Zdroje Antika Scholastici

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Zdroje Antika Scholastici i Zdroje Fuchs, Lisy. Dějiny ekonomických teorií pro právníky Hol ma n a kol. Dějiny ekonomickěho myšlení Lisy. Dejiny ekonomických teorií Schumpeter. History of Economic Analysis Sojka a kol. Dějiny ekonomických teorií Gide a Rist. Dějiny nauk národohospodářských http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/ Antika XENOFÓN (430-355 př. n. I.) Oikonomikos PLATÓN (427-347 př. n. I.) ARISTOTELES (384-322 př. n. I.) CATO starší (234-179 př. n. I.) VARRO (116-27 př. n. I.) COLUMELLA (4 př. n. I.-65) Scholastici TOMÁŠ AKVINSKÝ (1225-1274) JOHN DUNS SCOTUS (1265-1308) JOHANNES BURIDANUS (1295-1358) NICOLE DE ORESME (1320-1382) NAVARRUS (1493-1586) LUIS MOLINA (1535-1600) 2 Merkantilisté GASPARO SCARUFFI (1519-1606) BERNARDO DAVANZATI (1529-1606) ANTONIO SERRA (1580-1614) JEAN BODIN (1530-1596) ANTOINE DE MONTCHRÉTIEN (1575-1622) JEAN BAPTISTÉ COLBERT (1619-1683) THOMAS MUN (1571-1641) JOSIAH CHILD (1630-1699) JAMES STEUART (1712-1780) Kameralisté JOHAN HEINDRICH VON JUSTI (1705-1771) JOSEPH VON SONNENFELS (1732-1817) P re-klasici WILLIAM PETTY (1623-1687) JOHN LOCKE (1632-1704) DUDLEY NORTH (1641-1691) NICHOLAS BARBON (1637-1698) DAVID HUME (1711-1776) PIERRE DE BOISGUILLEBERT (1646-1714) RICHARD CANTILLON (1680-1734) JOHN LAW (1671-1729) 3 Fyziokraté FRANCOIS QUESNAY (1694-1774) VICTOR MIRABEAU (1715-1789) ANNE ROBERT TURGOT (1727-1781) Klasická škola ADAM SMITH (1723-1790) DAVID RICARDO (1772-1823) THOMAS ROBERT MALTHUS (1766-1834) JEAN BAPTISTÉ SAY (1767-1832) JAMES MILL (1773-1836) NASSAU WILLIAM SENIOR (1790-1864) JOHN STUART MILL (1806-1873) JOHN ELLIOT CAIRNES (1823-1875) FREDERIC BASTIAT (1801-1850) HENRY CHARLES CAREY (1793-1879) KARL MARX (1818-1883) Německá historická škola FRIEDRICH LIST (1789-1846) WILHELM RÖSCHER (1817-1894) BRUNO HILDEBRAND (1812-1878) 4 KARL KNIES (1821-1898) GUSTAV VON SCHMOLLER (1838-1917) GEORG FRIEDRICH KNAPP (1842-1926) WERNER SOMBART (1863-1941) MAX WEBER (1864-1920) Pre-marginalisté ETIENNE DE CONDILLAC (1714-1780) FERDINANDU GALIANI (1728-1787) DANIEL BERNOULLI (1700-1782) JOHANN HENRICH VON THÜNEN (1780-1850) ANTOINE AUGUSTIN COURNOT (1801-1877) HERMANN HEINRICH GOSSEN (1810-1858) Angloameričtí marginalisté WILLIAM STANLEY JEVONS (1835-1882) JOHN BATES CLARK (1847-1938) IRVING FISHER (1867-1947) FRANK FETTER (1863-1949) Lausanská škola LEON WALRAS (1834-1910) VILFREDO PARETO (1848-1923) 5 Rakouská škola CARL MENGER (1840-1921) EUGEN VON BÖHM-BAWERK (1851-1914) FRIEDRICH VON WIESER (1851-1926) LUDWIG VON MISES (1881-1973) JOSEPH SCHUMPETER (1883-1950) RICHARD VON STRIGL (1891-1942) FRIEDRICH AUGUST VON HAYEK (1889-1992) ISRAEL KIRTZNER (1930-) MURRAY ROTHBARD (1926-1995) Švédská škola KNUT WICKSELL (1851-1926) GUSTAV CASSEL (1866-1945) GUNNAR MYRDAL (1898-1987) Cambridgeská škola ALFRED MARSHALL (1842-1924) FRANCIS YSIDRO EDGEWORTH (1845-1926) ARTHUR CECIL PIGOU (1877-1959) DENNIS H. ROBERTSON (1890-1963) 6 Institucionalisté THORSTEIN VEBLEN (1857-1929) WESLEY CLAIR MITCHELL (1874-1948) JOHN KENNETH GALBRAITH (1908-) RONALD COASE (1910-) ARMEN ALCHIAN (1914-) DOUGLASS NORTH (1920-) Keynesiáni JOHN MAYNARD KEYNES (1883-1946) JOHN HICKS (1904-1989) PAUL SAMUELSON (1915-) ROY HARROD (1900-1978) PIERO SRAFFA (1898-1983) JOAN ROBINSON (1903-1983) GEORGE L. S. SHACKLE (1903-1992) Ordoliberálové WALTER EUKEN (1891-1950) WILHELM RÖPKE (1899-1966) 7 Chicagská škola FRANK KNIGHT (1885-1972) GEORGE STIGLER (1911-1991) GARY BECKER (1930-) MILTON FRIEDMAN (1912-) Nová klasická makroekonomie ROBERT LUCAS (1937-) ROBERT BARRO (1944-) Škola veřejné volby JAMES BUCHANAN (1919-) .
Recommended publications
  • Werner Sombart's ʻovercomingʼ of Marxism
    CHAPTER 27 Werner Sombart’s ʻOvercomingʼ of Marxism 27.1 The Historical School as ʻDigestive Scienceʼ (Rosa Luxemburg) The ʻolder historical schoolʼ of political economy, whose members included Wilhelm Roscher (1817–94), Bruno Hildebrandt (1812–78) and Karl Knies (1821– 98), emerged in the 1840s. It was a specifically ʻGermanʼ reaction both to the French Revolution and to the ʻWesternʼ cosmopolitanism of classical political economy from Smith to Ricardo.1 It was ostensibly concerned with opposing the ʻsurgical extractionʼ of the economy from the ʻliving bodyʼ of popular life and the life of the state, and in particular the ʻnarrow egotistic psychologyʼ according to which social actors are guided, in their economic behaviour, only by economic considerations, as opposed to ethical motives.2 If Machiavelli banished ethics from politics, Adam Smith performed the same operation for political economy, criticises Knies, who emphasises the significance of the ʻethico-political momentʼ for political economy and speaks of the discipline being ʻelevatedʼ to the status of a ʻmoral and political science’.3 At first glance, this seems to represent an integral approach to studying social practices. But behind this pathos of wholeness, there lies the definition of political economy as a ʻstate economyʼ concerned with ʻjudging men and ruling them’.4 The historical school developed from cameralism, which became the discipline of state science due to the Prussian path of capitalist develop- ment.5 Marx describes cameralism as ʻa medley of smatterings, through
    [Show full text]
  • Modern Monetary Theory: a Marxist Critique
    Class, Race and Corporate Power Volume 7 Issue 1 Article 1 2019 Modern Monetary Theory: A Marxist Critique Michael Roberts [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.fiu.edu/classracecorporatepower Part of the Economics Commons Recommended Citation Roberts, Michael (2019) "Modern Monetary Theory: A Marxist Critique," Class, Race and Corporate Power: Vol. 7 : Iss. 1 , Article 1. DOI: 10.25148/CRCP.7.1.008316 Available at: https://digitalcommons.fiu.edu/classracecorporatepower/vol7/iss1/1 This work is brought to you for free and open access by the College of Arts, Sciences & Education at FIU Digital Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Class, Race and Corporate Power by an authorized administrator of FIU Digital Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Modern Monetary Theory: A Marxist Critique Abstract Compiled from a series of blog posts which can be found at "The Next Recession." Modern monetary theory (MMT) has become flavor of the time among many leftist economic views in recent years. MMT has some traction in the left as it appears to offer theoretical support for policies of fiscal spending funded yb central bank money and running up budget deficits and public debt without earf of crises – and thus backing policies of government spending on infrastructure projects, job creation and industry in direct contrast to neoliberal mainstream policies of austerity and minimal government intervention. Here I will offer my view on the worth of MMT and its policy implications for the labor movement. First, I’ll try and give broad outline to bring out the similarities and difference with Marx’s monetary theory.
    [Show full text]
  • Karl Helfferich and Rudolf Hilferding on Georg Friedrich Knapp's State
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Greitens, Jan Conference Paper — Manuscript Version (Preprint) Karl Helfferich and Rudolf Hilferding on Georg Friedrich Knapp’s State Theory of Money: Monetary Theories during the Hyperinflation of 1923 Suggested Citation: Greitens, Jan (2020) : Karl Helfferich and Rudolf Hilferding on Georg Friedrich Knapp’s State Theory of Money: Monetary Theories during the Hyperinflation of 1923, Annual Conference of the European Society for the History of Economic Thought (ESHET) 2020, Sofia., ZBW - Leibniz Information Centre for Economics, Kiel, Hamburg This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/216102 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available
    [Show full text]
  • Weimar Republic Hyperinflation Through a Modern Monetary Theory Lens Phil Armstrong and Warren Mosler 2020 Abstract
    Weimar Republic Hyperinflation through a Modern Monetary Theory Lens Phil Armstrong and Warren Mosler 2020 Abstract The hyperinflation in Weimar Germany in 1922-23 has become the poster child of mainstream economists - and especially the monetarists- when presenting the benefits of constraining governments by the rules of ‘sound finance’. Their narrative presumes that governments are naturally inclined to spend beyond their means and that, if left to their profligate ways, inflation ‘gets out of hand’ and leads to hyperinflation in a continuous, accelerating, unstoppable catastrophic collapse of the value of the money. In contrast to this ubiquitous mainstream analysis, we recognize a fundamentally different origin of inflation, and argue that inflation requires sustained, proactive policy support. And, in the absence of such policies, inflation will rapidly subside. We replace the erroneous mainstream theory with the knowledge of Modern Monetary Theory (MMT) identifying both the source of the price level and what makes it change. We are not Weimar scholars, and our aim is not to present a comprehensive historical analysis. We examine the traditionally reported causal forces behind the Weimar hyperinflation, along with the factors that contributed to the hyperinflation and to its abrupt end. The purpose of this paper is to present our view of the reported information from an MMT perspective. In that regard, we identify the cause of the inflation as the German government paying continuously higher prices for its purchases, particularly those of the foreign currencies the Allies demanded for the payment of reparations, and we identify the rise in the quantity of money and the printing of increasing quantities of banknotes as a consequence of the hyperinflation, rather than its cause.
    [Show full text]
  • Ladislaus Von Bortkiewicz Statistician, Economist, and a European Intellectual
    statistician, economist, economist, statistician, Forschungsgemei SFB * * Max Planck Institut and a European a European and Wolfgang Karl Hä Karl Wolfgang 649 This wasresearch supported the by Deutsche Ladislaus von Ladislaus * Bortkiewicz SFB 649, Humboldt Annette B. Vogt B. Annette Humboldt Spandauer Straße 1, D intellectual Discussion Paper 20 http://sfb649.wiwi.hu nschaft through theSFB 649 "EconomicRisk". - ISSN 1860 Universitä for t he - Universität zu Berlin History of Sciences, Germany t zu Berlin,Germany - 5664 - 10178 Berlin - berlin.de rdle * * - 14 * - 015 SFB 6 4 9 E C O N O M I C R I S K B E R L I N S F B XXX E C O N O M I C R I S K B E R L I N Ladislaus von Bortkiewicz statistician, economist, and a European intellectual Wolfgang Karl H¨ardle Ladislaus von Bortkiewicz Chair of Statistics, C.A.S.E. - Center for Applied Statistics and Economics, Humboldt-Universit¨atzu Berlin, Unter den Linden 6, 10099 Berlin, Germany Lee Kong Chian School of Business, Singapore Management University Annette B. Vogt Max Planck Institute for the History of Science, Boltzmannstraße 22, 14195 Berlin, Germany Abstract Ladislaus von Bortkiewicz (1868 - 1931) was a European statistician. His scientific work covered theoretical economics, stochastics, mathematical statistics and radiology, today we would call him a cross disciplinary scientist. With his clear views on mathema- tical principles with their applications in these fields he stood in conflict with the mainstream economic schools in Germany at the dawn of the 20th century. He had many prominent students (Gumbel, Leontief, Freudenberg among them) and he carved out the path of modern statistical thinking.
    [Show full text]
  • The Monetary and Fiscal Nexus of Neo-Chartalism: a Friendly Critique
    JOURNAL OF ECONOMIC ISSUES Vol. XLVII No. 1 March 2013 DOI 10.2753/JEI0021-3624470101 The Monetary and Fiscal Nexus of Neo-Chartalism: A Friendly Critique Marc Lavoie Abstract: A number of post-Keynesian authors, called the neo-chartalists, have argued that the government does not face a budget constraint similar to that of households and that government with sovereign currencies run no risk of default, even with high debt-to-GDP ratio. This stands in contrast to countries in the eurozone, where the central bank does not normally purchase sovereign debt. While these claims now seem to be accepted by some economists, neo-chartalists have also made a number of controversial claims, including that the government spends simply by crediting a private-sector-bank account at the central bank; that the government does need to borrow to deficit-spend; and that taxes do not finance government expenditures. This paper shows that these surprising statements do have some logic, once one assumes the consolidation of the government sector and the central bank into a unique entity, the state. The paper further argues, however, that these paradoxical claims end up being counter-productive since consolidation is counter-factual. Keywords: central bank, clearing and settlement system, eurozone, neo-chartalism JEL Classification Codes: B5, E5, E63 The global financial crisis has exposed the weaknesses of mainstream economics and it has given a boost to heterodox theories, in particular, Keynesian theories. The mainstream view about the irrelevance of fiscal activism has been strongly criticized by the active use of fiscal policy in the midst of the global financial crisis.
    [Show full text]
  • Spring 2016 Syllabus
    Anwar Shaikh Spring 2016 Advanced Political Economy I: Classical Macrodynamics Primary Text: Shaikh, Anwar. 2016. Capitalism: Competition, Conflict, Crises. New York: Oxford University Press. I. Rise and Fall of Modern Macroeconomics A. Micro Foundations and Macro Properties Shaikh, Anwar. 2016. Capitalism: Competition, Conflict, Crises. New York: Oxford University Press: Ch 12 Section I. Ariely, Dan. 2008. Predictably Irrational: The Hidden Forces That Shape Our Decisions. HarperCollins: Ch 4-5, 9. Conlisk, John. 1996. "Why bounded rationality?" Journal of Economic Literature, 34(2), pp. 669–700. Dosi, Giovanni; Giorgio Fagiolo; Roberta Aversi; Mara Meacci and ClaUdia Olivetti. 1999. "Cognitive Processes, Social Adaptation and Innovation in Consumption Patterns: From Stylized Facts to Demand Theory," In Economic Organization and Economic Knowledge: Essays in Honour of Brian J. Loasby, ed. S. C. Dow and P. E. Earl. Cheltenham, U.K: Edward Elgar. Felipe, JesUs and Franklin M. Fisher. 2003. "Aggregation in ProdUction FUnctions: What Applied Economists ShoUld Know." Metroeconomica, 54 (May), pp. 208-262. Kirman, Alan. 1992. "Whom or What Does the Representative IndividUal Represent?" The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 6(2), pp. 117-136. Sen, A.K. 1977. "Rational fools: a critiqUe of the behavioral foUndations of economic theory." Philosophy and Public Affairs, 6(4), pp. 317-344. Shaikh, Anwar, 2010. "Reflexivity, Path-Dependence and DiseqUilibriUm Dynamics." JoUrnal of Post Keynesian Economics, 33(1 ), 3-16. B. Pre-Keynesian macroeconomics Shaikh, Anwar. 2016. op. cit.: Ch 12 Section II Snowdon, Brian and Howard R. Vane. 2005. Modern Macroeconomics: Its Origins, Development and Current State. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar: Ch 1, Ch 2 Sections 2.1-2.5 C.
    [Show full text]
  • Leontief and His German Period✩ Harald Hagemann*
    Russian Journal of Economics 7 (2021) 67–90 DOI 10.32609/j.ruje.7.58034 Publication date: 31 March 2021 www.rujec.org Leontief and his German period✩ Harald Hagemann* University of Hohenheim, Stuttgart, Germany Abstract Wassily Leontief jun. (1905–1999) moved to Berlin in April 1925 after getting his first academic degree from the University of Leningrad. In Berlin he mainly studied with Werner Sombart and Ladislaus von Bortkiewicz who were the referees of his Ph.D. thesis “The economy as a circular flow” (1928). From spring 1927 until April 1931 Leontief was a member of the research staff at the Kiel Institute of World Economics, interrupted by the period from April 1929 to March 1930 when he was an advisor to the Chinese Ministry of Railroads. In the journal of the Kiel Institute, Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, Leontief had already published his first article “Die Bilanz der russischen Volkswirtschaft. Eine methodologische Untersuchung” [The balance of the Russian economy. A methodo­ logical investigation] in 1925. In Kiel Leontief primarily worked on the statistical analysis of supply and demand curves. Leontief’s method triggered a fierce critique by Ragnar Frisch, which launched a heavy debate on “pitfalls” in the construction of supply and demand curves. The debate started in Germany but was continued in the USA where Leontief became a researcher at the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) in summer 1931. The Leontief–Frisch controversy culminated in the Quarterly Journal of Economics (1934), published by Harvard University, where Leontief made his sub­ sequent career from 1932–1975. His later analysis of the employment consequences of technological change in the 1980s had some roots in his Kiel period.
    [Show full text]
  • The “Kansas City” Approach to Modern Money Theory
    Working Paper No. 961 The “Kansas City” Approach to Modern Money Theory by L. Randall Wray Levy Economics Institute of Bard College July 2020 The Levy Economics Institute Working Paper Collection presents research in progress by Levy Institute scholars and conference participants. The purpose of the series is to disseminate ideas to and elicit comments from academics and professionals. Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, founded in 1986, is a nonprofit, nonpartisan, independently funded research organization devoted to public service. Through scholarship and economic research it generates viable, effective public policy responses to important economic problems that profoundly affect the quality of life in the United States and abroad. Levy Economics Institute P.O. Box 5000 Annandale-on-Hudson, NY 12504-5000 http://www.levyinstitute.org Copyright © Levy Economics Institute 2020 All rights reserved ISSN 1547-366X ABSTRACT Modern money theory (MMT) synthesizes several traditions from heterodox economics. Its focus is on describing monetary and fiscal operations in nations that issue a sovereign currency. As such, it applies Georg Friedrich Knapp’s state money approach (chartalism), also adopted by John Maynard Keynes in his Treatise on Money. MMT emphasizes the difference between a sovereign currency issuer and a sovereign currency user with respect to issues such as fiscal and monetary policy space, ability to make all payments as they come due, credit worthiness, and insolvency. Following A. Mitchell Innes, however, MMT acknowledges some similarities between sovereign and nonsovereign issues of liabilities, and hence integrates a credit theory of money (or, “endogenous money theory,” as it is usually termed by post-Keynesians) with state money theory.
    [Show full text]
  • Ludwig Von Mises: Scholar, Creator, Hero
    Murray N. Rothbard Ludwig von Mises: Scholar, Creator, Hero Introduction The purpose of this essay is to discuss and celebrate the life and work of one of the great creative minds of our century. Ludwig von Mises was born on September 29, 1881, in the city of Lemberg (now Lvov), in Galicia, in the Austro-Hungarian Empire. His father, Arthur Edler von Mises, a Viennese construction engineer working for the Austrian railroads, was stationed in Lemberg at the time. Ludwig’s mother, Adele Landau, also came from a prominent family in Vienna: her uncle, Dr. Joachim Landau, was a deputy from the Liberal Party in the Austrian Parliament. The Young Scholar Though the pre-eminent theorist of our time, Mises’s interest, as a teenager, centered in history, particularly economic and administrative history. But even while still in high school, he reacted against the relativism and historicism rampant in the German-speaking countries, dominated by the Historical School. In his early historical work, he was frustrated to find historical studies virtually consisting of paraphrases from official government reports. Instead, he yearned to write genuine economic history. He early disliked the State orientation of historical studies. Thus, in his memoirs, Mises writes: “It was my intense interest in historical knowledge that enabled me to perceive readily the inadequacy of German historicism. It did not deal with scientific problems, but with the glorification and justification of Prussian policies and Prussian authoritarian government. The German universities were state institutions and the instructors were civil servants. The professors were aware of this civil-service status, that is, they saw themselves as servants of the Prussian king”.[1] Ludwig von Mises entered the University of Vienna at the turn of the twentieth century and his major professor was the economic historian Karl Grünberg, a member of the German Historical School and a statist who was interested in labor history, agricultural history, and Marxism.
    [Show full text]
  • Economía MMT: MODERN MONETARY THEORY OR MAGICAL
    UNIVERSIDAD DEL CEMA Buenos Aires Argentina Serie DOCUMENTOS DE TRABAJO Área: Economía MMT: MODERN MONETARY THEORY OR MAGICAL MONETARY THINKING? THE EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE Emilio Ocampo Noviembre 2020 Nro. 762 www.cema.edu.ar/publicaciones/doc_trabajo.html UCEMA: Av. Córdoba 374, C1054AAP Buenos Aires, Argentina ISSN 1668-4575 (impreso), ISSN 1668-4583 (en línea) Editor: Jorge M. Streb; asistente editorial: Valeria Dowding <[email protected]> MMT: Modern Monetary Theory or Magical Monetary Thinking?* The Empirical Evidence Emilio Ocampo** Abstract This article presents a summary of the main theoretical arguments and policy recommendations of Modern Monetary Theory (MMT) and traces back its intellectual origins to the writings on money of Georg F. Knapp and on fiscal policy of Abba P. Lerner. It also presents evidence on two countries that followed MMT like policies: Germany between 1939 and 1945 and Argentina with brief interruptions since 1946. The main conclusion of the article is that any country that consistently follows the policy prescriptions of MMT will inevitably experience high inflation and lower (and even negative) economic growth. Keywords: Monetary Theory, MMT, Argentina. JEL Codes: B00, N14, N16, P40, P47. * Version updated on March 1, 2021. ** Professor of Economic History at Universidad del CEMA (UCEMA). I received valuable comments from Jorge Ávila, Nicolás Cachanosky and José Carlos Jaime. Any mistakes are my sole responsibility. The viewpoints expressed herein do not necessarily represent those of UCEMA. 1 MMT: Modern Monetary Theory of Magical Monetary Thinking? The Empirical Evidence Emilio Ocampo The money of a State is not what is of compulsory general acceptance, but what is accepted at the public pay offices.
    [Show full text]
  • Working Paper No. 252
    Working Paper No. 252 Modern Money by L. Randall Wray The Jerome Levy Economics Institute What is money and where did it come from? We all know the traditional answers to these questions. Our homogenous-globule-of-desire forefathers1 were inconvenienced by barter until they spontaneously hit upon the idea of using tobacco, furs, huge rocks, landmarks, and wives as media of exchange.2 Over time, greater efficiency was obtained as homo economicus coined precious metals, and market efficiency was enhanced by free banks, which substituted paper money backed by precious metal reserves.3 All would have been fine and dandy except that evil governments came along, monopolizing the mints, creating central banks that debased the currency, and interfering with the invisible hand of the market. This finally resulted in abandonment of commodity money, substitution of a fiat money, and central bank-induced inflation. If only we could return to that Peter Pan and the Lost Boys, Never-Never (Laissez-Faire) Land, free of Captain Hook and the Crocodile (Central Bank and Government), with privately supplied free bank money greasing the mighty wheels of entrepreneurial commerce! The problem is that the Never-Never land imagined by the Paul Samuelsons and George Selgins simply never, ever, existed. There is no evidence of barter-based markets (outside trivial prisoner-of-war cases), and all the evidence about the origins of money points to state involvement. This is not to say that there have never been private monies, nor is it my intention to claim too much of a role for government in the evolution of the financial system.
    [Show full text]