<<

sustainability

Article Over-Agglomeration and Its Effects on : A Case Study on Istanbul

Abdullah Kaya * and Muammer Koc Division of Sustainable Development (DSD), College of Science and Engineering (CSE), Hamad bin Khalifa University (HBKU), Doha 34110, Qatar; [email protected] * Correspondence: [email protected]; Tel.: +90-542-276-9128

 Received: 24 November 2018; Accepted: 23 December 2018; Published: 27 December 2018 

Abstract: Inequality, in any form and dimension, is a major damaging factor for sustainable development. One of the essential drivers of inequality is the over-agglomeration and congestion in a certain region. The reasons for the agglomeration are well documented, such as knowledge-spillovers, access to markets, availability of skilled labor, and good . However, over-agglomeration in a region, mainly triggered by poor and mismanagement of allocation, may also become a barrier for sustainable development. The over-agglomeration generally results in undesired negative effects impeding the economic, social, and environmental development any further, even causing irreversible social and environmental issues. Following the big-push model, a theoretical model is proposed to consider the negative effects of increasing rent due to over-agglomeration first on the industrial development of a country. This is then followed by a case study of Istanbul as a megacity and its effects on Turkey’s sustainable development through industrial, social, and ecological aspects. Istanbul has been the main industrial and economic center of Turkey as the further expanded rapidly in the last 50 years in terms of population and . This over-agglomeration has resulted in very high rent prices in the city compared to the rest of Turkey, which affected the country’s industrialization. The over-agglomeration in Istanbul has also created significant economic imbalances and income-inequalities within the city and across Turkey. The environmental degradation, the loss of forest area, and very high air and noise pollution were other results of the city’s rapid expansion and over-agglomeration. These industrial, social, and environmental dynamics pose serious challenges to Turkey’s sustainable development as long as over-agglomeration in Istanbul persists or even aggravates further.

Keywords: sustainable development; over-agglomeration; industrialization; Istanbul

1. Introduction Sustainable development has been initially defined as “meeting the needs of present without compromising the ability of future generations to meet their needs” by the Brundtland report published in 1987 [1]. Since then, the issue of sustainable development has increasingly attracted the attention of academia, international institutions, and multinational corporations [1]. There are three important pillars of sustainable development, which are the environment, , and society [2]. Fairness and equality in access to basic needs, such as housing, healthcare, security, clean water, and air; equality among genders and races in terms of income, justice, and rights; and preservation of the environment are among the main tenets of sustainable development [3,4]. As a result, equality is one of the most important drivers as well as an indicator of sustainable development [5]. Inequality of any form and dimension is known to be a major damaging factor for sustainable development [6]. Inequality due to structural issues is difficult to overcome and correct, which may hinder the sustainable development permanently [1]. For a given country or region, one of the essential drivers of inequality

Sustainability 2019, 11, 135; doi:10.3390/su11010135 www.mdpi.com/journal/sustainability Sustainability 2019, 11, 135 2 of 23 is the over-agglomeration and congestion around a certain geographic location, such as a city [7]. This particular issue is more of a concern for the sustainable development in emerging due to the increasing number of megacities in those countries [8]. Initial benefits in agglomeration of into a certain region are generally outweighed by congestion, rising costs, and environmental degradation in the later stage [9]. Agglomeration or cluster has been an important research area in since the 1970s. Transaction costs and knowledge spillovers are the key factors in the agglomeration and localization of certain industries in certain parts of a country and the world. By grouping together in close proximity, the firms in certain sectors are able to lower their transaction costs, such as labor and input materials, thanks to [10]. Second, accumulated experience and tacit knowledge are dissipated much faster in local production groups that contribute to significantly [11]. Finally, but not the least, the availability and abundance of skilled labor in the vicinity of the firms is another important factor gained by agglomeration or clustering [12]. All such positive factors and have led to an agglomeration of economic and industrial activities in certain centers or regions across the world usually by forces and natural clustering, but, increasingly, also by government planning and incentives. Nonetheless, the rapid development coupled with the poor (lack of) resource and have led to the problem of “over-agglomeration” in many developing countries, such as Brazil, Mexico, and India [13]. Over time, many in those countries have expanded well beyond their natural zones that resulted in over-agglomeration and congestion in terms of population, transportation, , economic activities, industrial production, and public services. Such over-agglomeration in a city eventually becomes a barrier for the sustainable development in the host country due to waste of limited resources, and economic and social inequality across the regions [8]. For example, an increasing population due to internal to such over-agglomerated megacities necessitated increasing infrastructure needs in transportation, communication, education, healthcare, etc. This has resulted in a further increase in population to uncontrollable levels, and overall life quality for society and individuals is consequently diminished due to increasing congestion, traffic, and pollution [14]. In addition, land prices and other services have become increasingly costly in these areas and factored in production costs of industries in the forms of rental payments, transportation, and costs [15]. All these side effects of over-agglomeration and congestion in megacities pose significant challenges to sustainable development. Over-agglomeration in a megacity can also result in increasing crime rates, social exclusion, high levels, and deteriorating health services for a large section of the society [8]. A case study is then conducted on the effects of Istanbul being a megacity on the city’s industrialization through high rent prices as a result of the over-agglomeration and congestion. There have been a number of industrial sectors agglomerated in various parts of the city, which have over-expanded the city to its geographical borders. A significant amount of Turkey’s human and economic resources are over-agglomerated in Istanbul. This has resulted in significant economic imbalances both in terms of economic size, personal , and income distribution. The city has both the highest personal wealth and income-inequality in Turkey at the same time. The poorest cities of Turkey have very high income-inequality by comparison with Istanbul. High costs of rent for both commercial and residential buildings are among the main recent culprits for the relatively decreasing role of industrial activity in the city. The city’s over-agglomeration and rapid expansion have also caused an environmental degradation in the form of lost forest area [16]. Furthermore, growing economic activity has resulted in an eight times faster growth in a number of motor vehicles than the population of Istanbul within the last 50 years [17]. As a result, widespread traffic congestions have become a critical and daily problem in every part of Istanbul due to insufficient and infrastructure in transportation to meet the demand of such rapid growth [17]. The city suffers heavily from noise pollution and subsequent hearing loss levels on its residents. Istanbul is among the worst cities when it comes to noise pollution and subsequent hearing loss problems as it is Sustainability 2019, 11, 135 3 of 23 ranked fifth out of 50 globally selected cities [18]. Moreover, significant lead times in the transportation of and labor are claimed to contribute to latent or even decreasing productivity levels in cases of over-agglomeration and congestion [19]. Istanbul is among the European cities with the highest air pollution due to road traffic as a result [20]. These three dynamics may play a significantly negative role in the sustainable development pattern of Turkey unless a course of actions is taken immediately. Section2 discusses the existing literature of industrialization and over agglomeration within the context of sustainable development. Section3 lays out the ’s revised version to study the trajectory of industrialization in the case of over-agglomeration. Section4 discusses the case of Istanbul for over-agglomeration and its negative effects on sustainable development, whereas Section5 gives the conclusions and discussions.

2. Over Agglomeration in Mega Cities and the Theory of Big Push for Industrialization The size of a city is regarded as a tradeoff between increasing returns due to agglomeration economies and urban congestion [21]. The agglomeration of economic and industrial activities into a certain city occurs due to a myriad of reasons, such as labor and equipment pooling and access to technical skills, and benefitting from the knowledge spillovers. Furthermore, firms gain the advantage of sharing indivisible goods, accessing special inputs, and attenuating the risk of upfront investment [22,23]. Agglomeration of certain firms, industries, or sectors results in not just input variety and accessibility, but in the availability of various intermediate and final goods as well. As a result, the agents get the benefit of both the economies of scale and scope in the whole production process due to agglomeration [24]. The Big Push Theory has been developed to explain the industrialization dynamics of a from the less-advanced to the advanced economy [25]. The main argument of this theory rests on the fact that a developing country may get stuck in a low level of economic advancement unless it overcomes the high initial cost of investment into certain industrialized sectors. The transition from backward production (constant returns to scale) to industrialized production (advanced and increasing returns to scale) requires a significant upfront investment cost, which may not be recovered if only a few sectors are industrialized [26]. When the initial investment cost for industrialized production is very high (precision equipment, sophisticated operating system, land, skilled labor), there may be no single firm taking such an investment due to insufficient demand and prospects of negative profits. However, when a certain number of firms invest in industrialized production simultaneously, there can be positive profits for each of these firms due to an overall expansion in the economy described as the “Big Push”. This occurs because implementing industrialized production across the whole economy creates demand externalities and enough economic expansion to overcome the initial investment cost by each individual factory production firm [25]. The existing literature has laid out well some reasons for under-industrialization in developing countries, such as the lack of an effective government support [27], inadequate physical and [25], and the size of the domestic economy [15]. However, the role of inflated rent prices due to over-agglomeration has not been studied in detail both theoretically and empirically. This paper attempts to address this perceived gap in the literature of by revisiting the Big Push Model from a rent perspective with a case study of Istanbul’s over-agglomeration. Furthermore, the analysis has been extended to the sustainable development aspects of over-agglomeration in a developing country. There are three pillars of sustainable development, which are economic equality, protection of the environment, and social justice [9]. There is a growing concern that over-agglomeration into certain megacities puts the sustainable development of a country in jeopardy due to economic imbalances across and within the regions, and rapid degradation in the environment as well as increasing pollution [28]. Megacities are growing in number and size across the world and especially in developing countries, which have resulted in serious economic, environmental, and social challenges [29,30]. Analyzing the relationship between the growth of megacities and sustainable development has become a critical subject from all aspects. This paper tries to address this challenge Sustainability 2019, 11, 135 4 of 23 by looking first into the relationship between over-agglomeration and industrialization dynamics with a theoretical analysis. The negative effects of over-agglomeration in a megacity have also been analyzed from an industrial, economic, social, and environmental perspective through a case study on the city of Istanbul.

3. A Model of the Big Push for Over-Agglomeration

3.1. Model Basics and Assumptions The model developed in this section is based on the model of big-push developed by Murphy, Shleifer, and Vishny, denoted as the “MSV model” following the initials of its three authors [25]. As explained earlier, this model presumes that industrialization in a developing country may require a simultaneous push in different sectors at once due to high fixed costs. Acquiring production equipment and further upfront capital investment for technology makes industrialization a costly for a developing country. Therefore, private agents may refrain from taking such an investment due to the concern of never recovering high initial costs in case of insufficient demand. In this instance, the country will be locked up into fringe (unindustrialized) production permanently. Indeed, this is a very likely scenario, which may prompt government intervention [27]. We, nonetheless, focus on not this initial lock-up or failure to industrialize, but the later stage of the process in a developing country. Basically, a model is developed to show that over-agglomeration and congestion in a megacity can stop or even reverse the industrialization trajectory of a developing country. The mechanism that this effect occurs through is the increasing of the fixed cost of industrialization due to high land, rent prices, and living and investment costs in a megacity. In such a close and developing economy, there are K sectors in total, where N of them are produced by using advanced technology and the rest (K-N) are produced by fringe technology. Each sector produces a unique product, which has equal utility with other products from the consumer’s perspective. In each sector, there is either a fringe technology utilizing a firm, or advanced technology utilizing a monopolist firm. While fringe technology utilizing a firm has no significant upfront cost, it has also constant returns to scale production per worker employed. On the other hand, the switch to advanced technology by a firm requires significant upfront (fixed, sunk) cost while that technology provides increasing returns to scale production per worker employed. The assumptions below summarize the main working dynamics of the model for the industrialization pattern of a developing country inspired by the model of MSV.

The Model’s Assumptions A1. Each sector has a fringe firm initially with a potential for an is be denoted by n, and hence the level of industrialization in a developing country is n/k. A2. A fringe firm has the following : Xj = Lj, where X represents the amount of and L represents the number of labor used in sector j. These firms are perfectly competitive and, hence, can enter or exit a sector freely depending on whether this sector is industrialized. A3. A monopolist (advanced) firm has the following production function:

Xa (amount of product) = β * (la (amount of labor utilized) - F (fixed cost in labor equivalent)), where X is the amount of output, β is technological parameter due to advanced utilization with it being greater than 1, L is the amount of labor, and F represents the fixed cost measured here through a unit of labor. It is very obvious that a monopolist firm gets more output per labor employed due to advanced technology utilization while incurring a fixed cost. A monopolist firm will enter a sector only if it makes a profit as opposed to a fringe firm, which has zero profit due to perfect from other fringe firms. A4. Profit of an advanced firm (πa) then becomes: Sustainability 2019, 11, 135 5 of 23

πa = Xa * 1 – la, where la = Xa/β + F from A3 and: 1 + v πa = Xa * (1 – β ) – (1 + v) * F

We also assume that the productivity of labor in the advanced sector (β) is higher than his premium (1 + v), such that an advanced firm makes a profit by employing skilled labor: β > 1 + v. A5. The total number of labor available in the economy is denoted with the parameter, L, and across fringe (unindustrialized) sectors assumed to be equal and normalized to 1 as a numeraire to simplify the analysis. On the other hand, wages in advanced sectors is higher than wages in fringe sectors due to the requirement for highly skilled workers, which dictates higher wages assumed to be 1 + v. A6. Products from each type of firm are almost similar in the sense that consumers will prefer the product of a monopolist firm over a fringe firm, but will not pay a higher . Therefore, the fringe firm is the price setter in each sector. As a result, the price of each product is going to be equal to the wage of labor in the fringe sector due to the assumption. Since we assumed wage equality across all the sectors, the price of each product will also be the same across each sector and equal to 1. A7. A closed economy is assumed with no export, import, or capital movements to simplify the analysis following the literature of industrialization [27]. Consumers also do not save their earnings in the form of wages and spend on goods produced in each sector.

3.2. A Solution of the Model The solution of the model starts with solving the consumer utilization problem to find the bundle of goods yielding the optimal utility based on the available budget and the price of each good. After finding the desired level of goods to be consumed by each consumer, the total level comprising both products of the fringe and advanced production is calculated. The total of the final consumption should be equal to the national output of the economy (Y) in a closed economy. The model does not incorporate for later periods and international (exports and imports). Thus, the final consumption by both private agents and labor is equal to the summation of their profits (agents in advanced production) and wages (labor). Once the national output level (Y) is calculated, the profit of each firm in advanced production (if there any) is calculated. The solution is then extended to the sensitivity analysis of profitability in advanced sectors depending on the fixed cost (F), size of the economy (Y), and productivity level (β) as well as the wage premium paid to labor in advanced sectors (v). The profitability of advanced sectors determines the final number of firms in advanced production (n*) and hence the level of industrialization. Consumers will maximize their utility by consuming a bundle of products produced across k sectors subject to their budgetary constraint:

Max Utility (U) = X1X2 ...Xk (1)

Subject to: P1X1 + P2X2 + . . . + PkXk = L*w

Since we assumed that P1 = P2 = . . . = Pk and w = 1, Taking the derivation of U with respect to the budget constraint yields, the following optimal consumption results: * * * X1 /P1 = X2 /P2 = . . . = Xk /Pk

Consumer utility (U) gets maximized when X1 = X2 = ... = Xk since prices are equal for each product: * * * X1 = X2 = . . . = Xk (2) To find out how much total actual output there will be, we need to calculate how many sectors are industrialized (advanced) in the economy, which is denoted as “n” previously. The reason is that Sustainability 2019, 11, 135 6 of 23 advanced firms have increasing returns to scale, such that their output will be higher than the number of their employees. On the other hand, if there is no industrialization (n = 0), then fringe firms will produce an output equal to the total labor supply (L), and the size of the economy is:

Y (n = 0) = L (3)

Since Y = Wage of total labor (L * 1 = L) + profit of fringe firms (0) To find the demand for each product, X1 + X2 + . . . + Xk = Y; Xi = Y/k = L/k for all i’s. When n > 0, there will be at least partial industrialization in the economy, and to find the total output:

Y = total wage in fringe sectors ((k – n)/k * Y) + total wage in advanced sectors

(L – (k – n)/k * Y) + profit of fringe firms (equal to 0) + profit of advanced firms (n * πa) where we find the profit of advanced firms by using the equation from A4:

1 + v n * πa = n * (Xa * (1− β ) – (1 + v) * F), so Y becomes: (k − n) (k − n) 1 + v Y = k * Y + (1 + v) * (L – k * Y) + n * (Xa * (1 – β ) – (1 + v) * F)

1 + v where Xa = Y/k and assumes 1 – β = α so that Y becomes:

(L − n ∗ F) ∗ k ∗ (1 + v) Y = (4) k ∗ (1 + v) − n ∗ (α + v)

Equation (4) shows the size of an economy with partial industrialization (0 < n < k). It should be noted that L >> n * F, especially for a large country, since L represents the total amount of labor in the economy. Therefore, the economy’s size (Y) grows with more industrialization (higher n) as more value added has been created in the economy. For such an industrialization to occur, the firms should take a decision to invest in industrialized technology. For this to happen, a single firm should be able to foresee a profit (πa ≥ 0) even if there is no other firm willing to invest in industrialized production (n = 1). The necessary level of fixed cost (F) for that profit level required must satisfy the following inequality:

πa = Xa * α − F * (1 + v) ≥ 0, n = 1 (5)

(L − F) ∗ k ∗ (1 + v) when n = 1, the size of the economy (Y) becomes k ∗ (1 + v)− (α + v) after replacing n with 1 in (L − F) ∗ (1 + v) Equation (4). We also know that Xa = Y/k, which is equal to k ∗ (1 + v) − (α + v) , and hence putting this into Equation (5) yields:

(L − F ) ∗ (1 + v) π = 0 ∗ α − (1 + v) ∗ F = 0 a k ∗ (1 + v) − (α + v) 0

L ∗ α F = 0 k ∗ (1 + v) − v) L ∗ α F ≤ F = (6) 0 k ∗ (1 + v) − v)

L ∗ α Proposition 1. Fixed cost (F) should be lower than the threshold fixed cost, (F0 = k ∗ (1 + v) − v) ), in an economy to induce industrialization by the firms (a big push), where even a single firm will be induced to invest into industrialization production regardless of what other firms do. Hence, there will not be a possibility of coordination failure when the fixed cost (F) is so low and promising profits will push all agents simultaneously into industrialization similar to the findings of other studies [27]. We have also shown previously that higher Sustainability 2019, 11, 135 7 of 23 industrialization will lead to higher profits for the firms switching to advanced technology due to the growing size of the economy and subsequent demand for their products. The following graph shows the relationship between the profit per an advanced firm that switched to industrialized production (πa) and the total number of the firms switched into industrialized production (n):

In such an economy, there is only one Nash equilibrium (point A in Figure1) where all the firms Sustainabilityswitch into 2018 industrialized, 10, x FOR PEER (advanced) REVIEW production and all sectors (k) will be industrialized. 7 of 22

Figure 1. Complete industrialization.

For inequality to happen at Equation (6), which indicates the relatively low fixed cost of advanced For inequality to happen at Equation (6), which indicates the relatively low fixed cost of production (F < F0), either population should be very large (L) or the productivity of the advanced advanced production (F < F0), either population should be very large (L) or the productivity of the β (industrialized)advanced (industrialized) sector ( ) mustsector be (β high.) must When be high. none When of these none is theof these case and is the the case fixed and cost the has fixed become cost bigger than the threshold fixed cost (F > F0), a different dynamic in the industrialization pattern of the has become bigger than the threshold fixed cost (F > F0), a different dynamic in the industrialization patterncountry of emerges. the country emerges. Proposition 2. In the case of very high fixed costs, no single firm can foresee a profit by switching into Proposition 2. In the case of very high fixed costs, no single firm can foresee a profit by switching into advanced advanced production in which high upfront investment will not be compensated by insufficient demand. On production in which high upfront investment will not be compensated by insufficient demand. On the other the other hand, a simultaneous investment by a group of firms will expand the economy sufficiently, such that hand, a simultaneous investment by a group of firms will expand the economy sufficiently, such that the high the high initial cost will not be an issue. For all practical purposes, let us assume the actual fixed cost, F, is initial cost will not be an issue. For all practical purposes, let us assume the actual fixed cost, F, is higher than higher than F0 by a cost parameter, C: F0 by a cost parameter, C: ∗ ∗ F = C + F0 = C + L α (7) F = C + F = ∗ (C +) ) (7) 0 k ∗ (1 + v) − v) Based on the previous Equation (5), when there is only a single agent in an industrialized sector with Baseda fixed on cost the (F) previous higher than Equation the threshold (5), when fixed there cost is only (F0), a its single profits agent will in be an negative: industrialized sector with a fixed cost (F) higher than the( threshold ) ∗ ( ) fixed cost (F ), its profits will be negative: πa = * α – (1 + 0v) * (C + F0) < 0, n = 1 (8) ∗ ( ) ( ) (L − F) ∗ (1 + v) In this case,π = no single firm will be willing∗ toα invest− (1 in+ thev) advanced∗ (C + F technology) < 0, n knowing= 1 that his (8) a ∗ ( + ) − ( + ) 0 profits will be negative.k However,1 v if aα certainv number of firms invest in the advanced technologies at once,In they this can case, break no singleeven this firm high will fixed be willing cost (F to = investc * F0). Let in the denote advanced threshold technology number knowing of firms thatneeded his * profitsto invest will into be advanced negative. sectors However, to break if a certain even numberas n such of that: firms invest in the advanced technologies at ( ∗ ∗ ) ∗ ( ) once, they can break even this high fixed cost (F = c * F0). Let denote threshold number* of firms needed πa = ∗ * α – (1+v) * (C + F0) = 0, n= n (9) to invest into advanced sectors to break ∗ ( even) ∗ as ( n *)such that: ( ∗ ∗ ) ∗ ∗ ( ) At industrialization level∗ of n = n*, the size of the economy will become Y = (L − n ∗ F) ∗ (1 + v) ∗ ( ) ∗ ∗ ( ) π = ∗ α − (1 + v) ∗ (C + F ) = 0, n = n∗. (9) and the firmsa can kbreak∗ (1 even+ v )if −theyn∗ switch∗ (α + to vadva) nced technologies by over0 coming high fixed costs (F). Solving the equality at 9 yields the value of n* as:

( ) ∗ ( ) * α – (1 + v) * (F) = 0, which becomes the following: ∗ ( ) ( )

∗ ∗ ∗ ( ) ∗ ( ) ∗ ∗ ( ) ) * α– (C + ) = 0 (10) ∗ ( ) ∗ ∗ ( ) ∗ ()) From Equation (10), after cancelling out same terms from both sides and subsequent simplification, it yields:

∗ ∗ ( ) ∗ ( ) ∗ ∗ ( ) ) * n = ∗ ( ) ∗ ∗ ( ) ∗ ( ) ) Where n* becomes the following after simplifying the term above:

Sustainability 2019, 11, 135 8 of 23

∗ * (L − n ∗ F) ∗ k ∗ (1 + v) At industrialization level of n = n , the size of the economy will become Y = k ∗ (1 + v) − n∗ ∗ (α + v) and the firms can break even if they switch to advanced technologies by overcoming high fixed costs (F). Solving the equality at 9 yields the value of n* as:

(L − F) ∗ (1 + v) ∗ α − (1 + v) ∗ (F) = 0, which becomes the following : k ∗ (1 + v) − (α + v)

( − ∗ ∗ ( + L ∗ α )) ∗ ( + ) L n C k ∗ (1 + v) − v) 1 v L ∗ α ∗ α − (C + ) = 0 (10) k ∗ (1 + v) − n∗ ∗ (α + v) k ∗ (1 + v) − v) From Equation (10), after cancelling out same terms from both sides and subsequent simplification, it yields: ( + L ∗ α ) ∗ ( + ) − ∗ ( + ) ∗ C k ∗ (1 + v) − v) 1 v L 1 v α n∗ = ( − ) ∗ ∗ ( + L ∗ α ) 1 α v C k ∗ (1 + v) − v) * Sustainabilitywhere n becomes 2018, 10, xthe FOR following PEER REVIEW after simplifying the term above: 8 of 22

∗ ((C − L ∗ α)(∗ (k ∗∗ )( ∗1 (+ ∗ (v ) −) ))v)) + ∗ L ∗ ∗( α )) ∗ (1 + v) n = n* = (11) (11) (C ∗ (k ∗ (1+ ∗ (v )∗ (− v))) +) L ∗∗ ) α∗ )( ∗ ()1 ∗ − α) ∗ v

FigureFigure 22 showsshows thethe relationshiprelationship betweenbetween thethe profitprofit perper anan advancedadvanced firmfirm thatthat switchedswitched toto industrializedindustrialized production production ( (ππaa)) and and the the total total number number of of the firms firms switched into industrialized 0 production (n) when the actual fixed fixed cost is greater than the threshold fixedfixed costcost (F(F >> F0).

FigureFigure 2. PotentialPotential equilibria equilibria in in industrialization. industrialization.

WhenWhen fixedfixed costs costs are are too too high, high, no singleno single firm canfirm break caneven break alone even in enteringalone in advanced entering productionadvanced productionwhere its profits where will its profits be negative. will be However, negative. ifHowever, a certain if number a certain of number firms (n of*) enterfirms into(n*) enter advanced into advancedproduction production simultaneously, simultaneously, named as named the big-push, as the bi theyg-push, will they break will even break due even to sufficient due to sufficient growth growthand subsequent and subsequent demand demand in the economy.in the economy. There Th areere two are important two important points points to be to discussed be discussed in this in thiscontext context of big-push of big-push industrialization industrialization dynamics. dynamics. It is very It is difficultvery difficult for firms for tofirms coordinate to coordinate their actions their actionssimultaneously simultaneously considering considering the whole the economy whole econ andomy involved and firmsinvolved for entering firms for advanced entering production advanced productionwhen fixed costswhen are fixed too costs high. are This too problem high. This is called problem a “collective is called action”a “collective problem action” in the problem development in the developmentof economic literatureof economic [27 ,literature31]. For that [27,31]. specific For that reason, specific some reason, scholars some argue scholars whether argue the whether state itself the stateshould itself take should action take by eitheraction entering by either into entering advanced into advanced production production or subsidizing or subsidizing firms to do firms so [13 to, 27do]. so [13,27]. Secondly, if a sufficient number of firms (n*) invests into advanced production and breaks even, then other firms will follow and the country will get industrialized fully. Therefore, points A and B in graph 2 are both Nash equilibria and a number of factors could dictate in which a developing country will settle.

3.3. A Modification to the Model Based on the Dynamics of a Developing Country In the previous section, the fixed costs (F) of a firm switching to advanced production was assumed to be static irrespective of industrialization dynamics of the country. Many initial expenditures for setting up an advanced production are bundled into this fixed cost in the analysis above. These expenditures are mainly capital equipment, technology acquisition, and physical facilities along with the land [25]. However, that fixed cost may change and behave in a dynamic pattern in the case of over-agglomeration and congestion [15]. This may impede the industrialization dynamics of the particular country. It is very probable that once a city reaches its natural borders due to economic activity and expansion, rent prices may start increasing rapidly. This may then make an initial investment into new (industrialized) production costlier compared to the previous case. The increase in cost would not just be an increase in the land price of the production facility, but the cost of all other services (labor and capital) due to congestion in the city. Indeed, this phenomenon has been observed in many

Sustainability 2019, 11, 135 9 of 23

Secondly, if a sufficient number of firms (n*) invests into advanced production and breaks even, then other firms will follow and the country will get industrialized fully. Therefore, points A and B in graph 2 are both Nash equilibria and a number of factors could dictate in which a developing country will settle.

3.3. A Modification to the Model Based on the Dynamics of a Developing Country In the previous section, the fixed costs (F) of a firm switching to advanced production was assumed to be static irrespective of industrialization dynamics of the country. Many initial expenditures for setting up an advanced production are bundled into this fixed cost in the analysis above. These expenditures are mainly capital equipment, technology acquisition, and physical facilities along with the land [25]. However, that fixed cost may change and behave in a dynamic pattern in the case of over-agglomeration and congestion [15]. This may impede the industrialization dynamics of the particular country. It is very probable that once a city reaches its natural borders due to economic activity and expansion, rent prices may start increasing rapidly. This may then make an initial investment into new (industrialized) production costlier compared to the previous case. The increase in cost would not just be an increase in the land price of the production facility, but the cost of all other services (labor and capital) due to congestion in the city. Indeed, this phenomenon has been observed in many developing countries where over-agglomeration and congestion have finally put a dent in the respective city’s industrialization and multi-dimensional sustainable development [32]. Oh (2008) analyzed the effect of congestion on the increase in fixed costs through an increase in labor cost. However, the increased cost of labor due to congestion should not just be represented in the fixed cost of labor, but the overall cost, if it is very important. We take these factors into consideration and propose a newly fixed cost equation while realizing the positive and negative effects of agglomeration simultaneously. In an earlier phase of industrialization, agglomeration of the advanced firms in the same geographic region reduces fixed costs due to easy access to initial labor and a facility site for establishing the production plant or factory [13,27,32]. A firm switching to advanced production would find it easier in access to manufacturing equipment and know-how needed to run the factory in a cluster with the same firms. Specifically, the local or regional governments may also propose incentives for the firms utilizing advanced production in certain locations to attract more firms. This may further decrease the fixed costs of a firm investing in advanced production. However, these kinds of government support are usually phased out once a certain number of firms have switched and the target is met [33]. Once a region has reached its natural geographical limits for industrialization due to agglomeration and clustering of the firms, costs will start increasing rapidly. Land prices will go up for both factory locations and housing of labor. Logistics will become more expensive for transportation of goods, equipment, and labor [15] in addition to the gradual decrease of life quality that will adversely affect further attraction of a skillful workforce. Therefore, the positive benefits of agglomeration will be outweighed by congestion and rapid increases in the cost of doing business, especially those fixed costs. As indicated earlier, a firm usually makes its investment decision irrespective of other firms, and over-agglomeration and congestion generally occur in many industrialized regions of the countries globally [32]. While the current literature has documented well the negative effects of over-agglomeration and congestion on the cost of labor and productivity [15], highly increased land prices and its negative effects on further industrialization are ignored. A modification to the fixed cost (F) has been proposed below to explain this phenomenon theoretically in industrialization dynamics of a developing country. We assume a similarly high fixed cost in Proposition 2 (F = C + F0) initially when there is no firm industrialized (n = 0). However, this high cost starts decreasing by the number of firms switching to industrialized production until agglomeration in a certain region has reached a tipping point. Let us assume that this tipping point is the same number of firms found in Equation (12), where the firms break even at a high fixed Sustainability 2019, 11, 135 10 of 23

cost of F that is n = n*. The inequality below shows the new dynamic fixed cost for an industrializing region that is still under the threshold industrialization level:

k − n F = ∗ (C + F ) for n ≤ n∗ (12) n k 0

∂Fn 1 It is very obvious that ∂n < − k ∗ (C + F0) < 0, which means that the more firms that are switching to industrialized production, the less the fixed cost for those firms will become. In a similar fashion, once the number of firms reaching n = n*, then the fixed cost will start increasing accordingly:

k − n∗ n F = ∗ ∗ (C + F ) for n ≤ n∗ (13) n n∗ k 0

∗ ∂Fn k − n 1 It is very obvious that ∂n < n∗ ∗ k ∗ (C + F0) > 0, which means that the more firms that are switching to industrialized production, the more the fixed cost for those firms will become once a threshold level (n*) is passed. Figure3 shows the new profitability and industrialization dynamics of Sustainabilitythe region 2018 with, 10 new, x FOR fixed PEER cost REVIEW assumed in Inequalities (12) and (13) above. 10 of 22

FigureFigure 3. 3. PotentialPotential equilibria equilibria in in partial partial industrialization. industrialization.

Figure3 illustrates the new dynamics of industrialization in a region of a developing country after Figure 3 illustrates the new dynamics of industrialization in a region of a developing country taking the dynamic nature of fixed cost into account. We assumed the same initial fixed cost, such as in after taking the dynamic nature of fixed cost into account. We assumed the same initial fixed cost, Proposition 2, where a single firm does not break even by switching to advanced production alone. such as in Proposition 2, where a single firm does not break even by switching to advanced This refers to point A in Figure3 and unless a group of firms moves simultaneously, the region or even production alone. This refers to point A in Figure 3 and unless a group of firms moves the country may get stuck in a permanent backward economy with no industrialization. It is one of simultaneously, the region or even the country may get stuck in a permanent backward economy the Nash equilibria in this case since no firm will change its decision (whether to switch to advanced with no industrialization. It is one of the Nash equilibria in this case since no firm will change its production) if no any other firm changes its decision. decision (whether to switch to advanced production) if no any other firm changes its decision. Once a sufficient number of firms collaborate to invest into industrialized production Once a sufficient number of firms collaborate to invest into industrialized production simultaneously or the government takes the initiative [27], then there will be a break even and simultaneously or the government takes the initiative [27], then there will be a break even and the the potential of profit for firms switching to advanced production. A number of firms needed to break potential of profit for firms switching to advanced production. A number of firms needed to break even (n) are less than the number of firms needed to break even in graph 2 (n*), since the fixed cost even (n) are less than the number of firms needed to break even in graph 2 (n*), since the fixed cost (F) decreases with more firms switching to advanced production. However, neither point B or C are (F) decreases with more firms switching to advanced production. However, neither point B or C are in Nash-equilibrium because backward production firms will follow the advanced firms due to the in Nash-equilibrium because backward production firms will follow the advanced firms due to the prospects of higher profits. The switch of more firms into advanced production will increase the profits until point C due to positive externalities and the decreasing fixed costs effect. Profit per the advanced firm will reach a maximum when there is exactly n* firms in industrial production. However, more firms will enter advanced production at point C in Figure 3 due to profits and free entry into the market as assumed earlier. Firms will keep switching to advanced production until profits become zero, which is marked as point D in Figure 3. At this point, no single firm will be enticed to enter advanced production since profits are zero. This point is also a Nash-equilibrium, since no firm will change its position unless another firm changes its position. The most important point to be noted here is that industrialization of the country will be below full industrialization (n < k) at point D due to over-agglomeration and congestion. Therefore, the country will not live up to its potential under increasing fixed costs as opposed to the case of fixed costs in Proposition 2.

4. Over-Agglomeration in Istanbul and Effects on Turkey’s Industrialization Istanbul city has been the main economic, industrial, and cultural center of Turkey for decades. The city’s famous history precedes the current developing country of Turkey by a great margin as it had been home to the Eastern Rome Empire and Ottoman Empire. The city has been strategically located in the northwestern region of the Anatolian peninsula (Asian side) with an equal sized section

Sustainability 2019, 11, 135 11 of 23 prospects of higher profits. The switch of more firms into advanced production will increase the profits until point C due to positive externalities and the decreasing fixed costs effect. Profit per the advanced firm will reach a maximum when there is exactly n* firms in industrial production. However, more firms will enter advanced production at point C in Figure3 due to profits and free entry into the market as assumed earlier. Firms will keep switching to advanced production until profits become zero, which is marked as point D in Figure3. At this point, no single firm will be enticed to enter advanced production since profits are zero. This point is also a Nash-equilibrium, since no firm will change its position unless another firm changes its position. The most important point to be noted here is that industrialization of the country will be below full industrialization (n < k) at point D due to over-agglomeration and congestion. Therefore, the country will not live up to its potential under increasing fixed costs as opposed to the case of fixed costs in Proposition 2.

4. Over-Agglomeration in Istanbul and Effects on Turkey’s Industrialization Istanbul city has been the main economic, industrial, and cultural center of Turkey for decades. TheSustainability city’s famous2018, 10, x history FOR PEER precedes REVIEW the current developing country of Turkey by a great margin 11 of as 22 it had been home to the Eastern Rome Empire and Ottoman Empire. The city has been strategically inlocated the European in the northwestern side. The city’s region geogra of thephical Anatolian land peninsulasize is around (Asian 5000 side) km with2, which an equal is less sized than section 1% of Turkey’sin the European total land side. area. The While city’s the geographical city occupies land less size than is around 1% of 5000the total km2 land, which area is of less Turkey, than 1% it ofis Turkey’shome to 18.5% total land of the area. total While population the city of occupies the country. less than The 1% city of has the 27 total times land of area the ofaverage Turkey, population it is home densityto 18.5% of of Turkey. the total The population city also of hosts the country. the highly The strategic city has 27Bosporus times of Strait, the average which populationis the only densitygate to theof Turkey. Black sea The (Figure city also 4). hostsThe city’s the highly historical strategic and geographical Bosporus Strait, importance which is is the coupled only gate further to the with Black its beautifulsea (Figure nature4). The that city’s hosts historical various andlakes geographical and forests. As importance a result, this is coupled splendid further city has with been its the beautiful crown jewelnature of that the hosts Turkish various Republic lakes andsimilar forests. to precedin As a result,g empires. this splendid The city city is has a beenmagnet the crownfor tourists, jewel businessmen,of the Turkish labor, Republic craftsmen, similar toand preceding so many empires.others, who The have city is made a magnet it one for of tourists, the megacities businessmen, of the 21stlabor, century. craftsmen, and so many others, who have made it one of the megacities of the 21st century.

FigureFigure 4. 4. GeographicalGeographical location location and and size size of of Istanbul Istanbul (blue) (blue) in Turkey’s city map (Tuik.gov).

Due to its favorable geographic location, the posi positioningtioning of Turkish capitalcapital class, support of the state in the forms of of infrastructure, infrastructure, and industrial , Istanbul has been the economic center of modern Turkey in an increasingincreasing capacity [[34].34]. Espe Especiallycially since since World World War War II, there has been a constant inward inward immigration immigration toward towardss Istanbul Istanbul from from all all other other parts parts ofof Turkey Turkey that that has has not not stopped stopped in thein the 21st 21st century century [35]. [ As35]. a result, As a result, the frontiers the frontiers of the city of thehave city kept have growing kept growingand stretched and to stretched Istanbul’s to bordersIstanbul’s from borders almost from all almostdirections, all directions, also with alsoan increasing with an increasing rate [36]. rateFigure [36 5]. shows Figure 5the shows rapid the increase rapid in Istanbul’s population and its share in Turkey’s total population, which have both increased continuously in the last 65 years. This huge growth in population has actually been spurred by the rapidly growing economic activity in Istanbul that has acted as a magnet for people from the rest of the Turkey [34]. Istanbul is roughly responsible for a one third of Turkey’s total economic activity, especially for industrial and services sectors, as shown in Figure 6.

Sustainability 2019, 11, 135 12 of 23 increase in Istanbul’s population and its share in Turkey’s total population, which have both increased continuously in the last 65 years. This huge growth in population has actually been spurred by the rapidly growing economic activity in Istanbul that has acted as a magnet for people from the rest of the Turkey [34]. Istanbul is roughly responsible for a one third of Turkey’s total economic activity, Sustainability 2018, 10, x FOR PEER REVIEW 12 of 22 especiallySustainability for2018 industrial, 10, x FOR PEER and REVIEW services sectors, as shown in Figure6. 12 of 22 16,000,000 40 16,000,000 40 14,000,000 35 14,000,000 35 Istanbul Population 12,000,000 30 Istanbul Population 12,000,000 30 10,000,000 25 As % of Turkey's 10,000,000 25 AsPopulation % of Turkey's 8,000,000 20 Population Linear (Istanbul 8,000,000 20 LinearPopulation) (Istanbul

Population 6,000,000 15 Population)

Population 6,000,000 15 Linear (As % of 4,000,000 10 LinearTurkey's (As Population) % of 4,000,000 10 2,000,000 5 Turkey's Population) 2,000,000 5 0 0 0 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 20200 1950 1960 1970 1980Years 1990 2000 2010 2020 Years

Figure 5. Istanbul’s total population and its share in Turkey’s population (TUIK, 2018). Figure 5. Istanbul’sIstanbul’s total total population population and and its its sh shareare in Turkey’s population (TUIK, 2018).

Share of Istanbul City in Turkey's GDP 2014 Share of Istanbul City in Turkey's GDP 2014 40.00% 40.00% 34.96% 35.00% 34.96% 35.00% 30.46% 28.87% 30.46% 30.00% 28.87% 30.00% 25.00% 25.00% 20.00% 20.00% 15.00% 15.00% 10.00% 10.00% 5.00% 5.00% 0.67% 0.00% 0.67% 0.00% Agriculture Services GDP Agriculture Industry Services GDP FigureFigure 6.6. Istanbul’sIstanbul’s shareshare inin Turkey’sTurkey’s economyeconomy byby sectors,sectors, 20142014 (TUIK).(TUIK). Figure 6. Istanbul’s share in Turkey’s economy by sectors, 2014 (TUIK). ConsideringConsidering itsits vast vast infrastructure infrastructure and highlyand highly developed developed supply chainsupply system, chain it system, is no coincidence it is no thatcoincidence IstanbulConsidering hasthat been itsIstanbul thevast epicenter infrastructurehas been of industrial,the andepicente highly economic,r of developedindustrial, social, and supplyeconomic, cultural chain agglomeration social, system, and it journeycultural is no ofcoincidenceagglomeration Turkey [37 ].that Istanbuljourney Istanbul hasof Turkey actuallyhas been [3 been7]. the Istanbul the epicente engine hasr of actuallyof economic industrial, been and th socialeconomic,e engine activity of social,economic of the and surrounding and cultural social regions,agglomerationactivity suchof the as journeysurrounding the Anatolian of Turkey regions, peninsula, [37]. such Istanbul for as centuries. the has Anatolian actually As discussed beenpeninsula, the earlier, engine for its centuries.of strategiceconomic As location anddiscussed social has givenactivityearlier, the itsof city strategicthe an surrounding immense location advantage hasregions, given such forthe attracting city as thean immense Anatolian business advantage activity,peninsula, which for for attracting hascenturies. never business ceasedAs discussed activity, in both theearlier,which Ottoman hasits strategic never Empire ceased location and in the both has Turkish giventhe Ottoman Republic. the city Empire an An immense important and the advantage reason Turkish for forRepublic. agglomeration attracting An businessimportant in a megacity activity, reason is thewhichfor varietyagglomeration has never of indivisible ceased in a megacityin private both the and is Ottoman the public variety goods Empire of that indivisible and serve the a Turkish benefitprivate toRepublic. and all thepublic agents An goods important in that that city servereason [21 ].a Istanbulforbenefit agglomeration to has all athe significant agents in a megacity in advantage that city is the[21]. in thatvariety Istanbul regard, of hasindivisible since a significant a significant private advantage and size public of thein thatgoods infrastructure regard, that serve since and aa socialbenefitsignificant investments to all size the of agents the have infrastructure beenin that undertaken city [21].and withinsocialIstanbul in thevestments has vicinity a significant ofhave the been city advantage [ 38undertaken]. Table in1 thatbriefly within regard, summarizes the vicinitysince a significantof the city size[38]. of Table the infrastructure 1 briefly summarizes and social the in vestmentsnumber of have units been of indivisibleundertaken goods within in the the vicinity city of ofIstanbul the city and [38]. its Table share 1in briefly Turkey’s summarizes total in addition the numb toer the of factunits that of itindivisible is home togoods around in the15 millioncity of Istanbulpeople as and residents its share and in aroundTurkey’s 20 totalmillion in additiontransiting to or the conducting fact that itbusiness is home in to any around given 15 day million (19% peopleand 25% as of residents the overall and po aroundpulation, 20 millionrespectively). transiti ng or conducting business in any given day (19% and 25% of the overall population, respectively).

Sustainability 2019, 11, 135 13 of 23 the number of units of indivisible goods in the city of Istanbul and its share in Turkey’s total in addition to the fact that it is home to around 15 million people as residents and around 20 million transiting or conducting business in any given day (19% and 25% of the overall population, respectively).

Table 1. List of selected indivisible goods in Istanbul and its share in Turkey.

Indivisible Total Number in Istanbul As a % of Total in Turkey Bank Branches 1730 29.00% Commercial Firms 270,000 29.50% Number of Universities 51 30.00% Number of Hospitals 233 26.60% Number of Art Galleries 68 23.13% Number of Stadiums 27 19.29% Freight Volume Capacity (tons) 6 million 32.43%

Furthermore, the Turkish government continues to gravitate most of the significant infrastructure investments towards Istanbul and its close vicinity, which further increases the agglomeration of the city. Table2 highlights the current major infrastructure spending in Turkey, where Istanbul holds a lion share [39].

Table 2. Current major infrastructure spending in Istanbul and Turkey.

Current Large-Scale Infrastructure Projects in Istanbul and the Rest of Turkey Name of the Project The value in USD Billion As a Percentage Region Third Bosporus Bridge 3.40 Istanbul Third Bridge Connection Roads 2.70 Third Istanbul Airport 6.90 57.98% Istanbul Istanbul Big Tunnel 3.50 Istanbul Eurasia Tunnel 1.20 Istanbul-Ankara High-Speed Railway 3.00 Gebze-Izmir Highway 6.30 Ankara-Nigde Motorway 1.50 42.02% Rest of Turkey Ankara-Sivas High-Speed Railway 1.20 Dardanelles Bridge and Motorway 6.00 Total 35.70 100.00% Total

As a result, Istanbul has become a poly-centric city and home to various industrial clusters specialized in different products and services as a heart of the Turkish economy [23]. Figure7 lists the industrial sectors where there is an agglomeration in the Istanbul (IMA) based on the Ellison Glaeser (EGI) [23]. The EGI shows how much a sector or industry has been localized geographically by calculating each plant’s geographic pattern [23]. The EGI can take values between zero and one. While a zero EGI means no geographical agglomeration of the given industry or sector, complete agglomeration refers to the value of 1 for the EGI. It is straightforward to conclude that Istanbul has been the industrial center of various sectors with strong agglomeration. The city has been the center of the Turkish industry by accommodating various sectors in certain industrial clusters. Istanbul is a polycentric city regarding industrial agglomeration as it is home to various industrial clusters scattered throughout the city. Sustainability 2019, 11, 135 14 of 23 Sustainability 2018, 10, x FOR PEER REVIEW 2 of 22

Sustainability 2018, 10, x FOR PEER REVIEW 2 of 22

25 26 FigureFigure 7.7. SectorsSectors agglomeratedagglomerated inin IstanbulIstanbul basedbased onon thethe EGI.EGI. Considering the small land size of the city compared to Turkey overall, its population, and the level of industrial agglomeration, Istanbul has become overpopulated, congested, and over-agglomerated [40]. As a result, land prices and rents are the highest in Istanbul compared to the other parts of Turkey’s 25 regions. Figure8 shows how much there has been a disparity regarding the rent prices in Istanbul 26 vis-à-vis the rest of TurkeyFigure as of7. Sectors 2017 according agglomerated to Central in Istanbul Bank based of Turkey on the (CBT,EGI. 2017).

27 28 Figure 8. Size of a residential unit for 300,000 Turkish Lira in Turkey [41].

29 Land prices across Istanbul are at minimum twice of the other regions in Turkey, a pattern which 30 is not so different in the industrial and business sectors as well [41]. Transportation time and costs, 2731 services, and utility costs have also increased rapidly in Istanbul due to the over-agglomeration and 32 congestion [42]. ThisFigure has 8. Sizeled to of aexclusion residential of unit some for 300,000sectors Turkishfrom the Lira city in Turkeyto its periphery [41]. while some 28 Figure 8. Size of a residential unit for 300,000 Turkish Lira in Turkey [41]. 33 new sectors have emerged [42]. However, the transfer of some industrial activity has accelerated from 34 IstanbulLand metropolitan prices across area Istanbul while are the at minimumshare of twice of sectors the other increased regions further in Turkey, in athe pattern city’s whichGross 29 Land prices across Istanbul are at minimum twice of the other regions in Turkey, a pattern which 35 isDomestic not so different Production in the (GDP). industrial Figure and 9 businessillustrates sectors this transformation as well [41]. Transportation regarding the timestructural and costs, shift 30 is not so different in the industrial and business sectors as well [41]. Transportation time and costs, 36 services, and utility costs have also increased rapidly in Istanbul due to the over-agglomeration and 31 services,between andindustrial utility andcosts service have al sectorsso increased in the sizerapidly of Istanbul’s in Istanbul GDP. due to the over-agglomeration and 37 congestion [42]. This has led to exclusion of some sectors from the city to its periphery while some 32 congestionThere [42].are ample This has reasons led to for exclusion such a decreasing of some sectors role of from industrial the city sectors to its inperiphery Istanbul’s while GDP. some The 38 newincreased sectors cost have of land emerged is among [42]. the However, primary thereasons transfer both of from some an industrial investment activity and labor has perspective. accelerated 33 new sectors have emerged [42]. However, the transfer of some industrial activity has accelerated from 39 fromRising Istanbul land prices metropolitan drive up area the while cost of the initial share investment of service sectors for land increased and cost further of labor in the due city’s to higher Gross 34 Istanbul metropolitan area while the share of service sectors increased further in the city’s Gross 40 compensation required for increased cost of living [38]. The municipal authority of Istanbul and other 35 Domestic Production (GDP). Figure 9 illustrates this transformation regarding the structural shift 41 numerous governmental are fully aware of this fact and have tried to deindustrialize 36 between industrial and service sectors in the size of Istanbul’s GDP. 37 There are ample reasons for such a decreasing role of industrial sectors in Istanbul’s GDP. The 38 increased cost of land is among the primary reasons both from an investment and labor perspective. 39 Rising land prices drive up the cost of initial investment for land and cost of labor due to higher 40 compensation required for increased cost of living [38]. The municipal authority of Istanbul and other 41 numerous governmental organizations are fully aware of this fact and have tried to deindustrialize

Sustainability 2018, 10, x FOR PEER REVIEW 3 of 22

Sustainability 2019, 11, 135 15 of 23 42 Istanbul and increase its services and tourism capacity [38]. The trend in Figure 9 indicates that the 43 importance of industrial sectors has been decreasing in the economy of Istanbul. The of land 44 Domesticand associated Production high prices (GDP). for Figureboth commercial9 illustrates and this residential transformation purposes regarding are among the the structural main culprits shift 45 betweenof this trend. industrial and service sectors in the size of Istanbul’s GDP.

Istanbul's Share in GDP of Turkey as Percentage 39% Industry Services 37% 35% 33% 31% 29% 27% 25% 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 46 47 Figure 9. Change in Istanbul’s economiceconomic structure between 2004–2014 (TUIK).

48 ThereThe over-agglomeration are ample reasons in forthe suchcity of a Istanbul decreasing has rolealso ofcaused industrial environmental sectors in and Istanbul’s further socio- GDP. 49 Theeconomic increased problems cost of in land Turkey is among apart the from primary the relatively reasons bothlow level from of an industrialization. investment and labor The perspective.forest areas 50 Risingof Istanbul land have prices been drive continually up the cost usurped of initial and investment turned into for residential, land and costcommercial, of labor and due industrial to higher 51 compensationland plots for requiredthe last 50 for years increased [43]. cost This of has living resulted [38]. The in significant municipal authorityloss of wildlife of Istanbul and andflora other and 52 numerousdecreases in governmental the air, water, organizations and soil qualities are fully in th awaree city [44]. of this The fact city and had have expanded tried to its deindustrialize borders more 53 Istanbulthan 80% and within increase the last its servicestwo decades and tourism of the 20th capacity century, [38]. associated The trend inwith Figure a significant9 indicates loss that in thethe 54 importanceforest area [16]. of industrial Figure 10 sectors shows has the beenrapid decreasing conversion in of the forest economy area into of Istanbul. man-made The structures scarcity of in land the 55 andcity of associated Istanbul, high which prices heavily for bothcoincides commercial with the and over-agglomeration residential purposes through are among time. theIstanbul main has culprits also 56 ofthe this worst trend. air quality among the largest European cities due to pollution from heavy traffic and other 57 industrialThe over-agglomeration activities [45]. Large inconcentrations the city of Istanbul of particulate has also matters caused (PM), environmental sulfur dioxide and (SO further2), and 58 socio-economicnitrogen oxide compounds problems in (NO Turkeyx) cause apart various from the respiratory relatively and low levelcardiovascular of industrialization. diseases as The well forest as a 59 areasvery high of Istanbul number have of premature been continually deaths usurped [20]. Over and-agglomeration turned into residential, and congestion commercial, cause andvery industrial common 60 landand ubiquitous plots for the traffic last jams 50 years across [43 the]. city This that has ca resulteduse more in than significant 6 billion loss Turkish of wildlife Liras annually and flora based and 61 decreaseson some research in the air, [46]. water, These and traffic soil qualitiesjams have in beco theme city a [ 44critical]. The and city very had ti expandedme-consuming its borders problem more in 62 thanevery 80% part withinof Istanbul the lastdue twoto insufficient decades of infrastruc the 20thture century, to meet associated the demand with from a significant such a rapid loss growth in the 63 forest[17]. In area addition [16]. Figure to air pollution10 shows and the rapidloss of conversion forest area, of Istanbul forest area heavily into suffers man-made from structures noise pollution in the 64 cityand ofsubsequent Istanbul, hearing which heavily loss on coincidesits residents. with Heavy the over-agglomeration traffic due to transportation through (air, time. land, Istanbul rail, sea), has 65 alsoindustrial the worst and airconstruction quality among activities, the largestand other European human citiesactivities due causes to pollution significant from noise heavy pollution traffic and in 66 otherIstanbul. industrial Figure activities11 highlights [45]. Largethis fact concentrations as Istanbul is of among particulate the worst matters cities (PM), when sulfur it comes dioxide to (SOnoise2), 67 andpollution nitrogen and oxide subsequent compounds hearing (NO lossx) cause problems various as respiratoryit is ranked andfifth cardiovascular out of 50 globally diseases selected as well cities as 68 a[18]. very high number of premature deaths [20]. Over-agglomeration and congestion cause very common 69 and ubiquitousIn addition traffic to the jams environmental across the city degradation that cause an mored destruction than 6 billion of the Turkish natural Liras habitat, annually the basedover- 70 onagglomeration some research in [Istanbul46]. These has traffic caused jams general have economic become a criticalimbalances and veryand inequalities time-consuming across problem Turkey 71 in[37]. every It is parta well-known of Istanbul fact due that to Istanbul insufficient has acted infrastructure as a magnet to meetfor both the population demand from and such capital a rapid from 72 growththe other [17 regions]. In addition of Turkey to airsince pollution 1950 [47]. and Figure loss of5 points forest area,out the Istanbul same dynamic heavily suffersas Istanbul’s from noiseshare 73 pollutionin Turkey’s and total subsequent population hearing has grown loss on consistently its residents. over Heavy time while traffic firmly due to cementing transportation its dominance (air, land, 74 rail,in economic sea), industrial activities. and This construction has resulted activities, in great and income other disparities human activities across Turkey causes significantin terms of noiseGDP 75 pollutionper capita, in where Istanbul. Istanbul Figure and 11 highlightsneighboring this cities fact ashave Istanbul much is higher among income the worst levels cities compared when it comesto the 76 torest noise of Turkey pollution as shown and subsequent in Figure hearing12. loss problems as it is ranked fifth out of 50 globally selected cities [18].

Sustainability 2019, 11, 135 16 of 23 SustainabilitySustainability 20182018,, 1010,, xx FORFOR PEERPEER REVIEWREVIEW 4 4 of of 22 22

7777 7878 FigureFigure 10.10. ChangeChange of of Istanbul’sIstanbul’s landscapelandscape byby timetime [[43].[43].43].

7979 8080 FigureFigure 11. 11. NoiseNoise pollution pollution and and hearing hearing loss loss index index [18]. [[18].18].

Sustainability 2019, 11, 135 17 of 23

In addition to the environmental degradation and destruction of the natural habitat, the over-agglomeration in Istanbul has caused general economic imbalances and inequalities across Turkey [37]. It is a well-known fact that Istanbul has acted as a magnet for both population and capital from the other regions of Turkey since 1950 [47]. Figure5 points out the same dynamic as Istanbul’s share in Turkey’s total population has grown consistently over time while firmly cementing its dominance in economic activities. This has resulted in great income disparities across Turkey in terms of GDP per capita, where Istanbul and neighboring cities have much higher income levels comparedSustainability to 2018 the, 10 rest, x FOR of Turkey PEER REVIEW as shown in Figure 12. 5 of 22

81 82 FigureFigure 12.12. GDPGDP perper capitacapita acrossacrossTurkish Turkish cities cities in in current current prices prices of of 2014 2014 (after (after Tuik.gov.tr). Tuik.gov.tr). This great economic imbalance between the periphery of Istanbul and the rest of Turkey, 83 This great economic imbalance between the periphery of Istanbul and the rest of Turkey, especially the south-eastern region, has resulted in greater income-inequalities across Turkey. 84 especially the south-eastern region, has resulted in greater income-inequalities across Turkey. Surprisingly, Istanbul has also the highest income-inequality measured by the Gini coefficient while 85 Surprisingly, Istanbul has also the highest income-inequality measured by the while being the richest city in Turkey. The south-eastern region of Turkey with the lowest income levels 86 being the richest city in Turkey. The south-eastern region of Turkey with the lowest income levels closely follows Istanbul when it comes to income-inequality, which is shown in Figure 13. Among the 87 closely follows Istanbul when it comes to income-inequality, which is shown in Figure 13. Among for Economic Cooperation and Development Countries (OECD), Iceland has a Gini score 88 the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development Countries (OECD), Iceland has a Gini of 0.25 as being the least inequal, and South Africa has a Gini score of 0.62 as being the most unequal 89 score of 0.25 as being the least inequal, and South Africa has a Gini score of 0.62 as being the most in terms of income distribution. Turkey has been ranked as the sixth worst income-inequality country 90 unequal in terms of income distribution. Turkey has been ranked as the sixth worst income-inequality among the all OECD countries [48]. Over-agglomerated Istanbul and subsequently the less-developed 91 country among the all OECD countries [48]. Over-agglomerated Istanbul and subsequently the less- south-eastern region of Turkey are among the main culprits of the high-income-inequality level of 92 developed south-eastern region of Turkey are among the main culprits of the high-income-inequality Turkey, which is among the highest across the OECD countries [49]. 93 level of Turkey, which is among the highest across the OECD countries [49].

94 95 Figure 13. Income-inequality across Turkish Cities measured by the Gini coefficient (tuik.gov.tr).

Sustainability 2018, 10, x FOR PEER REVIEW 5 of 22

81 82 Figure 12. GDP per capita across Turkish cities in current prices of 2014 (after Tuik.gov.tr).

83 This great economic imbalance between the periphery of Istanbul and the rest of Turkey, 84 especially the south-eastern region, has resulted in greater income-inequalities across Turkey. 85 Surprisingly, Istanbul has also the highest income-inequality measured by the Gini coefficient while 86 being the richest city in Turkey. The south-eastern region of Turkey with the lowest income levels 87 closely follows Istanbul when it comes to income-inequality, which is shown in Figure 13. Among 88 the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development Countries (OECD), Iceland has a Gini 89 score of 0.25 as being the least inequal, and South Africa has a Gini score of 0.62 as being the most 90 unequal in terms of income distribution. Turkey has been ranked as the sixth worst income-inequality 91 country among the all OECD countries [48]. Over-agglomerated Istanbul and subsequently the less- 92 Sustainabilitydeveloped2019 south-eastern, 11, 135 region of Turkey are among the main culprits of the high-income-inequality18 of 23 93 level of Turkey, which is among the highest across the OECD countries [49].

94 95 Figure 13. Income-inequalityIncome-inequality across across Turkish Cities measuredmeasured byby thethe GiniGini coefficientcoefficient (tuik.gov.tr).(tuik.gov.tr). 5. Conclusions and Remarks Sustainable development of a region heavily depends on overall equality among the populace in the form of economic, social, and environmental dimensions [5]. Inequality of any form and dimension is known to be a major damaging factor for sustainable development [6]. One of the essential drivers of inequality is the over-agglomeration and congestion around a certain section or city [7]. The sustainable development of emerging economies is particularly prone to a high level of over-agglomeration due to megacities [8]. Initial benefits in agglomeration of resources into a certain region are generally outweighed by congestion, rising costs, and environmental degradation, with numerous examples worldwide [9]. The benefits of agglomeration and industrial clustering have been discussed and documented by numerous scholars [10,23]. Agglomeration of certain sectors in a geographical area offers easy access to a large pool of labor, capital equipment and maintenance, and intermediate products for the firms. A further benefit of agglomeration is a of tacit knowledge and expertise among the participating firms, which is crucial for a [11,33]. Additionally, developing countries need a certain threshold for industrialization due to insufficient initial demand and expectations of negative profits by the firms willing to switch into advanced or industrial production. It has been argued by the big push theory that at least a certain amount of firms must switch simultaneously to the industrial production for those firms to break even and facilitate further industrialization as a result [15,25,50]. A theoretical model of the big push theory was revisited in that regard in Section3. Conditions for a complete industrialization in a developing country were studied. Similar to previous works, it was shown that the initial fixed cost (F) is among the most important factors in the industrialization process of a developing country. If there are no sufficient firms willing to take an investment into advanced (industrialized) production simultaneously, then the country may get trapped permanently in a backward economy. Once a sufficient number of firms manage to invest in industrialized production and expand the overall economy as a result, there will be profit in industrialization for all the firms involved. This will result in the big push for the developing country as all the sectors will get switched into industrialized production. However, one crucial aspect of these dynamics is the assumption of a constant fixed cost in response to the level of industrialization. Empirical evidence suggests that this is not the case for most of the time following the analysis of the industrialization Sustainability 2019, 11, 135 19 of 23 patterns in many developing countries [15]. Fixed costs increase with more agglomeration and start outweighing the benefits of industrialization in the case of congestion through an increase in labor costs or decreasing productivity [15]. This paper adds to the literature by considering the relationship between the level of agglomeration and fixed costs through land prices, which are among the key reasons for the high costs of doing business [38]. A positive relationship with fixed costs and level of agglomeration may result in sub-optimal industrialization or reversal of the industrialization process. Benefits of further industrialization may be outweighed by the cost of land prices, which affect fixed costs dramatically in the case of over-agglomeration and congestion in a specific geographic area. A special case study of over-agglomeration and congestion was analyzed for the city of Istanbul. There have been numerous industrial sectors agglomerated in various parts of the city, expanding to its geographical borders. Due to its favorable geographic location, and the continuous support of the successive Turkish governments in the forms of infrastructure and industrial investments, Istanbul has been the economic center of modern Turkey since its independence [34]. The constant inward immigration towards Istanbul from all other parts of Turkey have continued well into the 21st century [35]. As a result, the frontiers of the city have continued to grow and have stretched to Istanbul’s borders from almost all directions with an increasing rate [36]. However, the relative role of industrial sectors vis-à-vis service sectors has been decreasing in Istanbul over the last decade. There are ample reasons for such a decreasing role of industrial sectors in the Istanbul’s GDP. Very high costs of land for both residential and commercial purposes are among the primary reasons both from an investment and labor costs perspective. Rising land prices drive up the cost of initial investment due to an increasing cost of land and cost of labor [38]. The municipal authority of Istanbul and other numerous governmental organizations are fully aware of this fact and have tried to deindustrialize Istanbul and increase its services and tourism capacity [36,38]. Over-agglomeration has also caused environmental problems within Istanbul and across Turkey, impeding the sustainable development of the country further. There has been significant loss of forest area in Istanbul due to rapid expansion in all types of construction for the last 50 years. Figure 10 clearly illustrates the expansion of the city at a big cost to Istanbul’s vast forest lands and inevitable destruction of wildlife and deterioration in the environment of the city [43]. The loss of natural habitat and forestry has been further aggravated by the worsening air quality and increasing pollution due to heavy traffic and industrial activity in the city. Istanbul is consistently among the worst European cities for dangerous matters in the air, such as particulate matters, SO2, and NOx, based on numerous studies [20]. The common and ubiquitous traffic jams also cause a loss of productive time and significant due to insufficient infrastructure [17]. The city is also ranked as the fifth worst city out of 50 globally selected cities when it comes to noise pollution and subsequent hearing loss effects on its citizens [18]. There is a large income differential (measured by GDP per capita) across Turkey that is positively skewed towards Istanbul and its vicinity as shown in Figure 12. This income differential across the cities of Turkey manifests itself in as well. While being the richest city in Turkey in terms of GDP per capita, Istanbul has also the highest internal income-inequality, which is followed by the poorest south-eastern region of Turkey. The land price disparity across all of Turkey is also another direct result of over-agglomeration and congestion in Istanbul. This may further impede the industrialization of Turkey into advanced production while causing economic imbalances across the country. Such large economic imbalances and ubiquitous income-inequalities may block sustainable development. Other studies also indicate that high rental income and land prices in over-agglomerated Istanbul are among the key reasons for income-inequality in Turkey as shown in Figure 14[51]. Sustainability 2018, 10, x FOR PEER REVIEW 7 of 23

and other numerous governmental organizations are fully aware of this fact and have tried to deindustrialize Istanbul and increase its services and tourism capacity [36,38]. Over‐agglomeration has also caused environmental problems within Istanbul and across Turkey, impeding the sustainable development of the country further. There has been significant loss of forest area in Istanbul due to rapid expansion in all types of construction for the last 50 years. Figure 10 clearly illustrates the expansion of the city at a big cost to Istanbul’s vast forest lands and inevitable destruction of wildlife and deterioration in the environment of the city [43]. The loss of natural habitat and forestry has been further aggravated by the worsening air quality and increasing pollution due to heavy traffic and industrial activity in the city. Istanbul is consistently among the worst European cities for dangerous matters in the air, such as particulate matters, SO2, and NOx, based on numerous studies [20]. The common and ubiquitous traffic jams also cause a loss of productive time and significant money due to insufficient infrastructure [17]. The city is also ranked as the fifth worst city out of 50 globally selected cities when it comes to noise pollution and subsequent hearing loss effects on its citizens [18]. There is a large income differential (measured by GDP per capita) across Turkey that is positively skewed towards Istanbul and its vicinity as shown in Figure 12. This income differential across the cities of Turkey manifests itself in economic inequality as well. While being the richest city in Turkey in terms of GDP per capita, Istanbul has also the highest internal income‐inequality, which is followed by the poorest south‐eastern region of Turkey. The land price disparity across all of Turkey is also another direct result of over‐agglomeration and congestion in Istanbul. This may further impede the industrialization of Turkey into advanced production while causing economic imbalances across the country. Such large economic imbalances and ubiquitous income‐inequalities may block sustainable development. Other studies also indicate that high rental income and land Sustainabilityprices in2019 over, 11‐agglomerated, 135 Istanbul are among the key reasons for income‐inequality in Turkey as 20 of 23 shown in Figure 14 [51].

Figure 14. Factors contributing to income-inequality in Turkey (Selim, et al., 2014). Figure 14. Factors contributing to income‐inequality in Turkey [51]. From Turkey’s perspective, the wisdom of hoarding a significant size of its resources into a single city shouldFrom be Turkey’s questioned. perspective, All the the negative wisdom outcomes of hoarding of a the significant over-population size of its in resources Istanbul into have a been knownsingle to city the should governmental be questioned. bodies All the of Turkeynegative atoutcomes least in of opaque the over‐ termspopulation [52]. in However, Istanbul have the weak institutionalbeen known structure to the governmental of Turkey for bodies property of Turkey rights at andleast environmental in opaque terms protection [52]. However, has beenthe weak abused by theinstitutional local municipal structure authorities of Turkey in for Istanbul property in therights form andof environmental illegal settlement protection and has extension been abused of the city’s by the local municipal authorities in Istanbul in the form of illegal settlement and extension of the borders [52,53]. Regardless of their ideological or lifestyle differences, almost all the political parties have seen the inward migration to Istanbul from other parts of Turkey as a base of support and hence actively encouraged the city’s expansion [52]. This political dynamic has contributed significantly to the over-agglomeration of Istanbul apart from the positive factors, such as labor pooling, access to capital and equipment goods, economies of scale and scope, and a large market for goods and services. As shown in Table2, Istanbul continues to receive the lion’s share in current large infrastructure projects in Turkey. This will most probably increase further agglomeration of overall economic activity in Istanbul and aggravate further the economic, social, and environmental problems there. This study is a prelude to understanding the relationship between over-agglomeration and sub-optimal industrialization due to rapidly increasing land costs in a specific geographic area, such as a city or region. Over-agglomeration and congestion cause numerous problems for the industrialization dynamics of a developing country. The decrease in productivity levels of labor, increasing cost of living standards, and hence labor costs, and logistical difficulties in moving goods and products are also side effects of over-agglomeration and congestion [15]. It is very probable that the decrease in Istanbul’s industrialization level may be partly attributed to some other factors as well, which we did not consider in this study. The theoretical model presented in this paper does not cover all the negative dynamics of sustainable development as a result of the over-agglomeration. Further theoretical analysis and case studies are needed to have a better understanding of the over-agglomeration and the trajectory of sustainable development. This paper does not argue that service sectors are less important than industrial sectors. Therefore, the increasing role of service sectors in Istanbul could add overall benefits to Turkey’s economy since some of these sectors can also show increasing returns to a scale pattern [54]. The prevalence of a megacity and subsequent problems in sustainable development are similar in other emerging economies, such as Brazil and India [8]. The majority of megacities in the world are located in developing countries, from Mexico to Indonesia [8]. The problems discussed in the context of Istanbul are not dissimilar to the problems faced by Mexico City, Sao Paolo, or Delhi [9]. Rapid in many developing countries has resulted in entrenchment and dominance of megacities, which may further hamper sustainable development [55]. A better Sustainability 2019, 11, 135 21 of 23 understanding of the economic and political factors leading to over-agglomeration in a megacity is a must to come up with effective policy suggestions in the future not just for Turkey, but for other developing countries as well.

Author Contributions: A.K. wrote the article, conducted the theoretical analysis and the case study on Istanbul. M.K. has edited writing and directed the research throughout the paper. Funding: This research received no external funding. Acknowledgments: Authors hereby acknowledge the financial support of Hamad Bin Khalifa University in pursuing the research and production of this article. The publication of this article was funded by the Qatar National Library. Conflicts of : The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

1. Giddings, B.; Hopwood, B.; O’brien, G. Environment, economy and society: Fitting them together into sustainable development. Sustain. Dev. 2002, 10, 187–196. [CrossRef] 2. Boström, M. A missing pillar? Challenges in theorizing and practicing social sustainability: Introduction to the special issue. Sustain. Sci. Pract. Policy 2012, 8, 3–14. [CrossRef] 3. Mitchell, G. Problems and fundamentals of sustainable development indicators. Sustain. Dev. 1996, 4, 1–11. [CrossRef] 4. Hopwood, B.; Mellor, M.; O’Brien, G. Sustainable development: Mapping different approaches. Sustain. Dev. 2005, 13, 38–52. [CrossRef] 5. Sachs, J.D. The Age of Sustainable Development; Columbia University Press: New York, NY, USA, 2015. 6. Costanza, R.; Fioramonti, L.; Kubiszewski, I. The UN Sustainable Development Goals and the dynamics of well-being. Front. Ecol. Environ. 2016, 14, 59. [CrossRef] 7. Wei, Y.; Huang, C.; Li, J.; Xie, L. An evaluation model for urban carrying capacity: A case study of China’s mega-cities. Habitat Int. 2016, 53, 87–96. [CrossRef] 8. Kötter, T.; Friesecke, F. Developing urban indicators for managing mega cities. In Land Governance in Support of the MDGs: Responding to New Challenges; and International Federation of Surveyors Conference; World Bank Group: Washington, DC, USA, 9–10 March 2009. 9. Majd, S.N.; Tabibian, M. Sustainable development in megacities. Mediterr. J. Soc. Sci. 2015, 6, 668. [CrossRef] 10. Krugman, P. Increasing returns and economic . J. Polit. Econ. 1991, 99, 483–499. [CrossRef] 11. Dixit, A.K.; Stiglitz, J.E. and optimum product diversity. Am. Econ. Rev. 1977, 67, 297–308. 12. Kim, K.S. Industrialization Process, Employment, and Income Distribution in Mexico: Issues and Strategies. 1990. Available online: https://kellogg.nd.edu/sites/default/files/old_files/documents/131_ 0.pdf (accessed on 22 November 2018). 13. Kohli, A. State-Directed Development: Political Power and Industrialization in the Global Periphery; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2004. 14. Nilsson, K.; Nielsen, T.S.; Aalbers, C.; Bell, S.; Boitier, B.; Chery, J.P.; Fertner, C.; Groschowski, M.; Haase, D.; Loibl, W. Strategies for sustainable urban development and urban-rural linkages. 2014. Available online: https://www.researchgate.net/profile/Jean_Pierre_Chery/publication/272786925_Strategies_for_ Sustainable_Urban_Development_and_Urban-Rural_Linkages/links/54edebe20cf25238f939390b/Strategies- for-Sustainable-Urban-Development-and-Urban-Rural-Linkages.pdf (accessed on 27 December 2018). 15. Oh, J. Concentration, congestion, and the dynamics: Spatial re-modeling of the Murphy, Shleifer, and Vishny model. Lett. Spat. Resour. Sci. 2008, 1, 77–97. [CrossRef] 16. Karaburun, A.; Demirci, A.; Suen, I.-S. Impacts of urban growth on forest cover in Istanbul (1987–2007). Environ. Monit. Assess. 2010, 166, 267–277. [CrossRef][PubMed] 17. Batur, I.;˙ Koç, M. Travel Demand Management (TDM) case study for social behavioral change towards sustainable urban transportation in Istanbul. Cities 2017, 69, 20–35. [CrossRef] 18. Gray, A. These Are the Cities with the Worst Noise Pollution. 2017. Available online: https://www.weforum. org/agenda/2017/03/these-are-the-cities-with-the-worst-noise-pollution/ (accessed on 20 December 2018). 19. Garza, G.; Schteingart, M. Mexico city: The emerging . Lat. Am. Urban Res. 1978, 6, 51–86. Sustainability 2019, 11, 135 22 of 23

20. Çapraz, Ö.; Efe, B.; Deniz, A. Study on the association between air pollution and mortality in Istanbul,˙ 2007–2012. Atmos. Pollut. Res. 2016, 7, 147–154. [CrossRef] 21. Duranton, G.; Puga, D. Micro-foundations of urban agglomeration economies. In Handbook of Regional and ; Elsevier: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2004; Volume 4, pp. 2063–2117. 22. Glaeser, E.L. Learning in cities. J. Urban Econ. 1999, 46, 254–277. [CrossRef] 23. Alkay, E.; Hewings, G.J.D. The determinants of agglomeration for the manufacturing sector in the Istanbul metropolitan area. Ann. Reg. Sci. 2012, 48, 225–245. [CrossRef] 24. Rivera-Batiz, F.L. Increasing returns, monopolistic competition, and agglomeration economies in consumption and production. Reg. Sci. Urban Econ. 1988, 18, 125–153. [CrossRef] 25. Murphy, K.M.; Shleifer, A.; Vishny, R.W. Industrialization and the big push. J. Polit. Econ. 1989, 97, 1003–1026. [CrossRef] 26. Azariadis, C.; Drazen, A. Threshold externalities in economic development. Q. J. Econ. 1990, 105, 501–526. [CrossRef] 27. Bjorvatn, K.; Coniglio, N.D. Big push or big failure? On the effectiveness of industrialization policies for economic development. J. Jpn. Int. Econ. 2012, 26, 129–141. [CrossRef] 28. Barredo, J.I.; Demicheli, L. Urban sustainability in developing countries’ megacities: Modelling and predicting future urban growth in Lagos. Cities 2003, 20, 297–310. [CrossRef] 29. Detter, H. Satisfying transportation needs in fast-growing metropolitan areas: Mobility solutions for mega-cities in developing countries. OPEC Energy Rev. 2015, 39, 418–444. [CrossRef] 30. Khalil, H.A.E.E.; Ibrahim, A.; Elgendy, N.; Makhlouf, N. Could/should improving the urban climate in informal areas of fast-growing cities be an integral part of upgrading processes? Cairo case. Urban Clim. 2018, 24, 63–79. [CrossRef] 31. Acemoglu, D.; Johnson, S.; Robinson, J.A. Institutions as a fundamental cause of long-run growth. Handb. Econ. Growth 2005, 1, 385–472. 32. Rowland, A.; Gordon, P. Mexico City: No Longer a Leviathan? United Nations University Press: Tokyo, Japan, 1996; pp. 173–202. 33. Scheel, C. Knowledge clusters of technological innovation systems. J. Knowl. Manag. 2002, 6, 356–367. [CrossRef] 34. Altug, S.; Filiztekin, A.; Pamuk, ¸S.Sources of long-term for Turkey, 1880–2005. Eur. Rev. Econ. Hist. 2008, 12, 393–430. [CrossRef] 35. Tokatli, N.; Boyaci, Y. The changing morphology of commercial activity in Istanbul. Cities 1999, 16, 181–193. [CrossRef] 36. Eraydin, A. Changing Istanbul city region dynamics: Re-regulations to challenge the consequences of uneven development and inequality. Eur. Plan. Stud. 2011, 19, 813–837. [CrossRef] 37. Dogruel, F.; Dogruel, A.S. The Deindustrialization of Istanbul. 2010. Available online: https://mpra.ub.uni- muenchen.de/27070/ (accessed on 2 December 2018). 38. Erbil, T. Planning dilemmas in deindustrialization process in Istanbul.˙ ITÜ˙ J. Fac. Arch. 2017, 14, 43–56. [CrossRef] 39. PWC. Capital Projects and Infrastructure Spendingin Turkey, Outlook to 2023; PWC: London, UK, 2017. 40. Gezici, F.; Müderriso˘glu,B. Analyzing the Spatial Distribution of Manufacturing Clusters in the Istanbul Metropolitan Area. In Proceedings of the 50th European Congress of Association, Jonkoping, Sweden, 19–23 August 2010; pp. 1–12. 41. CBT. Residential Price Index. 2017. Available online: https://www.tcmb.gov.tr/wps/wcm/connect/en/ tcmb+en/main+menu/statistics/real+sector+statistics/house+price+index (accessed on 10 November 2018). 42. Ciraci, H.; Kundak, S. Changing Urban Pattern of Istanbul; from Monocentric to Polycentric Structure. 2000. Available online: https://www.econstor.eu/bitstream/10419/114915/1/ERSA2000_378.pdf (accessed on 15 November 2018). 43. Canaz, S.; Aliefendio˘glu,Y.; Tanrıvermi¸s,H. Change detection using Landsat images and an analysis of the linkages between the change and property tax values in the Istanbul Province of Turkey. J. Environ. Manag. 2017, 200, 446–455. [CrossRef] 44. Özsoy, A.; Gökmen, G.P. Space use, dwelling layout and housing quality: An example of low-cost housing in Istanbul.˙ In Housing, Space and Quality of Life; Routledge: Abington Thames, UK, 2017; pp. 17–28. Sustainability 2019, 11, 135 23 of 23

45. Elbir, T.; Mangir, N.; Kara, M.; Simsir, S.; Eren, T.; Ozdemir, S. Development of a GIS-based decision support system for urban air in the city of Istanbul. Atmos. Environ. 2010, 44, 441–454. [CrossRef] 46. Ilicali, M. of Istanbul’s Traffic. Available online: http://www.mustafailicali.com/haberler/ ilicaliistanbuldaki-trafik-sikisikliginin-yillik-maliyeti-6-milyar-lira-692 (accessed on 15 November 2018). 47. Biehl, K.S. Exploring Migration, Diversification and Urban Transformation in Contemporary Istanbul: The Case of Kumkapı. 2014. Available online: https://pure.mpg.de/pubman/faces/ViewItemOverviewPage.jsp? itemId=item_2079090 (accessed on 18 November 2018). 48. OECD. Income Inequality. 2018. Available online: https://data.oecd.org/inequality/income-inequality.htm (accessed on 12 November 2018). 49. Cingano, F. Trends in Income Inequality and Its Impact on Economic Growth. 2014. Available online: https://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/content/paper/5jxrjncwxv6j-en (accessed on 14 November 2018). 50. Kaya, A.; Tsai, I. Inclusive Economic Institutions in the Gulf Cooperation Council States: Current Status and Theoretical Implications. Rev. Middle East Econ. Financ. 2016, 12, 139–173. [CrossRef] 51. Selim, R.; Günçavdı, Ö.; Bayar, A.A. Türkiye’de Bireysel Gelir Da˘gılımıE¸sitsizlikleri:Fonksiyonel Gelir Kaynakları ve Bölgesel E¸sitsizlikler; tÜsIad˙ Rep. No TÜSIAD;˙ Tusiad: Istanbul, Turkey, 2014; p. 2014-06. 52. Yalcintan, M.C.; Erbas, A.E. Impacts of ‘Gecekondu’ on the Electoral Geography of Istanbul. Int. Labor. Work. Hist. 2003, 64, 91–111. [CrossRef] 53. Acemoglu, D.; Ucer, M. The ups and downs of Turkish Growth, 2002–2015: Political Dynamics, the European Union and the Institutional Slide. National Bureau of Economic Research. 2015. Available online: https: //www.nber.org/papers/w21608 (accessed on 27 December 2018). 54. Sachs, J.D.; Warner, A.M. The big push, natural resource booms and growth. J. Dev. Econ. 1999, 59, 43–76. [CrossRef] 55. Madon, S.; Sahay, S. 14 Urbanisation and Megacities in Developing Countries: The Management Challenge. In Information Technology in Context: Studies from the Perspective of Developing Countries; Routledge Revivals: New York, NY, USA, 2017.

© 2018 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).