we would have (17- 0)in (3)and (4)where 17 appears now. CAPITAL ACCUMULATION 1435 On such paths, the expected and actual inflation rates coincide. In addition, on equilibrium paths, the economy wide constraint that physical output is either consumed or invested binds in the sense that consumption and investment demands, derived from (3)-(59, sum to full employment output. Using the perfect foresight and equilibrium assumptions, we use (7) and (8)to substitute out for 17 in (3) and (4) and m and x( = Om) in (5'). Now (5') becomes By examining the perfect foresight path, we assure ourselves that our results are not due to any ad hoc expectations assumptions, but rather follow from the logic of the maximizing model itself. 2. UNIQUENESS OF THE OPTIMAL PATH Substituting (7) and (8)into (3) and (4), and linearizing around the steady state, we obtain: where we further assume6 and Asterisks in (9) denote steady state values of variables, and all derivatives are evaluated as those steady state values, c*, m*, and k*. The first step is to establish that the matrix in (9) has a unique negative root and thus that the steady state is a saddle-point. The product of the roots of the system is given by the determinant This establishes that there are either three negative roots (two of which may be complex with real parts negative) or one. To establish that there is only one negative root, we turn to a necessary condition for stability of a 3 x 3 system, These assumptions ensure that both consumption and real balances are normal goods. 1436 STANLEY FISCHER namely that the trace of the matrix (2)be negative. If Z is to be negative, then has to be negative. However is of the same sign as uIIu~~-uf2,which, by virtue of the concavity of u( ), is positive. Accordingly the differential equation system (9)is unstable, implying it has at least one positive root. But since we know it has either zero or two positive roots, it has two. There is therefore a unique negative root, and a unique perfect foresight path satisfying the necessary conditions (3)-(5)that converges to the steady state.7 Brock [I]shows in a similar context that the convergent path is the unique equilibrium perfect foresight path, and we henceforth, consider only that path.8 3. CHANGES IN THE GROWTH RATE OF MONEY To establish that the dynamic path of the economy is affected by the growth rate of money, we have to show that the unique negative root of the dynamic system is affected by the growth rate of money. Rather than work with a general utility function, which would require us to examine explicitly third derivatives of the utility function, we specialize to the constant relative risk aversion family: For R = 1,we have the logarithmic utility function, u(c, m)= a In c +p In m. The characteristic equation for the system becomes: 'An alternative proof of the saddle-point property is given in Calvo [Z],under the assumption ul2>0. However, I have not established that the unique convergent perfect foresight path is the only equilibrium path under the assumptions of this paper. CAPITAL ACCUMULATION 1437 We have taken care to write (13) as a function of c* and k* (through f"), which remain invariant across steady states as 19 changes, and of 19 itself. We will thus be able to examine the effects of changes in 8 on the negative root. Note that (8+6)>0 by assumption, so that we have less than the optimum quantity of money.9 We may write the characteristic equation equivalently as We are interested in where it is understood the derivatives are to be evaluated at the negative root.
Recommended publications
  • Endogenous Growth Theory and Models: the “First Wave”, 1952–1973
    Macroeconomic Dynamics Survey: Endogenous Growth Theory and Models: the “First Wave”, 1952–1973 Stephen E. Spear and Warren Young Introduction: scope and method In previous papers (Spear and Young 2014, 2015a, 2015b), we surveyed the origins, evolution and dissemination of optimal growth, two sector and turnpike, and stochastic growth models. In this paper, we focus on endogenous growth theory and models. However, in contrast to our previous findings regarding optimal growth theory and its offshoots, which exhibited fairly direct lines of conceptual development, the endogenous growth story, as will be seen, is multifaceted, with a more complex pattern of intellectual evolution. Our object here is not to provide a history of endogenous growth per se, as a number of conventional narratives have already appeared in the literature since 1990, including by those involved - - indirectly or directly - - in its evolution. These range from accounts presented in working and published papers, to survey articles, Festschrift chapters and textbooks (Dixit 1990; Stiglitz 1990; Aghion and Howitt 1998, Aghion, and Howitt 2006, Aghion and Durlauf 2007; Romer 1994, 2014, among others). Rather, the approach taken here focuses on individual, institutional, and thematic research programs related to the development of endogenous growth. Individual programs were those where one or more researchers were involved and based upon dissertations or collaborative efforts, such as between graduate students and their supervisors, or colleagues. Institutional programs originated in specific settings -- seminars, workshops, research centers and sponsored projects, and intra- or inter- university collaboration. Thematic programs reflected focus on specific theoretical elements or their combination such as technology and innovation, learning processes, externalities and returns, the nature of competition, and human capital.
    [Show full text]
  • Sintetizado De
    SINTETIZADO DE De Pablo, J. C. (1995): Héctor Luis Diéguez, Miguel Sidrauski y los comienzos de la licenciatura en economía en Argentina, Sudamericana. MIGUEL SIDRAUSKI (12 de octubre de 1939 - 1 de setiembre de 1968) 1. VIDA 75 minutos antes de que expirara el 12 de octubre de 1939 mamá Sofía (Zangier, polaca, de 36 años) olvidó los dolores del parto, al escuchar el llanto con que el recién nacido, cabeza abajo, protestó porque le pegaron en la cola. En la sala de espera del Instituto de Maternidad, papá Sani (Sidrauski, también polaco, 37 años), respiró aliviado luego de horas de lógica tensión. Esa noche, en Espinosa 1936, las luces se apagaron más tarde que de costumbre. Había nacido Miguel, el primer y único hijo de ambos1. Al parecer, Sani Sidrauski (hijo de Abraham Sidrauski y María Lew) y Sofía Zangier (hija de David Zangier y Raquel Belsberg) llegaron a Argentina escapando de la miseria reinante en Polonia, y no del nazismo. Su castellano era muy rudimentario. Componían el resto de la familia una tía (materna) y un abuelo, quienes atendían un puesto en el Mercado Municipal ubicado en Velasco y Malabia ("la falta de tíos, y de parientes en general, era uno de nuestros temas de conversación", recuerda Jane Wicnudel). Su padre murió cuando Miguel tenía 8 años. La mamá volvió a casarse. Miguel no tuvo una buena relación con su padrastro, Osías Schmahl, a quien llamaba tío (no era verdadero tío, como creía una de mis entrevistadas)2. Afortunadamente para la profesión, Sidrauski ignoró el consejo del padrastro para que en la UBA continuara en el plan de estudios D (carrera de contador público), pasándose al plan E (carrera de licenciado en economía, que se acababa de crear).
    [Show full text]
  • Curriculum Vitae for James J. Heckman
    September 13, 2021 James Joseph Heckman Department of Economics University of Chicago 1126 East 59th Street Chicago, Illinois 60637 Telephone: (773) 702-0634 Fax: (773) 702-8490 Email: [email protected] Personal Date of Birth: April 19, 1944 Place of Birth: Chicago, Illinois Education B.A. 1965 (Math) Colorado College (summa cum laude) M.A. 1968 (Econ) Princeton University Ph.D. 1971 (Econ) Princeton University Dissertation “Three Essays on Household Labor Supply and the Demand for Market Goods.” Sponsors: S. Black, H. Kelejian, A. Rees Graduate and Undergraduate Academic Honors Phi Beta Kappa Woodrow Wilson Fellow NDEA Fellow NIH Fellow Harold Willis Dodds Fellow Post-Graduate Honors Honorary Degrees and Professorships Doctor Honoris Causa, Vienna University of Economics and Business, Vienna, Austria. Jan- uary, 2017. Doctor of Social Sciences Honoris Causa, Lignan University, Hong Kong, China. November, 2015. Honorary Doctorate of Science (Economics), University College London. September, 2013. Doctor Honoris Causis, Pontifical University, Santiago, Chile. August, 2009. Doctor Honoris Causis, University of Montreal.´ May 2004. 1 September 13, 2021 Doctor Honoris Causis, Bard College, May 2004. Doctor Honoris Causis, UAEM, Mexico. January 2003. Doctor Honoris Causis, University of Chile, Fall 2002. Honorary Doctor of Laws, Colorado College, 2001. Honorary Professor, Jinan University, Guangzhou, China, June, 2014. Honorary Professor, Renmin University, P. R. China, June, 2010. Honorary Professor, Beijing Normal University, P. R. China, June, 2010. Honorary Professor, Harbin Institute of Technology, P. R. China, October, 2007. Honorary Professor, Wuhan University, Wuhan, China, 2003. Honorary Professor, Huazhong University of Science and Technology, Wuhan, China, 2001. Honorary Professor, University of Tucuman, October, 1998.
    [Show full text]
  • Money, Banking, and Capital Formation*
    Working Paper Series This paper can be downloaded without charge from: http://www.richmondfed.org/publications/ This material has been published in the Journal of Economic Theory, v.73, iss. 1, March 1997, pp. 157-82, the only definitive repository of the content that has been certified and accepted after peer review. Copyright and all rights therein are retained by Academic Press. This material may not be copied or reposted without explicit permission. Working Paper 94-5 Money, Banking, and Capital Formation* Stacey L. Schreft and Bruce D. Smith Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond May 1994 Ó1997 by Academic Press IDEAL Abstract We consider a monetary growth model in which banks arise to provide liquidity. In addition, there is a government that issues not only money, but interest-bearing bonds: these bonds compete with capital in private portfolios. When the government fixes a constant growth rate for the money stock, we show that there can exist multiple nontrivial monetary steady states. One of these steady states is a saddle, while the other can be a sink. Paths approaching these steady states can display damped endogenous fluctuations, and development trap phenomena are common. Across different steady states, low capital stocks are associated with high nominal interest rates; the latter signal the comparative inefficiency of the financial system. Also, increase in the steady state inflation rate can easily reduce the steady state capital stock. *Stacey L Schreft is an Associate Research Officer at the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, and Bruce D. Smith is a Professor at Cornell University and a visiting scholar in the Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis.
    [Show full text]
  • December 2010
    May 2021 Assaf Razin: Biographical Notes Family History I am the oldest of three children of my father, Mordechai (“Mussia”) Berezin, and my mother Dora Leibovitch. I spent the first 24 years of my life in my birthplace, Kibbutz Shamir; a rural place in the northeastern part of Israel. These personal biographical notes cover my background from the young age at the kibbutz, through my graduate education at the University of Chicago, the first academic jobs and the major turning points in my adult life. My professional life as an economist is covered in detail in my vitae (see http:// www. tau. ac. il/~ razin). Against expectations that economists' CVs will slip into mathematical formulae already by page five; this 70- page economist's bio does not slip into “Greek letter” academic paper expressions at all. Preface The lives of academic economists (i.e. CVs) typically went like this. He/she graduated from a very prestigious university as the best in their class; had many offers from equally prestigious universities; became an assistant professor at X, tenured at Y; wrote a seminal paper on Z when he/she was W. Served on one or two government panels. Moved to another prestigious university. Wrote another seminal paper. Then wrote a book. And then…this went on and on. You could create a single template, and just input the name of the author, and the titles of the papers, and perhaps only slight differences in age for each of them. Orderly and boring lives are a privilege of rich and orderly societies.
    [Show full text]
  • Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy, and Economic Growth
    Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy and Economic Growth Author(s): Duncan K. Foley, Karl Shell and Miguel Sidrauski Source: Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 77, No. 4, Part 2: Symposium on the Theory of Economic Growth (Jul. - Aug., 1969), pp. 698-719 Published by: The University of Chicago Press Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1829327 Accessed: 21-05-2015 18:36 UTC Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/ info/about/policies/terms.jsp JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. The University of Chicago Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of Political Economy. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 132.236.27.111 on Thu, 21 May 2015 18:36:03 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy and Economic Growth Duncan K. Foley,Karl Shell, and Miguel Sidrauski MassachusettsInstitute of Technology 1. Introduction Therehave been two broad strategicapproaches to the studyof economic growth.The first,exemplified by Solow's paper(1956), attemptsto explain how an enterpriseeconomy will grow, given its technology and the market behaviorof its consumers.The second approach,exemplified by Ramsey (1928), attemptsto determinean optimaldevelopment strategy for a fully plannedeconomy, given its technologicalconstraints.
    [Show full text]
  • Dieguez Y Sidrauski, a Medio Siglo Del Fallecimiento De Miguel
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics de Pablo, Juan Carlos Working Paper Dieguez y Sidrauski, a medio siglo del fallecimiento de Miguel Serie Documentos de Trabajo, No. 647 Provided in Cooperation with: University of CEMA, Buenos Aires Suggested Citation: de Pablo, Juan Carlos (2018) : Dieguez y Sidrauski, a medio siglo del fallecimiento de Miguel, Serie Documentos de Trabajo, No. 647, Universidad del Centro de Estudios Macroeconómicos de Argentina (UCEMA), Buenos Aires This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/203788 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu UNIVERSIDAD DEL CEMA Buenos Aires Argentina Serie DOCUMENTOS DE TRABAJO Área: Economía DIEGUEZ Y SIDRAUSKI, A MEDIO SIGLO DEL FALLECIMIENTO DE MIGUEL Juan Carlos de Pablo Agosto 2018 Nro.
    [Show full text]
  • Adaptation of Macro Theory to Rational Expectations
    4\ Adaptation of Macro Theory to Rational Expectations Thomas J. Sargent Long before rational expectations, macroeconomists interpreted time se- ries of aggregate quantities, monetary and fiscal variables, and nominal price levels in ways designed to inform macroeconomic policy decisions.' By im- posing more stringent standards of internal consistency, the 'rational expec- tations movement' caused reformulations of policy questions, a downsizing of the models we believe to be workable, and a heightened modesty about what science can promise economic policy makers. Equilibrium macroeconomics continues 'MIT. economics' in the ways it uses small but self-consistent 'parable' economies to confront broad facts. From the beginning, Solow's one-sector growth model and his growth resid- ual and Samuelson overlapping generations model were the vehicles that drove rational expectations revolutionaries to the front. Many of us regard Lucas's 1972 JET paper as the flagship of the Revolution; it is of different construc- tion than the flagship of that earlier revolution, Keynes's General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, which was ambitious, wide-ranging, im- precise, and vague enough to induce twenty five years of controversy about what the book really meant. Lucas's paper was a narrow, technical study of a modification of Samuelson's parable economy, designed to be a coun- terexample to interpreting a negative unemployment-inflation correlation as something that a particular type of monetary cum fiscal policy could exploit. There was never any confusion about what Lucas's paper meant, any more than there was about Samuelson's or Solow's. If Lucas's paper was slow read- ing for macroeconomists, it was because we were unfamiliar with contraction mappings, and with thinking of equilibria as functions.
    [Show full text]
  • December 2010
    April 2020 Assaf Razin: Biographical Notes The lives of academic economists (i.e. CVs) typically went like this. He/she graduated from a very prestigious university as the best in their class; had many offers from equally prestigious universities; became an assistant professor at X, tenured at Y; wrote a seminal paper on Z when he/she was W. Served on one or two government panels. Moved to another prestigious university. Wrote another seminal paper. Then wrote a book. And then…this went on and on. You could create a single template, and just input the name of the author, and the titles of the papers, and perhaps only slight differences in age for each of them. Orderly and boring lives are a privilege of rich and orderly societies. We all (perhaps except when we are 25) wish to lead such lives. But they are also very limited lives: the range of emotions and choices that we experience is narrow. Branko Milanovic, however, wants to have as our teachers in social science people who had to drink poison to make a point (Socrates), or were jailed and tortured (Machiavelli), or were executed on the orders of a national assembly (Condorcet), or banished and killed by a totalitarian regime (Kondratieff); or those who had to flee their governments and reinvent themselves (Marx), or move into incendiary politics (Weber), or migrate to another language and continent (Schumpeter, Hayek, Kuznets, Leontieff), or experience the thrill of forbidden pleasures (Keynes). My son, Ronny, and my grandson, Iddo, wrote about me: “Assaf Razin's life story is one of extremes.
    [Show full text]
  • Dynamic Technology Augmentation of Solow's Model
    Center for Economic Strategy and Competitiveness Endogenous growth: Dynamic technology augmentation of Solow’s model Murad Kasim [email protected] Sofia University “St. Kliment Ohridski”, 2017 Abstract In this paper, I endeavour to construct a new model, by extending the classic exogenous economic growth model by including a measurement which tries to explain and quantify the size of technological innovation (A) endogenously. ​ ​ I do not agree technology is a “constant” exogenous variable, because it is humans who create all technological innovations, and it depends on how much human and physical capital is allocated for its research. I inspect several possible approaches to do this, and then I test my model both against sample and real world evidence data. I call this method “dynamic” because it tries to model the details in resource allocations between research, labor and capital, by affecting each other interactively. In the end, I point out which is the new residual and the parts of the economic growth model which can be further improved. Page 1 Part I: Introduction 1. The problems of exogenous growth The Solow-Swan model (1956)1 is a simplified way to express economic growth: (1-⍺) ⍺ Y = A × L ​ × K (1) ​ ​ ​ In this model, the following variables are included: L - Labor. Measured in counts of physical people which actively engage in work. ​ ​ ​ A - Technology. A variable explaining technology level, including innovation, ideas, research, ​ ​ ​ know-how. Helps to create more output with the same L and K. ​ ​ ​ ​ K - Physical capital. Measured in consumption goods. ​ ​ ​ ​ ​ H - Human capital. Used as a measure of the cumulative effect of education or training a person has ​ ​ ​ received.
    [Show full text]
  • Balanced Growth and Transitional Dynamics
    Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas presents RESEARCH PAPER No. 9324 A General Two-Sector Model of Endogenous Growth with Human and Physical Capital: Balanced Growth and Transitional Dynamics by EricW.Bond The Pennsylvania State University Ping Wang. Research Department Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas and The Pennsylvania State University ChongK. Yip Georgia State University July 1993 This publication was digitized and made available by the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas' Historical Library ([email protected]) A GBnener TWo-SEcroRMoonr oF ENDoGENoUsGnowrrt WTTTTHuueN AND PI{YSICAL CAPITAL: BalancedGrowth and Transitional Dvnamics Eric W. Bond The Pennsylvania State University Ping Wang The PennsylvaniaState University and Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Chong IC Yip Georgia State University First Draft: December1991 Current Version: June 1993 JEL Classification Number: D90 * We would like to thank John Boyd Itr, David Gould Greg Hufftnan, Ron Jones, Bob King Paul Romer, Karl She[ Alan Stockman, Lori Taylor and Henry Wan, as well as seminar participants at Cornel! Penn State, and Rochester and of the 1992 ASSA Annual Meetings in New Orleans for helpful comments and suggestions on earlier drafts of the paper. Needless to say, the usual disclaimer applies. Address for Correspondence: Eric Bond, Department of Economics, The Pennsylvania State University, University Park, PA 16802; 814-863-0315. The views e4pressedin this article are solely those of the authors and should not be attributed to the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas or to the Federal Resewe Svstem. ABSTRACT This paper studies a general two-sector (goods and education/earning) endogenousgrowth model with general constant-return-to-scale production technologies governing the evolution of human and physical capital stocks.
    [Show full text]
  • Capital Gains, Income, and Saving
    MIT LIBRARIES 3 9080 02878 8112 LIBRARY OF THE MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium IVIember Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/capitalgainsincoOOshel ^mmmw^'^mB^ of economics MASS.IJIST.TECK- CAPITAL GAINS, INCOME, AND SAVINlJ JUL 8 1968 by DEWEY LIBRARY Karl Shell, Miguel Sidrauski, and Joseph E. Stiglitz Number 12 — December 1967 massachusetts institute of technology i 50 memorial drive Cambridge, mass. 02139 MflSSJiiST.TcCK. CAPITAL GAINS, INCOI-ffi, MT) SAVING JUL 8 1968 by DEWEY LIBRARY Karl Shell, Miguel Sidrauski, and Joseph E. Stiglitz Number 12 — December 1967 The views expressed in this paper are the authors' sole responsibility, and do not reflect those of the Department of Economics, nor the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. 1. Introduction Since the General Theory , the consumption function, relating the level of consumption to "income," has been a standard part of macroeconomic theory. In the usual analysis, the measure of "income" that is employed in the determination of the level of consumption is Disposable Income, Why is this chosen as the relevant measure of income? Presumably because the con- sumption function is derived from an aggregation over individual demands, and individuals base their decisions uoon a microeconomic measure of income that is similar to the macroeconomic Disposable Income, But if this is in fact how the consumption function is derived, i.e., if it results from an aggrega- tion over individual demands, then income of individuals is not correctly On the other hand, the consumption function could be thought to be the result of government action.
    [Show full text]