Alfred Marshall on Human Capitalandfuture Generations

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Alfred Marshall on Human Capitalandfuture Generations ffesMee Vol, 53, No. 4, Oct, 2002 Alfred MarShall on Human CapitalandFuture Generations Tamotsu Nishizawa I hold that the most important capital of a nation is that which is invested in the physical, mental, and moral nurture of its people. (Marshall to the Editor of 7";he Tla;mes, 13 November 1909) growing earnestness of the age. [ibid: 2-4] 1. Introduction : `The Spirit of the Age' -1 Pigou addressed in the same kind of spirit Reviewing Marshall's Principles of Eto- in his inaugural lecture as the Cambridge nomics, Edgeworth wrote that there was one Professor of Political Economy as successor element there to be searched in vain among of Marshall : `The least imaginative among the older economist `the modern element, us sometimes sees with vividness the faces of the spirit of the age', which prompted the the suffering and the degraded who have been question : `Is it necessary that large numbers worsted in the industrial struggle. ..No doubt, of the people should be exclusively occupied those who feel these things most keenly are with work that has no elevating character ?' not always economists'. He should be glad if [Edgeworth 1890: 12] a man comes to Economics because of his In the "Introduction" of his Pim'nciples, interest in Edgeworth's Mathematical ky- Marshall stated ' chics or Fisher's APPreciation and interest. ' In addition to the Residuum, there are vast But he should be far more glad `if he comes numbers of people both in town and coun- because he has walked through the slums of try who are brought up with insufficient London and is stirred to make some effort to food, clothing, and house-room; whose help his fellow-men'. `Wonder', Carlyle said, education is broken off early in order that `is the beginning of philosophy':`Social they may go to work for wages;who enthusiasm', Pigou added, `is the beginning of thenceforth are engaged during long hours economic science'. [Pigou 1908 : 12-13] in exhausting toil with imperfectly nouri- Edgeworth continued his "Review" as fol- shed bodies, and have therefore no chance lows. Marshall declared against the pre- 1 of developing their higher mental faculties. tended harmonies of economic optimism ; he [Marshall 1961A : 2-3] broke with the `hangers-on of the science who used it simply as an engine for keeping the And observing the steady progress of the working-classes in their place'. He was working classes in the 19th century, he posed preceded by Adolph Wagner and F. A. the question `whether it is really impossible Walker, by Jevons, and Sidgwick who best that all should start in the world with a fair taught that `the art of political economy does chance of leading a cultured life, free from not necessarily consist in inaction' and was to the pains of poverty and the stagnating influ- found modern `welfare' economics. But in ences of excessive mechanical toil ' and this some sense more convincingly Marshall ' question is being pressed to the front by the reasoned that `it would be theoretically pos- 306 ff es M ee sible for a government by fiscal arrange- ments admittedly within in its province, by a 596] Generally speaking, Pigou・ argued, `every- nicely adjusted system of taxes and bounties, body prefers present pleasures or satisfac- to increase the welfare of its citizens'. While tions of given magnitude to future pleasures thus recoiling from extreme individualism or satisfactions of equal magnitude'. It the author of the Pri'ncipies `may be suspected implies that `our telescopic faculty is defec- of leaning towards a moderate socialism'. tive', and `we see future pleasures, as it were, [Edgeworth 1890:12-13;Hutchison 1953: on a diminished scale'. Thus `people distrib- 47]. ute their resources between the present, the As is well-known, in his Preface to industi y near future and the remote future on the and 7'hrade, Marshall described how he `devel- basis of a wholly irrational preference'. oped a tendency to socialism', which was Mortality provides a further check to taking fortified later on by J. S. Mill's posthumous the long view. For a person who carries out "Chapters on Socialism" in the Fbrtnightly long-term investment, `the satisfaction with Review (1879). But as he wrote to Helen which his desire is connected is not his own Bosanquet (28 September 1902), `it is more satisfaction, but the satisfaction of somebody important to dwell on the truths in Mill's else, ..possibly somebody quite remote in Liberly than on those in his ESsays on Social- blood or in time, about whom he scarcely ism [i. e. "Chapters on Socialism"]'. [Whita- cares at all'. Practically these discrepancies ker II: 399] between desire and satisfaction work them- selves out to the injury of economic welfare, by checking the creation of new capital and 2. Cambridge Tradition on Welfare and encouraging people to use up existing capital Future Generations to such a degree that larger future advan- 2. 1 `Defective Telescopic Faculty' tages are sacrificed for smaller present one. Recently David Collard, in his stimulating [Pigou 1920: 25-27] article "Pigou and Future Generations: A The same slackness of desire towards the Cambridge Tradition", argued for a strong future distant satisfactions was also respon- Cambridge tradition (Sidgwick-Marshall- sible for `a tendency to wasteful exploitation Pigou-Ramsey) against discounting future of Nature's gift'. Using enormous quantities utilities and the injury of economic welfare. of coal in high-speed vessels, `we cut an hour Pigou stressed `defective telescopic faculty' off the time of our passage to New York at and held that the present generation would the cost of preventing, perhaps, one of our devote too few resources to investment in descendants from making the passage at all'. human capital and undertakings, the return [ibid: 28] In the general issue of depletable from which would be distant. He linked his resources and natural resource conservation argument with the controversies about eco- Pigou was anticipated by Jevons who grap- nomic environment and natural resource con- pled with similar issues in 7ZVze Coal Ques- servation. This Cambridge tradition held that tion : An inquiay Conceming the Pragress of issues of generational justice left an impor- the Alketion and the Probable Exhaustion of tant role for the state and could not be our Coal Mines (1865)i). resolved simply at the level of the individual Pigou linked his argument to the Conserva- or the family. Pigou's VVizalth and Wb4i2zre tionist Movement which was at its peak at (1912), and later Economics of I)VizijZire about the time that he was writing Vltlealth (1920) was `the apogee' of this Cambridge and VTle4XZzre. His contemporary L. C. Gray tradition and the most explicit and extensive put the link:`This issue is the problem of treatment of this issue. [Collard 1996: 585, adjusting the conflict between the interest of Alfred Marshall on Human Capital and Future Generations 307 present and future'. [Collard 1996:] The would benefit both future generations and the adjustment, for Pigou, was a matter for the present poor without significantly affecting state, rather than the family: Pigou argued current national income. This Cambridge that because of our defective telescopic fac- tradition (Marshall-Pigou-Ramsey) con- ulty and the weak links provided by blood stituted a thread of immanent criticism which and time the state should have a positive led to a very positive role for the state in role: investment decisions, particularly those relat- There is wide agreement that the State ing to humari capital. [Collard 1996:595, should protect the interests of the future in 596]2) some degree against the effects of our ir- In contrast with Pigou's and Sidgwick's rational discounting and of our preference stress on the role of the state, for Marshall for ourselves over our descendents.... It is the family and the individual were rather the clear duty of Government, which is the more central and strategic to economic prog- trustee for unborn generations as well as ress and growth. The `family affection' was l for its present citizens, to watch over, and, not merely an engine of saving, capital accu- 1 : if need be, by legislative enactment, to mulation, and economic growth, it was, for defend, the exhaustible resources of the Marshall, a vehicle for human improvement country from rash and reckless spoliation'. and generational enhancement. Marshall had 1 [Pigou 1920: 28-29] emphasized a more crucial role for strong individuality, the family, and the intermedi- In his invocation of the state as the vehicle ate organizations and institutions rather than for taking a longer view than individuals and the state. He put his trust in education, 1 families, it is clear that Pigou was following morality, altruism, together with the growth Mill and Sidgwick. Sidgwick argued, in "The of knowledge and intellectual power. The 1 Art of Political Economy" of Tlhe Pn'nciples best that people could do was to leave the of Pblitical Economp : `if .it is economically `strongest and most vigorous progeny' with a advantageous to a nation to keep up forests, good physical, mental, and moral education. 1 on account of their beneficial effects in Throughout, Marshall emphasizes the evolu- : moderating and equalizing rainfall, the tion of `prudential behaviour', `the habit of 1 advantage is one which private enterprise has vividly realizing the future and providing for no tendency to provide; since no one could iV. [ibid: 591] appropriate and sell improvements in cli- Marshall wrote in the chapter on "Indus- mate'. [Sidgwick 1883 : 406-7] trial Training": Most parents are willing enough to do for 2. 2 Pigou and Marshall their children what their own parents did Collard's arguments are particularly inter- for them; and perhaps even to go beyond it esting because of his emphasis on `the if they find themselves among neighbours Marshall-Pigou fascination with human capi- who happen to have a rather higher stan- tal'.
Recommended publications
  • Alfred Marshall on Big Business
    ALFRED MARSHALL ON BIG BUSINESS Jaques Kerstenetzky1 This paper is about the way Alfred Marshall, the champion of the family-owned and -managed firm, approached the phenomenon which Alfred Chandler considered as the emergence of a new kind of capitalism and enterprise, characterized by the presence of corporations.2 The examination of the theme involves history and theory. And, following Marshall’s judgment that history is not a purely inductive practice, nor is theory a purely deductive one, it is an opportunity for reflecting on the historical and institutional content of Marshall’s perusal of firm's nature, size, organization and coordination. The task includes the identification of some connections among the work of the two Alfreds. The theme inevitably refers to the classical issue of the dilemma of increasing returns and competition. The dilemma will be presented as the theoretical context and will work as a unifying thread through the paper. The paper is organized in two parts. The first part is an introduction to the Marshallian approach on business organization issues. It shall place Marshall’s work into historical context, and characterize Marshall’s work in a way which is different from how he is read and was incorporated into economic theory by mainstream economics. The second part specifically approaches Industry and Trade, the book in which Marshall discussed business organization in depth.3 1. Introduction to Marshall’s work on business organization 1.1 The historical and theoretical context of Marshall’s work on business organization The historical economic context of Marshall’s writings is the second industrial revolution, hatched in the last quarter of the nineteenth century.
    [Show full text]
  • Markets in Higher Education: Can We Still Learn from Economics' Founding Fathers?* Abstract
    Research & Occasional Paper Series: CSHE.4.06 UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, BERKELEY http://cshe.berkeley.edu/ MARKETS IN HIGHER EDUCATION: CAN WE STILL LEARN * FROM ECONOMICS’ FOUNDING FATHERS? March 2006 Pedro Nuno Teixeira Assistant Professor of Economics; Research Associate, CEMPRE and CIPES University of Porto and Visiting Scholar, Center for Studies in Higher Education, UC Berkeley Copyright 2006 Pedro Nuno Teixeira, all rights reserved. ABSTRACT Markets or market-like mechanisms are playing an increasing role in higher education, with visible consequences both for the regulation of higher education systems as a whole, as well as for the governance mechanisms of individual institutions. This article traces the history of economists’ views on the role of education, from Adam Smith, John Stuart Mill, Alfred Marshall, and Milton Friedman, to present-day debates about the relevance of market economies to higher education policy. Recent developments in higher education policy reflect both the rising strength of market mechanisms in higher education worldwide, and a certain ambivalence about these developments. The author argues that despite the peculiarities of the higher education sector, economic theory can be a very useful tool for the analysis of the current state of higher education systems and recent trends in higher education policy. Introduction Markets or market-like mechanisms are playing an increasing role in higher education, with visible consequences both for the regulation of higher education (HE) * The author is Assistant Professor in the Economics Department at the University of Porto and Research Associate of CEMPRE (Centre for Macroeconomics and Forecasting) and CIPES (Portuguese National Research Centre on Higher Education Policy).
    [Show full text]
  • Monetary Theory
    MONETARY THEORY Henry H. Villard I. I ntroduction In t h e social sciences our accumulated knowledge is so small and the unexplored areas so vast that of necessity we measure progress by the understanding we obtain of particular and pressing problems. Thus Adam Smith did not write primarily as a scholar but rather as a social surgeon to remove from the body politic the surviving malignant remnant of Mercantilism, while the emphasis of Ricardo and Mill on diminishing returns and the rent of land directly reflected their interest in the ulti­ mately successful campaign of the rising business classes to end the im­ pediment to further industrialization represented by the Com Laws. In the same way recent monetary theory direcdy reflects the unprece­ dented depression which rocked the industrialized world during the nine­ teen-thirties; in the United States, perhaps worse hit than any other country, the increase in productive capital, which had averaged 6 per cent a year for the first three decades of the century, over the ’thirties as a whole was negligible in amount. As a result the center of interest has in general shifted from the factors determining the quantity of money and its effect on the general level of prices to those determining the level of output and employment. In addition, the purely monetary devices for control, on which great store had been laid, were found to be broadly ineffective, taken by themselves, in bringing about recovery from the Great Depression. And finally, as a result of the way in which the war was financed, it seems quite likely that it will prove impossible to use such devices for the effective control of a future boom.
    [Show full text]
  • Utilitarianism Without Utility: a Missed Opportunity in Alfred Marshall's Theory of Market Choice
    Utilitarianism without Utility: A Missed Opportunity in Alfred Marshall’s Theory of Market Choice Marco Dardi In his early economic writings1 Alfred Marshall analyzed the basic mar- ket choice—whether to accept or turn down a proposed transaction—in terms of an internal confl ict between opposing desires: that of acquiring property or other rights, on the one hand, and that of keeping hold of what is required in exchange, on the other. Transactions in which the forces of the confl icting desires happen to balance constitute the so-called margin of indecision. Indeed, in modern societies practically all transactions are settled by means of money transfers. Thus, the desire for money can be taken to be a common ingredient of all these internal confl icts. In marginal transactions, the desire to keep or acquire the amount of money transferred offsets the net resultant force of all the other desires involved. Conse- quently, if it were possible to measure its force, the desire for money would provide a common measure of the net force of all the various desires, the satisfaction of which is attained through marginal transactions. Lacking such a measurement, we can at least take the amount of money transferred, which is measurable, as a rough, indirect indicator of force. Economics Correspondence may be addressed to Marco Dardi, Via delle Pandette 9, 50127 Firenze, Italy; e-mail: marco.dardi@unifi .it. I wish to thank three anonymous referees for comments and useful suggestions. 1. The relevant texts for the present discussion are the manuscript essays “Value” and “Money” (early 1870s), published in Marshall 1975, vol.
    [Show full text]
  • Regulation and the Marginalist Revolution
    Florida Law Review Volume 71 Issue 2 Article 4 Regulation and the Marginalist Revolution Herbert Hovenkamp Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.ufl.edu/flr Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons Recommended Citation Herbert Hovenkamp, Regulation and the Marginalist Revolution, 71 Fla. L. Rev. 455 (). Available at: https://scholarship.law.ufl.edu/flr/vol71/iss2/4 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by UF Law Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Florida Law Review by an authorized editor of UF Law Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Hovenkamp: Regulation and the Marginalist Revolution REGULATION AND THE MARGINALIST REVOLUTION Herbert Hovenkamp* Abstract The marginalist revolution in economics became the foundation for the modern regulatory State with its “mixed” economy. For the classical political economists, value was a function of past averages. Marginalism substituted forward looking theories based on expectations about firm and market performance. Marginalism swept through university economics, and by 1920 or so virtually every academic economist was a marginalist. This Article considers the historical influence of marginalism on regulatory policy in the United States. My view is at odds with those who argue that marginalism saved capitalism by rationalizing it as a more defensible buttress against incipient socialism. While marginalism did permit economists and policy makers to strike a middle ground between laissez faire and socialism, the “middle ground” tilted very strongly toward public control. Ironically, regulation plus private ownership was able to go much further in the United States than socialism ever could because it preserved the rhetoric of capital as privately owned, even as it deprived firms of many of the most important indicia of ownership.
    [Show full text]
  • Selected Critiques of the Philosophical Underpinnings of the Neoclassical School
    Portland State University PDXScholar University Honors Theses University Honors College 2014 Selected Critiques of the Philosophical Underpinnings of the Neoclassical School Thomas Howell Portland State University Follow this and additional works at: https://pdxscholar.library.pdx.edu/honorstheses Let us know how access to this document benefits ou.y Recommended Citation Howell, Thomas, "Selected Critiques of the Philosophical Underpinnings of the Neoclassical School" (2014). University Honors Theses. Paper 59. https://doi.org/10.15760/honors.91 This Thesis is brought to you for free and open access. It has been accepted for inclusion in University Honors Theses by an authorized administrator of PDXScholar. Please contact us if we can make this document more accessible: [email protected]. 1 Selected Critiques of the Philosophical Underpinnings of the Neoclassical School Presented as an Undergraduate Thesis Project to the Honors College of Portland State University May, 27 th 2014 Student: Thomas Howell Advisor: Professor John Hall Abstractus : This inquiry seeks to establish the importance of the critiques leveled by Thorstein Veblen and Tony Lawson against the orthodox economics. In order to advance this point this inquiry advances the notion that Neoclassical school and its sub school known as marginal utility theory are constructed upon shaky philosophical and methodological foundations that include the hedonistic conception of man, Benthamite Utilitarianism, static equilibria, and the use of the mathematical deductivist method far beyond its scope of effectiveness. Writing in two different time periods, Veblen and Lawson comment upon the same essential methodological maladies and then advance alternative methodologies and ontologies aimed at reorienting a classical physics based economics towards a social- biological future.
    [Show full text]
  • Neoclassical Economics: Some Marshallian Insights
    Annals of the „Constantin Brâncuşi” University of Târgu Jiu, Economy Series, Issue 4/2016 NEOCLASSICAL ECONOMICS: SOME MARSHALLIAN INSIGHTS PROF. KRUME NIKOLOSKI PHD GOCE DELCHEV UNIVERSITY - STIP, REPUBLIC OF MACEDONIA E-mail: [email protected] Abstract In this paper are going to be analyzed the theories of supply, demand and equilibrium. It is about a neoclassical economics, Nobel laureate economist Alfred Marshall who is the inventor of the analyzed theories. And of course that these theories which that are subject to elaboration remain valid till today in the modern market economy conditions. Marshall also was the first who introduced the term "economics", which is in mass use. He studied, primarily the problems of production, distribution, exchange and consumption in terms of individuals, households, enterprises. With its total work appears as the founder of macroeconomics. I personally believe, that understanding the different approaches and perspectives on the economy, the reasons for these differences and how they evolved over time, provides a historical and philosophical context that encourages most economists to use critical analysis of current economic tools and their application. Keywords: demand, supply, production, competition, distribution. Classification JEL: B0, B1, B3 1. Introduction Alfred Marshall (1842-1924) is one of the biggest, best and most respected English economists of his time. After finishing his studies in Cambridge, ten years working as a math teacher, then a few years president of the University of Bristol, and finally, more than twenty years, until his retirement, head of the Department of Political Economy at the University of Cambridge. In 1970 he resided the United States to study economics.
    [Show full text]
  • On Money Rovaniemi: University of Lapland 2010, 324 Pp., Acta Universitatis Lapponiensis 175 Dissertation: University of Lapland ISSN 0788-7604 ISBN 978-952-484-351-5
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Lauda 8IVS%YZMRIR 3R1SRI] %OEXIIQMRIRZÈMXÚWOMVNENSOE0ETMR]PMSTMWXSR ]LXIMWOYRXEXMIXIMHIRXMIHIOYRRERWYSWXYQYOWIPPE IWMXIXÈÈRNYPOMWIWXMXEVOEWXIXXEZEOWM 0ETMR]PMSTMWXSR)WOSNE%WOSWEPMWWE OIWOMZMMOOSREOIPPS %GXE)PIGXVSRMGE9RMZIVWMXEXMW0ETTSRMIRWMW 9RMZIVWMX]SJ0ETPERH *EGYPX]SJ7SGMEP7GMIRGIW 'ST]VMKLX8IVS%YZMRIR (MWXVMFYXSV0ETPERH9RMZIVWMX]4VIWW 43&S\ *-6SZERMIQM XIP JE\ TYFPMGEXMSR$YPETPERH [[[YPETPERH PYT 4ETIVFEGO -7&2 -772 THJ -7&2 -772 [[[YPETPERH YRMTYFEGXERIX 3 Abstract Auvinen Tero On Money Rovaniemi: University of Lapland 2010, 324 pp., Acta Universitatis Lapponiensis 175 Dissertation: University of Lapland ISSN 0788-7604 ISBN 978-952-484-351-5 The study explores the political choices and confl icts inherent in the “technical” specifi cations of any monetary system and some of the social scientifi c implications of the prevailing forms of money in the widest possible sense of the terms. As a constantly evolving social relation, no single theory of money is likely to capture its tremendous capacity for self-transformation. It is argued that the precise manner in which the prevailing forms of fi nancial capital in general and money in particular are socially constructed creates a privileged reality for fi nancial capital which distorts competition among the diff erent factors of production and eliminates money’s capacity to accurately capture and reproduce real world economic phenomena – if possible even in theory. Contrary to some of the traditional economistic legitimating narratives for money, it is suggested that control over the issuance and circulation of money may render various aspects of the human governable with a fraction of the resources that might be required to implement comparable combinations of coercion and rewards through alternative institutional mechanisms.
    [Show full text]
  • Alfred Marshall, Evolutionary Economics and Climate Change
    Department Discussion Paper DDP2001 ISSN 1914-2838 ALFRED MARSHALL, EVOLUTIONARY ECONOMICS AND CLIMATE CHANGE Fourth Annual Tiziano Raffaelli Lecture, STOREP Conference, Rome, October 2020 Sheila Dow Department of Economics, University of Victoria Victoria, B.C., Canada V8W 2Y2 October 2020 Abstract The way in which any topic is analysed in economics depends on methodological approach. The purpose here is to explore the argument that the way in which climate change is addressed depends on how economics is understood to relate to the physical environment and also to the social and ethical environment. This involves an exploration of the formation of knowledge, both in economics and in the economy. Alfred Marshall’s evolutionary approach to knowledge formation was central to his approach to economics and to his understanding of economic behaviour. Here we consider the application of Marshall’s approach to issues around climate change, through the lens of the subsequent development of evolutionary economics and ecological economics. Keywords: Alfred Marshall, evolutionary economics, environmental economics, ecological economics JEL Classifications: B31, B52, Q54, Q57 Author Contact: Sheila Dow, Dept. of Economics, University of Victoria, P.O. Box 1700, STN CSC, Victoria, B.C., Canada V8W 2Y2; E-mail: [email protected]; [email protected] 1 Alfred Marshall, Evolutionary Economics and Climate Change1 Introduction It is a tremendous honour to be invited to give the Raffaelli Lecture. I met Professor Raffaelli originally through Professor Brian Loasby, my colleague at the University of Stirling. Tiziano impressed me from the start as the epitome of a scholar and a gentleman, and the legacy of his work on Marshall provides a fine illustration of the power of ideas.
    [Show full text]
  • Marshallian Cross Diagrams and Their Uses Before Alfred Marshall: the Origins of Supply and Demand Geometry
    Marshallian Cross Diagrams and Their Uses before Alfred Marshall: The Origins of Supply and Demand Geometry ThonaasM. Humphrey And Karl Rau (184 l), Jules Dupuit (1844), Hans von Mangoldt (1863), and Fleeming Jenkin (1870) thor- Undoubtedly the simplest. and most frequently oughly developed it years before Marshall presented used tool of microeconomic analysis is the conven- it in his Pzm Theory of Domestic Vafues (1879) and tional partial equilibrium demand-and-supply-curve later in his Pnitciples of fionomics (1890). Far from diagram of the textbooks. Economics professors merely introducing the diagram, these writers applied and their students put the diagram to at least six it to derive many of the concepts and theories often main uses. They use it to depict the equilibrium or attributed to Marshall or his followers. The notions market-clearing price and quantity of any particular of price elasticity of demand and supply, of stability good or factor input. They employ it to show how of equilibrium, of the possibility of multiple equilibria, (Walrasian) price or (Marshallian) quantity adjust- of comparative statics analyses involving shifts in the ments ensure this equilibrium: the first by eliminating curves, of consumers’ and producers’ surplus, of con- excess supply and demand, the second by eradicating stant, increasing and decreasing costs, of pricing of disparities between supply price and demand price. joint and composite products, of potential benefits They use it to illustrate how parametric shifts in of price discrimination, of tax incidence analysis, of demand and supply curves induced by changes in deadweight-welfare-loss triangles and the allocative tastes, incomes, technology, factor prices, and prices inefficiency of monopoly: all find expression in of related goods operate to alter a good’s equilibrium early expositions of the diagram.
    [Show full text]
  • Working Paper No. 36, the Rise of Marginalism: the Philosophical Foundations of Neoclassical Economic Thought
    Portland State University PDXScholar Working Papers in Economics Economics 5-19-2014 Working Paper No. 36, The Rise of Marginalism: The Philosophical Foundations of Neoclassical Economic Thought Emily Pitkin Portland State University Follow this and additional works at: https://pdxscholar.library.pdx.edu/econ_workingpapers Part of the Economic History Commons, and the Economic Theory Commons Let us know how access to this document benefits ou.y Citation Details Pitkin, Emily. "The Rise of Marginalism: The Philosophical Foundations of Neoclassical Economic Thought, Working Paper No. 36", Portland State University Economics Working Papers. 36. (19 May 2014) i + 14 pages. This Working Paper is brought to you for free and open access. It has been accepted for inclusion in Working Papers in Economics by an authorized administrator of PDXScholar. Please contact us if we can make this document more accessible: [email protected]. The Rise of Marginalism: The Philosophical Foundations of Neoclassical Economic Thought Working Paper No. 36 Authored by: Emily Pitkin A Contribution to the Working Papers of the Department of Economics, Portland State University Submitted for: EC 460, “History of Economic Thought” 19 May 2014; i + 14 pages Prepared for Professor John Hall Abstract: This inquiry examines the works of the early thinkers in marginalist theory and seeks to establish that certain philosophical assumptions about the nature of man led to the development and ultimate ascendance of neoclassical thought in the field of economics. Jeremy Bentham’s key assumption, which he develops in his 1781 work, A Fragment on Government and an Introduction to the Principles of Morals and Legislation, that men are driven by the forces of pain and pleasure led directly to William Stanley Jevons and Carl Menger’s investigation and advancement of utility maximization theory one hundred years after Bentham, in 1871.
    [Show full text]
  • The Great Economists Alfred Marshall
    The Great Economists Edited by Corrado Bevilacqua Alfred Marshall I libri di laprimaradice.myblog.it To readers. Alfred Marshall was the dominant figure in British economics (itself dominant in world economics) from about 1890 until his death in 1924. His specialty was microeconomics—the study of individual markets and industries, as opposed to the study of the whole economy. In his most important book, Principles of Economics, Marshall emphasized that the price and output of a good are determined by both supply and demand: the two curves are like scissor blades that intersect at equilibrium. Modern economists trying to understand why the price of a good changes still start by looking for factors that may have shifted demand or supply, an approach they owe to Marshall. To Marshall also goes credit for the concept of price elasticity of demand, which quantifies buyers’ sensitivity to price (see demand). The concept of consumer surplus is another of Marshall’s contributions. He noted that the price is typically the same for each unit of a commodity that a consumer buys, but the value to the consumer of each additional unit declines. A consumer will buy units up to the point where the marginal value equals the price. Therefore, on all units previous to the last one, the consumer reaps a benefit by paying less than the value of the good to himself. The size of the benefit equals the difference between the consumer’s value of all these units and the amount paid for the units. This difference is called the consumer surplus, for the surplus value or utility enjoyed by consumers.
    [Show full text]