The Difference Between Productivity and Innovation – and the Implications for Growth and Equity Markets 12.04.2018   

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Difference Between Productivity and Innovation – and the Implications for Growth and Equity Markets 12.04.2018    Fund Search Luxembourg Our Firm Our Funds Our Firm Sustainability Our Funds Insights SEARCH The Difference between Productivity and Innovation – and the Implications for Growth and Equity Markets 12.04.2018 Summary Official productivity measurements have been falling for decades – a puzzling development given the rapid pace of high-tech innovations. But rather than functioning as productivity-enhancers, many of these innovations disrupt economies and markets. This could have major implications for jobs and productivity, and trigger unforeseen amounts of social and political change. 1 WELCOME TO THE FOURTH INDUSTRIAL REVOLUTION Technological innovations are taking place at a rapid and accelerating pace. Apps on our mobile phones enable us to search and find information to an extent that was unimaginable only a few years ago. The digital footprints we leave on the internet allow companies to use vast amounts of data to provide tailor-made advertisements. Self-driving cars will probably become commonplace in the not-too-distant future, while self-learning machines are already taking over functions that were once carried out by highly trained specialists. And these are just a few examples. Innovations in the digital world, notably artificial intelligence (AI), are likely to have an even more profound effect on a range of industries in the future – energy, manufacturing, retail, finance, legal and even healthcare are all expected to change significantly. In fact, the scale and scope of these technological changes have been described as a new industrial revolution – one that may be taking place right under our noses. The First Industrial Revolution – from the late 18th to mid-19th centuries – was all about the introduction of mechanical production processes, steam power and railways. The Second Industrial Revolution – from the late 19th century to the early 1930s – was characterised by major breakthroughs in the use of electricity, and by the invention of telephones, automobiles, the radio and plastics. The Third Industrial Revolution – from around 1950 to the early 2000s – saw the development of mainframe computers, personal computers (PCs), mobile phones and the internet. Since the beginning of this decade, some argue, we have been in the midst of a Fourth Industrial Revolution – one in which we can observe the fusing of the digital, physical and biological worlds. One of the earliest champions of this theory was Klaus Schwab, the founder of the Davos World Economic Forum. He has described the changes presented by the Fourth Industrial Revolution as “so profound … there has never been a time of greater promise or potential peril”. 2 WHERE HAS ALL THE PRODUCTIVITY GONE? The promise and perils of the Fourth Industrial Revolution can be applied first-hand to the concept of productivity. In other words, while today’s technological innovations may lead to significantly higher productivity – that is, much higher output per unit of input, often measured as output per hour worked – many of these technologies could also disrupt existing business processes. This could have major implications on labour markets, and trigger unforeseen amounts of social and political change. When we think about productivity in a traditional sense, we expect it to respond positively to the major technological innovations of the last few years. However, when analysing official productivity numbers, both in developed markets and in the emerging-market world, this does not seem to be the case. One is even tempted to repeat the famous Robert Solow quote from 1987: “You can see the computer age everywhere but in the productivity statistics”. According to Robert Gordon, one of the godfathers of productivity research, US labour productivity was around 2 1/3 per cent per year from the late 19th century onwards – that is, until the early 1970s. Since then, labour productivity has fallen to around 1 1/3 per cent per year, with the exception of a few years around 2000. Data provided by the Conference Board confirm these conclusions (see Figure A). Labour-productivity growth has been trending down in the developed markets for many years already – a trend that started well before the global financial crisis of 2007/2008. Even in China, the biggest emerging economy in the world, labour-productivity growth peaked in 2006. A: YEAR-OVER-YEAR PERCENTAGE CHANGE IN LABOUR PRODUCTIVITY, 3-YEAR CENTRED AVERAGE Source: Allianz Global Investors Global Economics & Strategy, The Conference Board. Data as at 2017. So how can we explain this perceived disconnect between technological innovation and low productivity numbers – and where has all the productivity gone? Unfortunately, as is often the case in the field of economics, there is no definite answer. Optimists would argue that we are still early in the multi-phase technological revolution cycle. During the current instalment phase – which is marked by the introduction of new innovations – aggregate productivity numbers still tend to be rather low. However, once we enter the deployment phase, new technologies are likely to be widely used. And once the labour force learns how to best use and apply these technologies, the argument goes, productivity is likely to pick up. In other words, optimists believe that it is only a question of when – and not if – the economy-wide productivity numbers will ultimately rise. The sectors that are likely to contribute most to productivity growth should be the most intensive digital-using sectors, rather than the tech sectors themselves. Seen through this lens, the problems presented by the potential mismeasurement of productivity are of negligible relevance, as various studies have shown. Robert Gordon1 and others take a much more pessimistic view of the long-term trend in productivity. To those in this camp, it is the lack of a “new general-purpose technology” that explains the structural decline we are seeing in productivity growth. Case in point: electricity, the major technological advance of the Second Industrial Revolution, is a technology sine qua non – one that drastically altered production processes across the board and had a massive impact on consumer behaviour. For evidence of how dependent we are on electricity, consider what happens during power outages: only a few hours after the lights go out, the world seems to come to a standstill. On the contrary, today’s technological innovations are potentially much less far-reaching – or so the argument goes. Moreover, Robert Gordon points to the overall declining trend of educational attainment – which is not only happening in the US – as an additional explanation for relatively weak productivity growth. There is another argument – and a very different one – for why the productivity trend has been declining, and it relates to monetary policy. According to this view, easy monetary conditions from central banks have lasted for too long, depressing the costs of capital and contributing to the misallocation of resources. With an artificially reduced hurdle rate for investment, there is an increasing likelihood that investments that deliver little or no boost to productivity growth will be implemented. Overinvestment in real estate during the “noughties” – which directly followed the popping of the tech bubble in 2000 – provides a classic example. The low interest rates in effect at that time pushed capital into the real-estate market, which is not a sector that has traditionally contributed a significant amount to productivity growth. In this context, one could even make the argument that monetary policy in the US and Europe since the mid-1980s has been asymmetric: expansionary in times of actual or expected economic downturns and crisis, but not sufficiently restrictive in boom times. As a result, this asymmetric monetary policy has contributed to the secular decline in productivity growth rates. The long-term solution is for central banks to normalise monetary policy, rather than to maintain or extend their ultra-easy stance. The jury is still out on which argument – the optimistic or pessimistic view – will answer the question of why productivity is falling, even as technological advancement is growing. Yet the facts are clear: the most recent wave of technological innovations has not yet led to a more efficient economy. It also seems that today’s technological revolution is likely to exacerbate labour-market trends that have been in place since the 1980s, as a consequence of the move towards automation and globalisation: In the middle-income segment of the population, there has been a decline in the demand for routine jobs such as clerking and manufacturing (seeFigure B). In the high-wage bracket, the share of labour has been growing in all major developed economies, due to rising demand for highly skilled employees. Interestingly, in the low-wage segment, the share of labour in most economies has been stable to rising – albeit accompanied by falling real wages. "THE MOST RECENT WAVE OF TECHNOLOGICAL INNOVATIONS HAS NOT YET LED TO A MORE EFFICIENT ECONOMY." B: ROUTINE JOBS ARE IN LESS DEMAND Source: C. B. Frey, T. Berger, C.Che, Political Machinery: Automation Anxiety and the 2016 U. S. Presidential Election, 2017 This trend seems likely to continue as new technologies make routine and manual jobs increasingly obsolete, while making highly skilled jobs harder to fill. For example, consider the skills that are in high demand in a technology-driven work environment: Strong IT and analytical skills (eg, data scientists) Soft skills such as creativity and communication (eg, public relations) Complex perception and refined manipulation tasks (eg, physicians) Contrast these professions with, for example, the taxi or lorry drivers whose jobs might eventually be replaced by driverless vehicles. While there is a wide range of estimates on how many jobs will be affected by the introduction of new technologies – from less than 10 per cent to almost 50 per cent – the majority of recent studies seem to agree that highly skilled, highly paid labour will be in rising demand, and low-skilled labour carrying out routine jobs will see a marked decline.
Recommended publications
  • Staff Working Paper No. 845 Eight Centuries of Global Real Interest Rates, R-G, and the ‘Suprasecular’ Decline, 1311–2018 Paul Schmelzing
    CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007 CODE OF PRACTICE 2007
    [Show full text]
  • How to Beat the Recession
    Taxcafe.co.uk Business Guides How to Beat the Recession Make Sure Your Business Prospers While Others Struggle By Alistair Gibb Important Legal Notices: Taxcafe® BUSINESS GUIDE – “How to Beat the Recession” Published by: Taxcafe UK Limited 67 Milton Road Kirkcaldy KY1 1TL United Kingdom Tel: (01592) 560081 First Edition, June 2009 ISBN 978-1-904608-96-7 Copyright Copyright © Alistair Gibb 2009. All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced or transmitted in any form or by any means (electronically or mechanically, including photocopying, recording or storing it in any medium by electronic means) without the prior permission in writing of the copyright owner except in accordance with the provisions of the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988 or under the terms of a licence issued by the Copyright Licensing Agency Ltd, 90 Tottenham Court Road, London, W1P 0LP. All applications for the written permission of the copyright owner to reproduce or transmit any part of the guide should be sent to the publisher. Warning: Any unauthorised reproduction or transmission of any part of this guide may result in criminal prosecution and a civil claim for damages. Trademarks Taxcafe® is a registered trademark of Taxcafe UK Limited. All other logos, trademarks, names and logos in this guide may be trademarks of their respective owners. Disclaimer Before reading or relying on the content of this guide, please read carefully the disclaimer on the last page which applies. If you have queries then please contact the publisher at [email protected]. About the Author Alistair Gibb studied economics and business at Durham University and the University of Strathclyde and then joined the 3i Group, where he held senior positions in both the investment and merchant banking sides of the business.
    [Show full text]
  • The Historic Failure of the Chicago School of Antitrust Mark Glick
    Antitrust and Economic History: The Historic Failure of the Chicago School of Antitrust Mark Glick1 Working Paper No. 95 May 2019 ABSTRACT This paper presents an historical analysis of the antitrust laws. Its central contention is that the history of antitrust can only be understood in light of U.S. economic history and the succession of dominant economic policy regimes that punctuated that history. The antitrust laws and a subset of other related policies have historically focused on the negative consequences resulting from the rise, expansion, and dominance of big business. Antitrust specifically uses competition as its tool to address these problems. The paper traces the evolution of the emergence, growth and expansion of big business over six economic eras: the Gilded Age, the Progressive Era, the New Deal, the post-World War II Era, the 1970s, and the era of neoliberalism. It considers three policy regimes: laissez-faire during the Gilded Age and the Progressive Era, the New Deal, policy regime from the Depression through the early 1970s, and the neoliberal policy regime that dominates today and includes the Chicago School of antitrust. The principal conclusion of the paper is that the activist antitrust policies associated with the New Deal that existed from the late 1 Professor, Department of Economics, University of Utah. Email: [email protected]. I would like to thank members of the University of Utah Competition Group, Catherine Ruetschlin, Marshall Steinbaum, and Ted Tatos for their help and input. I also benefited from suggestions and guidance from Gérard Duménil’s 2019 seminar on economic history at the University of Utah.
    [Show full text]
  • Imperialism in the 21St Century
    Imperialism in the 21st Century Doug Lorimer 2 Imperialism in the 21st Century Contents Imperialism in the 21st Century........................................................3 Rise of US imperialism.......................................................................................... 4 Decolonisation & US imperialism........................................................................ 7 Vietnam war........................................................................................................ 10 ‘Marshall Plan’ for Third World......................................................................... 11 Transnational corporations................................................................................ 13 Imperialism & state economic intervention....................................................... 15 The last empire.................................................................................................... 16 Growing social & political instability................................................................... 18 Imperialist Capitalism & Neo-Liberal Globalisation ...................21 Marx’s analysis of capitalism.............................................................................. 21 The imperialist epoch of capitalism.................................................................... 24 The global economy today................................................................................. 25 ‘Neo-liberalism’ & ‘globalisation’......................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • ECONOMIC GROWTH and STRUCTURAL CHANGE in the LONG NINETEENTH CENTURY Robert E
    1 ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STRUCTURAL CHANGE IN THE LONG NINETEENTH CENTURY robert e. gallman INTRODUCTION This chapter is concerned with quantitative features of the development of the American economy in the period between the late eighteenth century and World War I – the long nineteenth century. A reasonable place to begin is with measurements of the size of the economy. Since a central feature of any economy is production, size is appropriately measured by aggregate output. Other indicators, such as population and geographic extent, are considered below. The conventional measures of aggregate output are the national product – that is, output produced by factors of production owned by Americans – and the domestic product – output produced by factors of production domiciled in the United States. The proper index to select depends upon whether one thinks of the United States as the sum of all Americans or as a geographic entity. We are interested in the history of the people of the United States, and therefore the national product is the more appro- priate concept. It underlies most of the measurements treated in this chapter; in practice the choice matters little, however, since in the years under examination the national product and the domestic product were virtually identical. A more important question is the extent to which these conventional measures properly describe levels of output and changes in output over time, a question set aside for the moment but treated later in this essay. Cambridge Histories Online © Cambridge University Press, 2008 2 Robert E. Gallman SIZE AND GROWTH OF THE AMERICAN ECONOMY Size The American gross national product probably ran around $144 million just before the Revolution (Table 1.3).
    [Show full text]
  • Lowell National Historical Park Foundation Document (Overview Version
    NATIONAL PARK SERVICE • U.S. DEPARTMENT OF THE INTERIOR Foundation Document Overview Lowell National Historical Park Massachusetts © James Higgins Contact Information For more information about the Lowell National Historical Park Foundation Document, contact: [email protected] or (978) 970-5000 or write to: Superintendent, Lowell National Historical Park, 67 Kirk Street, Lowell, MA 01852 Description © James Higgins Growth and change have long dominated the American As crowded tenements took the place of Lowell’s well system of values. Industry flourished in 19th-century regulated system of boarding houses, Lowell became an America as major technological advancements in industrial city similar to others in New England. transportation, power production, and industrial manufacturing facilitated a fundamental shift from rural Competition within the textile industry increased continually farm-based communities to a modern urban-industrial throughout the 19th century. Eventually, the combination of society. Lowell, Massachusetts, 30 miles northwest a cheaper, less unionized workforce; newer, more efficient of Boston, was founded in 1822 as a seminal planned factories and machinery; cheaper real estate; and lower industrial city and became one of the most significant taxes persuaded the textile industry to move south. Eight of textile producing centers in the country. The city of Lowell Lowell’s original 10 textile firms closed their doors for good is not, as is sometimes claimed, the birthplace of the during the 1920s, and the remaining two closed in the 1950s. Industrial Revolution in America. Most of the developments The city fell into a long depression that lasted through the associated with this phenomenon in the nation’s history 1960s.
    [Show full text]
  • Financial Catastrophe Research & Stress Test Scenarios
    Cambridge Judge Business School Centre for Risk Studies 7th Risk Summit Research Showcase Financial Catastrophe Research & Stress Test Scenarios Dr Andy Skelton Research Associate, Cambridge Centre for Risk Studies 20 June 2016 Cambridge, UK Financial Catastrophe Research 1. Catalogue of historical financial events 2. Development of stress test scenarios 3. Understanding contagion processes in financial networks (eg, interbank loans) - Network models & visualisations - Role of central banks in financial crises - Practitioner model – scoping exercise 2 Learning from History Financial systems and transaction technologies have changed But principles of credit cycles, human trust and financial interrelationships that trigger crises remain relevant 12 Historical Financial Crisis Crises occur periodically – Different causes and severities – Every 8 years on average – $0.5 Tn of lost annual economic output – 1% of global economic output Without FinCat global growth could be 4% a year instead of 3% Financial catastrophes are the single greatest economic risk for society – We need to understand them better 3 Historical Severities of Crashes – Past 200 Years US Stock Market Crashes UK Stock Market Crashes 1845 Railway Mania… 1845 Railway Mania… 1997 Asian Crisis 1997 Asian Crisis 1866 Collapse of Overend… 1866 Collapse of Overend… 1825 Latin American Crisis 1825 Latin American Crisis 1983 Latin American Debt… 1983 Latin American Debt… 1837 Cotton Crisis 1837 Cotton Crisis 1857 Railroad Mania… 1857 Railroad Mania… 1907 Knickerbocker 1907 Knickerbocker
    [Show full text]
  • Parallel Journeys: Adam Smith and Milton Friedman on the Regulation of Banking
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Rockoff, Hugh Working Paper Parallel journeys: Adam Smith and Milton Friedman on the regulation of banking Working Paper, No. 2010-04 Provided in Cooperation with: Department of Economics, Rutgers University Suggested Citation: Rockoff, Hugh (2010) : Parallel journeys: Adam Smith and Milton Friedman on the regulation of banking, Working Paper, No. 2010-04, Rutgers University, Department of Economics, New Brunswick, NJ This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/59460 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu February, 2010 Parallel Journeys: Adam Smith and Milton Friedman on the Regulation of Banking Hugh Rockoff Rutgers University and NBER Department of Economics 75 Hamilton Street New Brunswick NJ 08901 [email protected] 1 Abstract Adam Smith and Milton Friedman are famous for championing Laissez Faire, yet both supported government regulation of the banking system.
    [Show full text]
  • Ohlin on the Great Depression
    Ohlin on the Great Depression BENNY CARLSON | LARS JONUNG KNUT WICKSELL WORKING PAPER 2013:9 Working papers Editor: F. Lundtofte The Knut Wicksell Centre for Financial Studies Lund University School of Economics and Management Ohlin on the Great Depression Ten newspaper articles 1929-1935 selected by Benny Carlson and Lars Jonung Abstract: Bertil Ohlin was a most active commentator on current economic events in the inter- war period, combining his academic work with a journalistic output of an impressive scale. He published more than a thousand newspaper articles in the 1920s and 1930s, more than any other professor in economics in Sweden. Here we have collected ten articles by Ohlin, translated from Swedish and originally published in Stockholms-Tidningen, to trace the evolution of his thinking during the Great Depression of the 1930s. These articles, spanning roughly half a decade, bring out his response to the stock market crisis in New York in 1929, his views on monetary policy in 1931, on fiscal policy and public works in 1932, his reaction to Keynes' ideas in 1932 and 1933 and to Roosevelt's New Deal in 1933, and, finally, his stand against state socialism in 1935. At the beginning of the depression, Ohlin was quite optimistic in his outlook. But as the downturn in the world economy deepened, his optimism waned. He dealt with proposals for bringing the Swedish economy out of the depression, and reported positively on the policy views of Keynes. At an early stage, he recommended expan- sionary fiscal and monetary policies including public works. This approach permeated the contributions of the young generation of Swedish economists arising in the 1930s, eventually forming the Stockholm School of Economics.
    [Show full text]
  • Depression, War, and Cold War This Page Intentionally Left Blank Depression, War, and Cold War
    Depression, War, and Cold War This page intentionally left blank Depression, War, and Cold War Studies in Political Economy Robert Higgs Senior Fellow in Political Economy The Independent Institute 1 2006 1 Oxford University Press, Inc., publishes works that further Oxford University’s objective of excellence in research, scholarship, and education. Oxford New York Auckland Cape Town Dar es Salaam Hong Kong Karachi Kuala Lumpur Madrid Melbourne Mexico City Nairobi New Delhi Shanghai Taipei Toronto With offices in Argentina Austria Brazil Chile Czech Republic France Greece Guatemala Hungary Italy Japan Poland Portugal Singapore South Korea Switzerland Thailand Turkey Ukraine Vietnam © Copyright 2006, The Independent Institute 100 Swan Way, Oakland, CA 94621–1428 510–632–1366 • 510–568–6040 fax • [email protected] • www.independent.org Published by Oxford University Press, Inc. 198 Madison Avenue, New York, New York 10016 www.oup.com Oxford is a registered trademark of Oxford University Press. All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording, or otherwise, without the prior permission of Oxford University Press. Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Higgs, Robert. Depression, war, and cold war : studies in political economy / by Robert Higgs. p. cm. Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN 13: 978-0-19-518292-7 ISBN 0-19-518292-8 1. United States—Economic conditions—20th century. 2. War—Economic aspects—United States. 3. Depressions—1929—United States. I. Title. HC106.H535 2006 330.973’091—dc22 2005022028 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 Printed in the United States of America on acid-free paper For Elizabeth who wouldn’t let me give up on it Love is patient, love is kind.
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Crashes, Mini-Case Studies
    April 28, 2020 Economic Crashes, Mini-Case Studies Background and Introduction Economic restructuring is a constant dynamic throughout the history of human history. This paper, developed for the Why Entrepreneurship? – Making the Case for Entrepreneurship! and Community- Centered Economic Development papers, provides a summary of regionally based economic crashes created by structural changes in our economy. Questions and Additional Information Don Macke – e2 Entrepreneurial Ecosystems A Hosted Initiative of NetWork Kansas 402.323.7336 – [email protected] The Great Reset In 2010 Richard Florida (author of the Creative Class writings) released The Great Reset – How New Ways of Living and Working Drive the Post-Crash Economy. While this book is probably not the most read of the many Florida works, we found it very insightful and helpful as we grasped to understand the implications of the Great Recession (2007- 2010). In this book Florida documents transformative change that occurred following the Long Depression of the late 1800s and the Great Depression of the 1930s. Bottom line, with traumatic events like depressions and global wars, the “status quo” is up- ended enabling and driving transformative change in economies, societies and governance. We used The Great Reset to help us anticipate potential profound change coming out of the Great Recession. Mega Trends in Global Economic Restructuring Local Economic Restructuring Events. Higher-impact economic crashes are often driven by global or national forces impacting entire industries and regions. But economic crashes can impact individual communities like the Watts Neighborhood in Los Angeles or what is happening right now in Sidney, Nebraska where the acquisition of Cabela’s Outdoor Outfitters by Bass Pro Shop is creating an economic crash in the small, rural areas of Western Nebraska and Northeastern Colorado.
    [Show full text]
  • The Quarterly Review Is Published by the Research Department of The
    Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis i; Winter 1999 The Great Depression in the United States From a Neoclassical Perspective (p. 2) Harold L. Cole Lee E. Ohanian Some Observations on the Great Depression (p. 25) Edward C. Prescott 1998 Contents (p. 32) 1998 Staff Reports (p. 33) Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review Vol. 23, No. 1 ISSN 0271-5287 This publication primarily presents economic research aimed at improving policymaking by the Federal Reserve System and other governmental authorities. Any views expressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis or the Federal Reserve System. Editor: Arthur J. Rolnick Associate Editors: Edward J. Green, Preston J. Miller, Warren E. Weber Economic Advisory Board: Harold L. Cole, Edward J. Green, Lee E. Ohanian, James A. Schmitz, Jr. Managing Editor: Kathleen S. Rolfe Article Editor: Jenni C. Schoppers Designer: Phil Swenson Typesetter: Mary E. Anomalay Circulation Assistant: Elaine R. Reed The Quarterly Review is published by the Research Department Comments and questions about the Quarterly Review may be of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. Subscriptions are sent to available free of charge. Quarterly Review Quarterly Review articles that are reprints or revisions of papers Research Department published elsewhere may not be reprinted without the written Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis permission of the original publisher. All other Quarterly Review P.O. Box 291 articles may be reprinted without charge. If you reprint an article, Minneapolis, Minnesota 55480-0291 please fully credit the source—the Minneapolis Federal Reserve (Phone 612-204-6455 / Fax 612-204-5515).
    [Show full text]