Trade, Globalization and the Financial Crisis by Mark A

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Trade, Globalization and the Financial Crisis by Mark A VOL. 4, NO. 8 NOVEMBER 2009­­ EconomicLetter Insights from the FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS Trade, Globalization and the Financial Crisis by Mark A. Wynne and Erasmus K. Kersting The financial crisis that began in August 2007 and intensified in the The recession’s heavy fall of 2008 pushed the global economy into a severe downturn that some have toll on world trade called the Great Recession. World trade collapsed at a pace unseen since the Great raises the possibility Depression of the 1930s. The decline in trade and the protectionist instincts that of deglobalization. invariably come to the fore in difficult economic times have raised concerns that today’s crisis may lead to deglobalization—a reversal of the globalization that has characterized the past three decades. In this Economic Letter, we will illustrate the crisis’ impact on world trade and examine the typical patterns of international trade over the business cycle. We urge caution in using trade data to estimate the extent of globalization or deglobalization. And we present evidence that international trade has fallen by more than expected given the course of the current business cycle. This raises the question of what unprecedented. During the recession might have accounted for the excess of 2001, for example, global trade decline. We look at two possibilities: increased 0.3 percent, largely due to first, a direct effect on trade flows continued export growth in the emerg- associated with a drying up of trade ing market economies. finance at the height of the crisis; One measure, based on work second, a breakout of protectionist by the economic historians Barry measures. We conclude that trade Eichengreen and Kevin O’Rourke, finance is the most likely explana- suggests that declines in international Declines in tion. However, it’s vitally important trade have exceeded the losses dur- to remain vigilant to the risks of ing the 1930s. Indexing to the peaks international trade protectionism. The Great Depression in global industrial production in of the 1930s would have been less both episodes, global trade fell 32 have exceeded the severe had countries not resorted to percent during the first year of the ultimately self-defeating protectionist Great Recession, compared with 15 losses during measures. percent during the first year of the Great Depression (Chart 2). Of course, the 1930s. International Trade Collapses trade continued to ebb for years in the According to the October 2009 1930s, an unlikely prospect this time edition of the International Monetary around given the recent improvements Fund’s World Economic Outlook, in the world economy. international trade as measured by The collapse of world trade has total exports of goods and services manifested itself in shipping costs. will decline 11.9 percent this year. While we don’t have a comprehensive Advanced economies’ exports will measure of how much it costs to ship fall 13.6 percent, while emerging and goods around the world, two closely developing economies face a more watched indexes capture significant modest 7.2 percent slump (Chart segments of the market. 1). Declines of these magnitudes are The Baltic Dry Index tells us what is going on with dry bulk commodi- ties, such as coal, iron ore and grain. After peaking at 11,793 on May 20, 2008, the index collapsed to 663 on Chart 1 Dec. 5, then posted gradual improve- Global Trade Falls in Financial Crisis ments over the course of this year. The Harpex index, produced on a Annual percent change in volume of exports of goods and services weekly basis by the shipbroking firm 15 Harper Petersen, measures the cost of shipping containers. It dropped 76 10 percent between February 2008 and June 2009. 5 Of course, the U.S. hasn’t been immune to these developments (Chart 3). U.S. import volume peaked in the 0 third quarter of 2007, when the finan- Emerging and developing economies cial crisis began. Export volume con- –5 World Advanced economies tinued to rise until the second quarter of 2008, when the crisis went global. –10 So what, if anything, do these data tell us about the fate of globalization? –15 Has globalization gone into reverse? To 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2009 address this question, we consider two SOURCE: World Economic Outlook, International Monetary Fund, October 2009. issues. The first centers on the normal behavior of international trade flows EconomicLetter 2 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS EconomicLetter over the business cycle. Are imports and exports more volatile than overall Chart 2 economic activity, or less volatile? The second involves the usefulness of trade Trade Losses: Great Depression Vs. Great Recession flows to measure globalization. Does more international trade always mean Index 130 more globalization? 120 Considering Deglobalization 110 June 1929 = 100 Two points are noteworthy once 100 we isolate U.S. business-cycle ups and 90 downs from the economy’s long-run growth. First, exports and imports 80 tend to move in the same direction 70 April 2008 = 100 as GDP—that is, they’re procyclical 60 (Chart 4). Second, exports and imports 50 are more volatile than the overall economy. 40 The scatter of points in Chart 30 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38 40 42 44 46 48 50 52 4A plots the cyclical component of Months since peak U.S. exports each quarter against SOURCE: Authors’ calculations following “A Tale of Two Depressions,” by Barry Eichengreen and Kevin O’Rourke, the cyclical component of U.S. GDP. VoxEU.org, September 2009, http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/3421. Note that the line fitted to the scat- ter is steeper than the 45-degree line. That is, when the cyclical component of GDP declines by a given amount, the cyclical component of exports Chart 3 tends to decline by more. Likewise, when the cyclical component of GDP U.S. Trade Tails Off, Too increases by a given amount, the cyclical component of exports tends Index, 2005 = 100 to increase by more. A similar pattern 140 is seen in the scatter for the cyclical 120 component of U.S. imports and GDP in Chart 4B. 100 GDP’s cyclical movements range Exports of goods and services (volume) between –5 percent and 5 percent, 80 well below the low of –15 and high of 15 percent for both exports and 60 imports. The average volatility of GDP (standard deviation) is about 1.7 per- 40 Imports of goods and cent, compared with 5.6 percent for services (volume) exports and 5.2 percent for imports. 20 Why are trade flows so much more volatile than the overall econ- 0 1980 1984 1988 1992 1996 2000 2004 2008 omy? Part of the reason may be that NOTE: Shaded areas represent U.S. recessions. trade is still heavily skewed toward SOURCE: Bureau of Economic Analysis. goods rather than services. Measured by value, goods make up 70 per- cent of U.S. exports and 84 percent of imports. By comparison, goods account for only a fifth of overall U.S. production, measured as a share of value added. Using a broader defini- EconomicLetter FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS 3 EconomicLetter tion—the sum of agriculture, mining, One can illustrate this point with a construction and manufacturing—rais- simple supply and demand picture for es goods’ share of the economy, but some hypothetical good traded inter- only to 30 percent. nationally (Chart 5A). Assume a world Because trade flows depend heav- price at which we can buy as much ily on the volatile goods sector, they as we want—thus, the supply curve is tend to increase more in good times flat. How much we purchase will be and decline more in bad times than determined by the domestic demand A global recession the rest of the economy. If that’s so, it for imports of this good, the down- shouldn’t come as a great surprise that ward slope indicating we’ll buy more that reduced import trade flows have dried up in the midst as it gets cheaper. of a severe global recession. Far from Transportation costs, barri- demand will lead to telling us about incipient deglobaliza- ers to trade and other factors create tion, the decline in trade may simply a gap between the domestic and declines in trade— be a cyclical phenomenon. world prices. The size of this distor- There are other reasons to be tion will determine just how much of but it needn’t skeptical of what trade flows can tell the good we import and consume. us about globalization. To economists, Improvements in transport and com- signify a reversal of globalization is about the integration of munications technology and more lib- national economies into a single global eral trade policies will reduce the dif- economic integration. market. While imports and exports ference between the home and world may be symptomatic of such integra- prices (Chart 5B). As domestic prices tion, they’re not synonymous with it. fall, trade will increase. This is what Economists generally favor another we mean by globalization. measure—how close domestic prices But note that trade volumes are to the ones prevailing on world can change without markets becom- markets. ing more integrated. For example, a Chart 4 Business Cycle Volatility Is Greater for Trade Flows A. Exports B. Imports Cycle in exports (percent) Cycle in imports (percent) 25 25 20 20 15 15 10 10 5 5 0 0 5 –5 –10 –10 –15 –15 –20 –20 –25 –25 –25 –20 –15 –10 –5 0 5 10 15 20 25 –25 –20 –15 –10 –5 0 5 10 15 20 25 Cycle in GDP (percent) Cycle in GDP (percent) SOURCE: Authors’ calculations using data from Bureau of Economic Analysis.
Recommended publications
  • Globalization and Financial Development
    Globalization and Financial Development Frederic S. Mishkin Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System October 2007 This paper is based on a speech at the New Perspectives on Financial Globalization Conference at the International Monetary Fund in Washington, D.C. on April 26, 2007. I thank Steve Kamin and Shaghil Ahmed for their comments and assistance on this paper. Note that the opinions expressed here are my own and not necessarily those of my colleagues on the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC). - 1 - ABSTRACT This paper argues that globalization is a key factor in stimulating institutional reforms in developing countries that promote financial development and economic growth. Advanced countries can help in this process by supporting the opening of their markets to goods and services from emerging market countries. By encouraging these countries to increase their participation in global markets, advanced countries can create exactly the right incentives for developing countries to implement the reforms that will enable them to have high economic growth. Our parents drill into us that the key to success is hard work. Yet when we look at many developing countries, we see people who work extremely hard for long hours. Their wages are low, and so they remain poor. And as a whole, their countries remain poor. If hard work does not make a country rich, what does? The right institutions are essential. Nobel laureate Douglass North defines institutions as the “rules of the game in a society, or, more formally, humanly devised constraints that shape human intervention.” (North, 1990, p. 3). Among the institutions that are most crucial to economic growth are those that enable a country to allocate capital to its most productive uses.
    [Show full text]
  • Trade Globalization and Political Liberalization: a Gravity Approach
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Yu, Miaojie Working Paper Trade globalization and political liberalization: A gravity approach TIGER Working Paper Series, No. 104 Provided in Cooperation with: TIGER - Transformation, Integration and Globalization Economic Research, Warsaw Suggested Citation: Yu, Miaojie (2007) : Trade globalization and political liberalization: A gravity approach, TIGER Working Paper Series, No. 104, Transformation, Integration and Globalization Economic Research (TIGER), Warsaw This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/140756 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der
    [Show full text]
  • The Contemporary Crisis in Globalization and Its Impact on Latin America with Special Reference to the Caribbean Region of Latin America
    The Contemporary Crisis in Globalization and its impact on Latin America with special reference to the Caribbean region of Latin America Jessica Byron Introduction This contribution evolved out of a panel discussion that was organized around a series of questions concerning the development and evolu- tion of globalization since the 1990s; the potential consequences of the current political crises for the future of globalization processes; and the major implications and lessons on the way forward for Latin American and Caribbean economies and societies. The following sections first make reference to major features of globalization and to the earlier discourse on its implications, which remain relevant to our analyses of the contemporary tendencies. Thereafter, I discuss the consequences of these new developments for countries and regions in the South. The final section examines the outlook specifically for small, developing economies in the Greater Caribbean sub-region of Latin America and the Caribbean. I. The development and evolution of globalization since the 1990s The discussion draws from three definitions and observations about globalization. Mittelman (1997:3) describes it as “a worldwide phenomenon […] a coalescence of varied transnational processes and domestic structures, allowing the economy, politics, culture and ideology of one country to penetrate another. The chain of causality runs from the spatial reorganization of production to inter- national trade, to the integration of production and to the integration of financial markets […] driven by changing modes of competition, 97 The Contemporary Crisis in Globalization and its impact on Latin America with special reference to the Caribbean region of Latin America globalization compresses the time and space aspects of social relations […] (it is) a market-induced, not policy-led process”.
    [Show full text]
  • A History of Globalization 1750-2050
    Department of History University of Warwick 3rd Year Advanced Option Course HI 31V A HISTORY OF GLOBALIZATION 1750-2050 Module Booklet 2018-19 Course Tutor: Giorgio Riello Department of History Room H014, ext. 22163 Email: [email protected] 1 HI 31V ONE WORLD: A HISTORY OF GLOBALIZATION, 1750-2050 Context We are perennially told that we live in a ‘global society’, that the world is fast becoming a ‘global village’ and that this is an age of ‘globalisation’. Yet globalisation, the increasing connectedness of the world, is not a new phenomenon. This course provides a historical understanding of globalisation over the period from the mid eighteenth century to the present. It aims to introduce students to key theoretical debates and multidisciplinary discussions about globalisation and to reflect on what a historical approach might add to our understanding of our present-day society and economy. The course considers a variety of topics including the environment, migration, the power of multinationals and financial institutions, trade, communication and the critique of globalisation. Principal Aims To introduce students through a thematic approach to modern global history (post 1750) and the history of globalization. To introduce students to key theories of globalization. To train students to consider contemporary debates in a historical perspective. To explore a range of topics related to globalization and understand how some key features of human history have changed over the period from 1750 to the present. To understand how globalization has shaped people’s lives since the industrial revolution. To provide students with perspectives on Globalization from the point of view of different world areas (ex: China, India, and Africa).
    [Show full text]
  • Megatrends the Deglobalization Myth(S)
    Vanguard Research: Megatrends The deglobalization myth(s) About the Megatrends series Megatrends have accompanied humankind throughout history. From the Neolithic Revolution to the Information Age, innovation has been the catalyst for profound socioeconomic, cultural, and political transformation. The term “Megatrends” was popularized by author John Naisbitt, who was interested in the transformative forces that have a major impact on both businesses and societies, and thus the potential to change all areas of our personal and professional lives. Vanguard’s “Megatrends” is a research effort that investigates fundamental shifts in the global economic landscape that are likely to affect the financial services industry and broader society. A megatrend may bring market growth or destroy it, increase competition or add barriers to entry, and create threats or uncover opportunities. Exploring the long-term nature of massive shifts in technology, demographics, and globalization can help us better understand how such forces may shape future markets, individuals, and the investing landscape in the years ahead. Vanguard Investment Strategy Group’s Global Economics Team From left to right: Joseph Davis, Ph.D., Global Chief Economist; Roger A. Aliaga-Díaz, Ph.D., Americas Chief Economist; Peter Westaway, Ph.D., Europe Chief Economist; Qian Wang, Ph.D., Asia-Pacific Chief Economist Americas: Jonathan Lemco, Ph.D.; Andrew J. Patterson, CFA; Joshua M. Hirt, CFA; Maximilian Wieland; Asawari Sathe, M.Sc.; Adam J. Schickling, CFA Europe: Shaan Raithatha, CFA; Roxane Spitznagel; Griffin Tory Asia-Pacific: Beatrice Yeo, CFA; Alexis Gray, M.Sc. 2 Megatrend The deglobalization myth(s): Why slowing trade growth shouldn’t concern investors ■ While economists and policymakers have historically emphasized globalization’s benefits, the consensus is fracturing.
    [Show full text]
  • The Hyperglobalization of Trade and Its Future
    Working Paper Series WP 13-6 JULY 2013 The Hyperglobalization of Trade and Its Future Arvind Subramanian and Martin Kessler Abstract Th is paper describes seven salient features of trade integration in the 21st century: Trade integration has been more rapid than ever (hyperglobalization); it is dematerialized, with the growing importance of services trade; it is democratic, because openness has been embraced widely; it is criss-crossing because similar goods and investment fl ows now go from South to North as well as the reverse; it has witnessed the emergence of a mega-trader (China), the fi rst since Imperial Britain; it has involved the proliferation of regional and preferential trade agreements and is on the cusp of mega-region- alism as the world's largest traders pursue such agreements with each other; and it is impeded by the continued existence of high barriers to trade in services. Going forward, the trading system will have to tackle three fundamental challenges: In developed countries, the domestic support for globalization needs to be sustained in the face of economic weakness and the reduced ability to maintain social insurance mechanisms. Second, China has become the world’s largest trader and a major benefi ciary of the current rules of the game. It will be called upon to shoulder more of the responsibilities of maintaining an open system. Th e third challenge will be to prevent the rise of mega-regionalism from leading to discrimi- nation and becoming a source of trade confl icts. We suggest a way forward—including new areas of cooperation such as taxes—to maintain the open multilateral trading system and ensure that it benefi ts all countries.
    [Show full text]
  • First It Was the 2008 Global Financial Crisis. Then the Arab Spring. Then
    A SYMPOSIUM OF VIEWS Future Surprises That Could Shock the World irst it was the 2008 global financial crisis. Then the Arab Spring. Then Brexit. International conventional Fwisdom always seems unaware of the big changes about to unfold. There are in the present few facts about the future. Ten years ago, for example, who would have predicted surprise developments such as negative interest rates, the potential breakup of the European Union, the Donald Trump/Bernie Sanders effect, drones, the use of driverless cars, the rise of ISIS, the myriad uses of artificial intelligence and big data, U.S. energy independence, the emergence of the Zika virus, or the rate at which robots are taking away jobs. TIE asked more than fifty top thinkers to look ahead ten years at what outside-the-box developments THE MAGAZINE OF INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC POLICY could shock the world. 220 I Street, N.E., Suite 200 Washington, D.C. 20002 Phone: 202-861-0791 Fax: 202-861-0790 www.international-economy.com [email protected] 8 THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY SUMMER 2016 The breakup of the European Union. The Trump-Brexit The greater phenomenon will concentration of have destroyed power in the offices of presidents and the “common good.” policymakers. GARY CLYDE HUFBAUER W. BOWMAN CUTTER Reginald Jones Senior Fellow, Peterson Institute for Senior Fellow and Director, Economic Policy Initiative, International Economics Roosevelt Institute ot for me to speculate about drones or clones. Both “Things fell apart. The centre did not hold. will deliver surprises in the decade ahead, along Mere anarchy was loosed upon the world…” Nwith artificial intelligence, robots, magic materials, —William Butler Yeats (with apologies) and cures for cancer.
    [Show full text]
  • The Cost of Doing Nothing: the Price of Inaction in Response to the COVID-19 Crisis
    The cost of doing nothing: The price of inaction in response to the COVID-19 crisis Version: 10 July 2020 Authors: Dirk-Jan Omtzigt, Head, Humanitarian Financing Strategy and Analysis Unit, OCHA Ashley Pople, University of Oxford and consultant for OCHA Introduction The global crisis induced by the COVID-19 pandemic is unprecedented in nature. Emerging as a health crisis, the pandemic has become a threat to global prosperity and stability. Keeping in mind the fundamental uncertainty about the trajectory of the pandemic and the economic forecasts, there is common consensus that the global economy will experience the deepest recession since the Great Depression and the broadest collapse in per capita income since 1870. As of 24 June, the IMF projects a -4.9 percent contraction in global GDP in 2020, followed by a protracted and uneven recovery due to the persistence of the shock. The extent to which these downturns are synchronised and spill over across borders makes this crisis relatively unique. Domestically, the OECD and the G20 countries have responded with a large stimulus package estimated at over $11 trillion (approximately 10% of world GDP). In comparison, the cost of protecting the most vulnerable 10 percent of the world from the worst primary and secondary impacts of COVID-19 today is an additional $90 billion – less than 1 percent of the current stimulus package. Relative to high-income countries, “whatever it takes” is a fundamentally different concept in low-income countries due to limited forex reserves, central bank dollar swap lines and fiscal space. Strong multilateral coordination is required to meet the shortfall in financing and support the strengthening of health, education and other social safety nets – now, rather than later.
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Growth, Financial and Trade Globalization in the Philippines: a Vector Autoregressive Analysis
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive Economic Growth, Financial and Trade Globalization in the Philippines: A Vector Autoregressive Analysis Deluna, Roperto Jr and Chelly, Antiquisa University of Southeastern Philippines, School of Applied Economics August 2014 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/60206/ MPRA Paper No. 60206, posted 26 Nov 2014 07:18 UTC ECONOMIC GROWTH, FINANCIAL AND TRADE GLOBALIZATION IN THE PHILIPPINES: A VECTOR AUTOREGRESSIVE ANALYSIS Chelly P. Antiquisa and Roperto Deluna Jr Abstract This study was conducted to examine the relationship among Economic Growth, Financial and trade Globalization in the Philippines from 1980 to 2011. The study used the Vector Autoregressive VAR (1) model and Granger Causality test. It was found out that the current value of GDP is positively affected by the previous value of itself and trade openness. The estimation results suggested that growth in trade volumes accelerate economic growth. However, financial openness has no significant effect on the current value of GDP. This implies that the level of openness of the Philippine economy is not sufficient to obtain the potential benefits of financial globalization in enhancing economic growth. INTRODUCTION Financial globalization refers to the integration of all financial markets in the world. There are three major forces that have contributed importantly to the process of financial globalization and these are the (i) liberalization of capital movements and deregulation of financial services, (ii) the opening of markets to trade and investment spurring the growth of international competition and (iii) the important role played by information and communication technologies (ICT) in the economy (www.oecd.com). In general, the concept of financial globalization is the creation of global money market, global financial market and global financial system that entails an intensification of financial capital flows and expansion in degree of openness of national financial markets (Hetes, 2011).
    [Show full text]
  • Why Was Japan Hit So Hard by the Global Financial Crisis?
    ADBI Working Paper Series Why was Japan Hit So Hard by the Global Financial Crisis? Masahiro Kawai and Shinji Takagi No. 153 October 2009 Asian Development Bank Institute ADBI Working Paper 153 Kawai and Takagi Masahiro Kawai is the dean of the Asian Development Bank Institute. Shinji Takagi is a professor, Graduate School of Economics, Osaka University, Osaka, Japan. This is a revised version of the paper presented at the Samuel Hsieh Memorial Conference, hosted by the Chung-Hua Institution for Economic Research, Taipei,China 9–10 July 2009. The authors are thankful to Ainslie Smith for her editorial work. The views expressed in this paper are the views of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views or policies of ADBI, the Asian Development Bank (ADB), its Board of Directors, or the governments they represent. ADBI does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this paper and accepts no responsibility for any consequences of their use. Terminology used may not necessarily be consistent with ADB official terms. The Working Paper series is a continuation of the formerly named Discussion Paper series; the numbering of the papers continued without interruption or change. ADBI’s working papers reflect initial ideas on a topic and are posted online for discussion. ADBI encourages readers to post their comments on the main page for each working paper (given in the citation below). Some working papers may develop into other forms of publication. Suggested citation: Kawai, M., and S. Takagi. 2009. Why was Japan Hit So Hard by the Global Financial Crisis? ADBI Working Paper 153.
    [Show full text]
  • Coping with the Global Economic Crisis: a Challenge to Technical Vocational Education and Training (TVET) in Nigeria (Pp
    An International Multidisciplinary Journal, Ethiopia Vol. 6 (3), Serial No. 26, July, 2012 ISSN 1994-9057 (Print) ISSN 2070--0083 (Online) DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.4314/afrrev.v6i3.12 Coping with the Global Economic Crisis: A Challenge to Technical Vocational Education and Training (TVET) in Nigeria (Pp. 165-175) Ekpo, Aloysius B. - Department of Vocational Education, University of Uyo, Uyo, Akwa Ibom State, Nigeria Phone: 234-8029527712 E-mail: emmezik‘yahoo.com Onweh, Vincent Eze - Department of Vocational Education, University of Uyo, Uyo, Akwa Ibom State, Nigeria Phone: 234-8037463345 Abstract There is rapid transformation of the economics of the developed countries of the world-in the last two decades. This has resulted in global economic crisis affecting both the developing and underdeveloped countries of the world. The erratic changes have been creating new demands for more adaptable, multi- skilled and creative labour. To meet the demands, it has become necessary to reduce the gap between academic education and vocational education; to develop competence-based curriculum development mechanism; to strengthen the co-operation between education authorities, government/employment organizations as well as industries, to decentralize the delivery system and to involve employers more in the process of TVET. This paper is an attempt to x-ray the Nigerian situation in this time of Global Economic Crisis and the Challenge to TVET in Nigeria. Key words: TVET, global economy, globalization Copyright © IAARR 2012: www.afrrevjo.net 165 Indexed African Journals Online: www.ajol.info Vol. 6 (3) Serial No. 26, July, 2012. Pp. 165-175 Introduction The notion of crisis as adopted in this work is as defined by the Merriam Webster‘s Collegiate Dictionary, eleventh edition of 2003; where it states thus‖- crisis is an unstable or crucial time or state of affairs in which a decisive change is impending; especially one with the distinct possibility of a highly undesirable outcome.
    [Show full text]
  • A Proposal to Prevent Offshoring: an Analysis of the Latest Anti-Offshoring Proposals James Emilcar
    Journal of International Business and Law Volume 11 | Issue 1 Article 10 2012 A Proposal to Prevent Offshoring: An Analysis of the Latest Anti-Offshoring Proposals James Emilcar Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarlycommons.law.hofstra.edu/jibl Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Emilcar, James (2012) "A Proposal to Prevent Offshoring: An Analysis of the Latest Anti-Offshoring Proposals," Journal of International Business and Law: Vol. 11: Iss. 1, Article 10. Available at: http://scholarlycommons.law.hofstra.edu/jibl/vol11/iss1/10 This Notes & Student Works is brought to you for free and open access by Scholarly Commons at Hofstra Law. It has been accepted for inclusion in Journal of International Business and Law by an authorized administrator of Scholarly Commons at Hofstra Law. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Emilcar: A Proposal to Prevent Offshoring: An Analysis of the Latest Anti- A PROPOSAL TO PREVENT OFFSHORING: AN ANALYSIS OF THE LATEST ANTI-OFFSHORING PROPOSALS James Emilcar* I. INTRODUCTION Many companies are increasingly becoming aware of their ability to reduce costs significantly by offshoring personnel.' Indeed, a concern over the issue of offshoring has swept the country.' Many Americans are concerned that this business practice results in American job-loss.3 Offshoring-that is, moving jobs to a lower wage location-is a com- mon effect of globalization.4 Globalization is a process by which companies of different nations integrate into the international economy. 5 This process is driven by international trade and investment and fueled by innovative technological developments. 6 The concept of globalization provokes much debate and controversy for the American populace.
    [Show full text]