Multinomial Probit and Multinomial Logit: a Comparison of Choice Models for Voting Research Jay K

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Multinomial Probit and Multinomial Logit: a Comparison of Choice Models for Voting Research Jay K Electoral Studies 23 (2004) 107–122 www.elsevier.com/locate/electstud Multinomial probit and multinomial logit: a comparison of choice models for voting research Jay K. Dow ∗, James W. Endersby Department of Political Science, University of Missouri, Columbia, MO 65201-0630, USA Abstract Several recent studies of voter choice in multiparty elections point to the advantages of multinomial probit (MNP) relative to multinomial/conditional logit (MNL). We compare the MNP and MNL models and argue that the simpler logit is often preferable to the more complex probit for the study of voter choice in multi-party elections. Our argument rests on three areas of comparison between MNP and MNL. First, within the limits of typical data—a small sample of revealed voter choices among a few candidates or parties—neither model will clearly appear to have generated the observed data. Second, MNP is susceptible to a number of estimation problems, the most serious of which is that the MNP is often weakly identified in application. Weak identification is difficult to diagnose and may lead to plausible, yet arbitrary or mislead- ing inferences. Finally, the logit model is criticized because it imposes the independence of irrelevant alternatives (IIA) property on voter choice. For most applications the IIA property is neither relevant nor particularly restrictive. We illustrate our arguments using data from recent US and French presidential elections. 2003 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved. 1. Introduction Models of voter choice among more than two parties or candidates rest on underly- ing assumptions about the nature of individual decision-making. Statistical methods commonly used to estimate models of multiparty vote choice often impose restrictive assumptions about these choices that render inferences suspect. For example, binary logit or probit analyses are sometimes used to represent voter choice as a decision ∗ Corresponding author. Tel.: +1-573-882-0047; fax: +1-573-884-5131. E-mail addresses: [email protected] (J.K. Dow); [email protected] (J.W. Endersby). 0261-3794/$ - see front matter 2003 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved. doi:10.1016/S0261-3794(03)00040-4 108 J.K. Dow, J.W. Endersby / Electoral Studies 23 (2004) 107–122 between government and opposition. This ignores potentially important differences within the opposition. Less restrictive are ordered models including ordered logit, ordered probit and least squares. These represent voter choice among multiple candi- dates or parties, but impose the assumption that political competition takes place along a single, ordered axis. The unidimensionality assumption is typically invalid for multiparty systems (Lijphart, 1984; Taagepera and Shugart, 1989: pp. 92–98). Stokes (1963) provided an early criticism of the ordered axis assumption. Alvarez and Nagler (1995, 1998, 2001), Alvarez et al. (2000), Schofield et al. (1998), Lacey and Burden (1999) and Quinn et al. (1999) identify advantages of multinomial probit (MNP) analysis in these applications. MNP fits within a class of multinomial choice models that includes the multinomial/conditional logit (MNL), and more flexible logit-type specifications including the generalized extreme value (GEV) and mixed logit (MXL) models. These represent voter choice as a decision among unordered alternatives (parties, candidates) as a function of chooser (voter) and choice (party/candidate) attributes. Since the MNL specification is tractable and simple to estimate, it is included in many commercial software packages and is used regularly in electoral research.1 MNL, however, imposes the restrictive assumption that choices are independent across alternatives. MNP does not impose the indepen- dence assumption and advances in computer technology make its estimation increas- ingly practical. Thus, one might reasonably argue that MNP should be the benchmark methodology in the study of voter choice in multiparty elections. Although political methodologists understand the relative merits of MNP and MNL in application, our experience suggests that many scholars investigating voter choice in multiparty elections are not fully aware of the assumptions and implications of the two models. We seek to inform applied researchers about the benefits and liabilities of MNP and MNL and to compare the two models in typical application. We assess MNP and MNL in the study of voter choice in multicandidate/multiparty elections and argue that for most purposes the simpler logit is preferable to probit. This is particularly true for applications estimating the probability that a voter casts a ballot for a candidate or a party selected from a fixed, stable pool of alternatives and the marginal changes in the probability associated with changes in the values of explanatory variables. We are motivated by our perception that electoral scholars are sometimes uncertain about MNP and associated issues such as the independence of irrelevant alternatives property (IIA). In particular, researchers are unsure as to whether their statistical analyses provide useful insights or are subject to challenge if based on MNL. We demonstrate that for the most common application in which these concerns arise—the study of voter choice in multiparty/candidate elections— these concerns are exaggerated and, under most circumstances, logit estimation per- forms as well or better than MNP. Our argument rests on three areas of comparison between the MNP and MNL models. First, since the statistical properties motivating MNP and MNL are asymp- 1 We do not distinguish between strictly multinomial (MNL) and conditional (CL) logit models as most electoral applications use a logit specification that combines the two. J.K. Dow, J.W. Endersby / Electoral Studies 23 (2004) 107–122 109 totic, there are few a priori reasons to believe that one method or the other is superior in typical application. The relative merits of any statistical model primarily depend on the method that best represents the underlying choice process that generates the observed data. Within the limits of typical data—a relatively small sample vector of observed choices among a few candidates or parties—neither model will clearly appear to have produced the sample of observed data. The estimated MNP and MNL coefficients and standard errors (adjusted for scale), probabilities and marginal effects will be indistinguishable. Second, MNP imparts a number of potentially serious problems. These are suf- ficiently difficult to detect that, in the absence of investing exceptional effort in model diagnostics, researchers are justified in using the MNL specification. The most important problem is that even formally identified MNP specifications are often weakly identified in application. This is serious because weak identification is diffi- cult to diagnose and may lead to plausible, yet arbitrary or misleading inferences. The MNP presents a difficult maximum likelihood optimization problem that some- times fails to converge at a global optimum or produces parameter estimates that are sufficiently imprecise as to make statistical inferences suspect. Except for cases of profound mis-specification, the logit likelihood will optimize at its global maximum and is not prone to optimization errors. Finally, the logit model is criticized because it imposes the IIA property on voter choice. The IIA property imposes the restriction that the relative odds of selecting between any two candidates or parties is independent of the number of alternatives. Behavioral theories of voter choice sometimes assume IIA is violated, so logit esti- mation is suspect. For much of empirical voting research, the IIA property is not particularly restrictive. We illustrate our arguments using data from recent US and French presidential elections. 2. The multinomial logit and multinomial probit models 2.1. Overview Scholars of voting behavior must adopt theoretically appropriate models of voter choice among multiple alternatives (Whitten and Palmer, 1996; Alvarez and Nagler, 1998; Adams and Merrill, 2000). The MNL and MNP models fit this requirement as each may be derived from economic theories of utility maximization. In multican- = = didate elections, assume voter i’s utility for candidate j, Uij,(i 1,…,n; j 1,…,p) is a function of both voter and candidate attributes and a stochastic error. A typical representation (Maddala, 1983: p. 61; Alvarez and Nagler, 1998; Powers and Xie, 2000: p. 248) is: ϭ Ј ϩ Ј ϩ Uij b Xij a jZi eij where Xij is a vector of candidate attributes as perceived by voter i, and Zi is a vector of voter characteristics. We seek to estimate the coefficients b and aj and their standard errors. 110 J.K. Dow, J.W. Endersby / Electoral Studies 23 (2004) 107–122 If each voter is a utility maximizer, the probability that voter i casts a ballot for candidate 1 is: Pi1 ϭ P[Ui1 Ͼ Ui2,Ui1 Ͼ Ui3,…,Ui1 Ͼ Uip] For any “m” in the set of 1,...,p candidates: ϭ Ϫ Ͻ Ј ϩ Ј Ϫ Ј ϩ Ј P(m) P[eim eij (b Xij a jZi) (b Xim a mZi), j m] MNL and MNP differ according to the assumed error structure for the eij. The logit assumes the errors are independent, identically distributed (iid) with type I extreme value distribution (log Weibull). The probability that a voter i votes for candidate j is given by: exp(bЈX ϩ aЈ Z ) P(vote ϭ j͉ , ,X ,Z ) ϭ ij j i b aj ij i p ͸ Ј ϩ Ј exp(b Xik a kZi) k ϭ 1 The MNP assumes the errors are distributed multivariate normal, with mean 0 and 2 s1 s12 . s1n s s2 .. covariance matrix Σ= 12 2 . The probabilities are written: ΄....΅ 2 s1n ..sn ϭ ͉ ⌺∗ P(vote j b,aj,Xij,Zi, ) ∗ ∗ ϩ ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ ϩ ∗ b X1 a1 Z b XjϪ1 ajϪ1Z ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ ϭ ͵ ͵ Ϫ ∂ ∂ Ϫ … f(ei1,…,eij 1) ei1,…, eij 1 Ϫϱ Ϫϱ where f(.) is the probability density function of the multivariate normal distribution.2 2.2. General comparisons Given the effort invested to argue the merits of one method over the other, the MNP and MNL are remarkably similar in important respects.
Recommended publications
  • MNP: R Package for Fitting the Multinomial Probit Model
    JSS Journal of Statistical Software May 2005, Volume 14, Issue 3. http://www.jstatsoft.org/ MNP: R Package for Fitting the Multinomial Probit Model Kosuke Imai David A. van Dyk Princeton University University of California, Irvine Abstract MNP is a publicly available R package that fits the Bayesian multinomial probit model via Markov chain Monte Carlo. The multinomial probit model is often used to analyze the discrete choices made by individuals recorded in survey data. Examples where the multi- nomial probit model may be useful include the analysis of product choice by consumers in market research and the analysis of candidate or party choice by voters in electoral studies. The MNP software can also fit the model with different choice sets for each in- dividual, and complete or partial individual choice orderings of the available alternatives from the choice set. The estimation is based on the efficient marginal data augmentation algorithm that is developed by Imai and van Dyk (2005). Keywords: data augmentation, discrete choice models, Markov chain Monte Carlo, preference data. 1. Introduction This paper illustrates how to use MNP, a publicly available R (R Development Core Team 2005) package, in order to fit the Bayesian multinomial probit model via Markov chain Monte Carlo. The multinomial probit model is often used to analyze the discrete choices made by individuals recorded in survey data. Examples where the multinomial probit model may be useful include the analysis of product choice by consumers in market research and the analysis of candidate or party choice by voters in electoral studies. The MNP software can also fit the model with different choice sets for each individual, and complete or partial individual choice orderings of the available alternatives from the choice set.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 3: Discrete Choice
    Chapter 3: Discrete Choice Joan Llull Microeconometrics IDEA PhD Program I. Binary Outcome Models A. Introduction In this chapter we analyze several models to deal with discrete outcome vari- ables. These models that predict in which of m mutually exclusive categories the outcome of interest falls. In this section m = 2, this is, we consider binary or dichotomic variables (e.g. whether to participate or not in the labor market, whether to have a child or not, whether to buy a good or not, whether to take our kid to a private or to a public school,...). In the next section we generalize the results to multiple outcomes. It is convenient to assume that the outcome y takes the value of 1 for cat- egory A, and 0 for category B. This is very convenient because, as a result, −1 PN N i=1 yi = Pr[c A is selected]. As a consequence of this property, the coeffi- cients of a linear regression model can be interpreted as marginal effects of the regressors on the probability of choosing alternative A. And, in the non-linear models, it allows us to write the likelihood function in a very compact way. B. The Linear Probability Model A simple approach to estimate the effect of x on the probability of choosing alternative A is the linear regression model. The OLS regression of y on x provides consistent estimates of the sample-average marginal effects of regressors x on the probability of choosing alternative A. As a result, the linear model is very useful for exploratory purposes.
    [Show full text]
  • Lecture 6 Multiple Choice Models Part II – MN Probit, Ordered Choice
    RS – Lecture 17 Lecture 6 Multiple Choice Models Part II – MN Probit, Ordered Choice 1 DCM: Different Models • Popular Models: 1. Probit Model 2. Binary Logit Model 3. Multinomial Logit Model 4. Nested Logit model 5. Ordered Logit Model • Relevant literature: - Train (2003): Discrete Choice Methods with Simulation - Franses and Paap (2001): Quantitative Models in Market Research - Hensher, Rose and Greene (2005): Applied Choice Analysis 1 RS – Lecture 17 Model – IIA: Alternative Models • In the MNL model we assumed independent nj with extreme value distributions. This essentially created the IIA property. • This is the main weakness of the MNL model. • The solution to the IIA problem is to relax the independence between the unobserved components of the latent utility, εi. • Solutions to IIA – Nested Logit Model, allowing correlation between some choices. – Models allowing correlation among the εi’s, such as MP Models. – Mixed or random coefficients models, where the marginal utilities associated with choice characteristics vary between individuals. Multinomial Probit Model • Changing the distribution of the error term in the RUM equation leads to alternative models. • A popular alternative: The εij’s follow an independent standard normal distributions for all i,j. • We retain independence across subjects but we allow dependence across alternatives, assuming that the vector εi = (εi1,εi2, , εiJ) follows a multivariate normal distribution, but with arbitrary covariance matrix Ω. 2 RS – Lecture 17 Multinomial Probit Model • The vector εi = (εi1,εi2, , εiJ) follows a multivariate normal distribution, but with arbitrary covariance matrix Ω. • The model is called the Multinomial probit model. It produces results similar results to the MNL model after standardization.
    [Show full text]
  • A Multinomial Probit Model with Latent Factors: Identification and Interpretation Without a Measurement System
    DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 11042 A Multinomial Probit Model with Latent Factors: Identification and Interpretation without a Measurement System Rémi Piatek Miriam Gensowski SEPTEMBER 2017 DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 11042 A Multinomial Probit Model with Latent Factors: Identification and Interpretation without a Measurement System Rémi Piatek University of Copenhagen Miriam Gensowski University of Copenhagen and IZA SEPTEMBER 2017 Any opinions expressed in this paper are those of the author(s) and not those of IZA. Research published in this series may include views on policy, but IZA takes no institutional policy positions. The IZA research network is committed to the IZA Guiding Principles of Research Integrity. The IZA Institute of Labor Economics is an independent economic research institute that conducts research in labor economics and offers evidence-based policy advice on labor market issues. Supported by the Deutsche Post Foundation, IZA runs the world’s largest network of economists, whose research aims to provide answers to the global labor market challenges of our time. Our key objective is to build bridges between academic research, policymakers and society. IZA Discussion Papers often represent preliminary work and are circulated to encourage discussion. Citation of such a paper should account for its provisional character. A revised version may be available directly from the author. IZA – Institute of Labor Economics Schaumburg-Lippe-Straße 5–9 Phone: +49-228-3894-0 53113 Bonn, Germany Email: [email protected] www.iza.org IZA DP No. 11042 SEPTEMBER 2017 ABSTRACT A Multinomial Probit Model with Latent Factors: Identification and Interpretation without a Measurement System* We develop a parametrization of the multinomial probit model that yields greater insight into the underlying decision-making process, by decomposing the error terms of the utilities into latent factors and noise.
    [Show full text]
  • Nlogit — Nested Logit Regression
    Title stata.com nlogit — Nested logit regression Description Quick start Menu Syntax Options Remarks and examples Stored results Methods and formulas References Also see Description nlogit performs full information maximum-likelihood estimation for nested logit models. These models relax the assumption of independently distributed errors and the independence of irrelevant alternatives inherent in conditional and multinomial logit models by clustering similar alternatives into nests. By default, nlogit uses a parameterization that is consistent with a random utility model (RUM). Before version 10 of Stata, a nonnormalized version of the nested logit model was fit, which you can request by specifying the nonnormalized option. You must use nlogitgen to generate a new categorical variable to specify the branches of the nested logit tree before calling nlogit. Quick start Create variables identifying alternatives at higher levels For a three-level nesting structure, create l2alt identifying four alternatives at level two based on the variable balt, which identifies eight bottom-level alternatives nlogitgen l2alt = balt(l2alt1: balt1 | balt2, l2alt2: balt3 | balt4, /// l2alt3: balt5 | balt6, l2alt4: balt7 | balt8) Same as above, defining l2alt from values of balt rather than from value labels nlogitgen l2alt = balt(l2alt1: 1|2, l2alt2: 3|4, l2alt3: 5|6, /// l2alt4: 7|8) Create talt identifying top-level alternatives based on the four alternatives in l2alt nlogitgen talt = l2alt(talt1: l2alt1 | l2alt2, talt2: l2alt3 | l2alt4) Examine tree structure
    [Show full text]
  • Simulating Generalized Linear Models
    6 Simulating Generalized Linear Models 6.1 INTRODUCTION In the previous chapter, we dug much deeper into simulations, choosing to focus on the standard linear model for all the reasons we discussed. However, most social scientists study processes that do not conform to the assumptions of OLS. Thus, most social scientists must use a wide array of other models in their research. Still, they could benefit greatly from conducting simulations with them. In this chapter, we discuss several models that are extensions of the linear model called generalized linear models (GLMs). We focus on how to simulate their DGPs and evaluate the performance of estimators designed to recover those DGPs. Specifically, we examine binary, ordered, unordered, count, and duration GLMs. These models are not quite as straightforward as OLS because the depen- dent variables are not continuous and unbounded. As we show below, this means we need to use a slightly different strategy to combine our systematic and sto- chastic components when simulating the data. None of these examples are meant to be complete accounts of the models; readers should have some familiarity beforehand.1 After showing several GLM examples, we close this chapter with a brief discus- sion of general computational issues that arise when conducting simulations. You will find that several of the simulations we illustrate in this chapter take much longer to run than did those from the previous chapter. As the DGPs get more demanding to simulate, the statistical estimators become more computationally demanding, and the simulation studies we want to conduct increase in complexity, we can quickly find ourselves doing projects that require additional resources.
    [Show full text]
  • Estimation of Logit and Probit Models Using Best, Worst and Best-Worst Choices Paolo Delle Site, Karim Kilani, Valerio Gatta, Edoardo Marcucci, André De Palma
    Estimation of Logit and Probit models using best, worst and best-worst choices Paolo Delle Site, Karim Kilani, Valerio Gatta, Edoardo Marcucci, André de Palma To cite this version: Paolo Delle Site, Karim Kilani, Valerio Gatta, Edoardo Marcucci, André de Palma. Estimation of Logit and Probit models using best, worst and best-worst choices. 2018. hal-01953581 HAL Id: hal-01953581 https://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-01953581 Preprint submitted on 13 Dec 2018 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. Estimation of Logit and Probit models using best, worst and best-worst choices Paolo Delle Sitea,∗, Karim Kilanib, Valerio Gattac, Edoardo Marcuccid, André de Palmae aUniversity Niccolò Cusano, Rome, Italy bCNAM LIRSA, Paris, France cUniversity Roma Tre, Rome, Italy dMolde University College, Molde, Norway eENS Paris Saclay, France Abstract The paper considers models for best, worst and best-worst choice probabilities, that use a single common set of random utilities. Choice probabilities are de- rived for two distributions of the random terms: i.i.d. extreme value, i.e. Logit, and multivariate normal, i.e. Probit. In Logit, best, worst and best-worst choice probabilities have a closed form.
    [Show full text]
  • Using Heteroskedastic Ordered Probit Models to Recover Moments of Continuous Test Score Distributions from Coarsened Data
    Article Journal of Educational and Behavioral Statistics 2017, Vol. 42, No. 1, pp. 3–45 DOI: 10.3102/1076998616666279 # 2016 AERA. http://jebs.aera.net Using Heteroskedastic Ordered Probit Models to Recover Moments of Continuous Test Score Distributions From Coarsened Data Sean F. Reardon Benjamin R. Shear Stanford University Katherine E. Castellano Educational Testing Service Andrew D. Ho Harvard Graduate School of Education Test score distributions of schools or demographic groups are often summar- ized by frequencies of students scoring in a small number of ordered proficiency categories. We show that heteroskedastic ordered probit (HETOP) models can be used to estimate means and standard deviations of multiple groups’ test score distributions from such data. Because the scale of HETOP estimates is indeterminate up to a linear transformation, we develop formulas for converting the HETOP parameter estimates and their standard errors to a scale in which the population distribution of scores is standardized. We demonstrate and evaluate this novel application of the HETOP model with a simulation study and using real test score data from two sources. We find that the HETOP model produces unbiased estimates of group means and standard deviations, except when group sample sizes are small. In such cases, we demonstrate that a ‘‘partially heteroskedastic’’ ordered probit (PHOP) model can produce esti- mates with a smaller root mean squared error than the fully heteroskedastic model. Keywords: heteroskedastic ordered probit model; test score distributions; coarsened data The widespread availability of aggregate student achievement data provides a potentially valuable resource for researchers and policy makers alike. Often, however, these data are only publicly available in ‘‘coarsened’’ form in which students are classified into one or more ordered ‘‘proficiency’’ categories (e.g., ‘‘basic,’’ ‘‘proficient,’’ ‘‘advanced’’).
    [Show full text]
  • Multinomial Logistic Regression Models with SAS Example
    Newsom Psy 525/625 Categorical Data Analysis, Spring 2021 1 Multinomial Logistic Regression Models Multinomial logistic regression models estimate the association between a set of predictors and a multicategory nominal (unordered) outcome. Examples of such an outcome might include “yes,” “no,” and “don’t know”; “Apple iPhone,” “Android,” and “Samsung Galaxy”; or “walk,” “bike,” “car,” “public transit.” The most common form of the model is a logistic model that is a generalization of the binary outcome of standard logistic regression involving comparisons of each category of the outcome to a referent category. There are J total categories of the outcome, indexed by the subscript j, and the number of comparisons is then J – 1. The equation for the model is written in terms of the logit of the outcome, which is a comparison of a particular category to the referent category, both denoted πj here. π ln j =αβ + X π jj j The natural log of the ratio of the two proportions is the same as the logit in standard logistic regression, where ln(πj/πj) replaces ln[π/(1-π)] , and is sometimes referred to as the generalized logit. The binary logistic model is therefore a special case of the multinomial model. In generalized linear modeling terms, the link function is the generalized logit and the random component is the multinomial distribution. The model differs from the standard logistic model in that the comparisons are all estimated simultaneously within the same model. The j subscript on both the intercept, αj, and slope, βj, indicate that there is an intercept and a slope for the comparison of each category to the referent category.
    [Show full text]
  • The Generalized Multinomial Logit Model
    The Generalized Multinomial Logit Model By Denzil G. Fiebig University of New South Wales Michael P. Keane University of Technology Sydney Jordan Louviere University of Technology Sydney Nada Wasi University of Technology Sydney June 20, 2007 Revised September 30, 2008 Abstract: The so-called “mixed” or “heterogeneous” multinomial logit (MIXL) model has become popular in a number of fields, especially Marketing, Health Economics and Industrial Organization. In most applications of the model, the vector of consumer utility weights on product attributes is assumed to have a multivariate normal (MVN) distribution in the population. Thus, some consumers care more about some attributes than others, and the IIA property of multinomial logit (MNL) is avoided (i.e., segments of consumers will tend to switch among the subset of brands that possess their most valued attributes). The MIXL model is also appealing because it is relatively easy to estimate. But recently Louviere et al (1999, 2008) have argued that the MVN is a poor choice for modelling taste heterogeneity. They argue that much of the heterogeneity in attribute weights is accounted for by a pure scale effect (i.e., across consumers, all attribute weights are scaled up or down in tandem). This implies that choice behaviour is simply more random for some consumers than others (i.e., holding attribute coefficients fixed, the scale of their error term is greater). This leads to what we call a “scale heterogeneity” MNL model (or S-MNL). Here, we develop a “generalized” multinomial logit model (G-MNL) that nests S-MNL and MIXL. By estimating the S-MNL, MIXL and G-MNL models on ten datasets, we provide evidence on their relative performance.
    [Show full text]
  • 15 Panel Data Models for Discrete Choice William Greene, Department of Economics, Stern School of Business, New York University
    15 Panel Data Models for Discrete Choice William Greene, Department of Economics, Stern School of Business, New York University I. Introduction A. Analytical Frameworks for Panel Data Models for Discrete Choice B. Panel Data II Discrete Outcome Models III Individual Heterogeneity A. Random Effects A.1. Partial Effects A.2. Alternative Models for Random Effects A.3. Specification Tests A.4. Choice Models B. Fixed Effects Models C. Correlated Random Effects D. Attrition IV Dynamic Models V. Spatial Correlation 1 I. Introduction We survey the intersection of two large areas of research in applied and theoretical econometrics. Panel data modeling broadly encompasses nearly all of modern microeconometrics and some of macroeconometrics as well. Discrete choice is the gateway to and usually the default framework in discussions of nonlinear models in econometrics. We will select a few specific topics of interest: essentially modeling cross sectional heterogeneity in the four foundational discrete choice settings: binary, ordered multinomial, unordered multinomial and count data frameworks. We will examine some of the empirical models used in recent applications, mostly in parametric forms of panel data models. There are many discussions elsewhere in this volume that discuss discrete choice models. The development here can contribute a departure point to the more specialized treatments such as Keane’s (2013, this volume) study of panel data discrete choice models of consumer demand or more theoretical discussions, such as Lee’s (2013, this volume) extensive development of dynamic multinomial logit models. Toolkits for practical application of most of the models noted here are built into familiar modern software such as Stata, SAS, R, NLOGIT, MatLab, etc.
    [Show full text]
  • A Survey of Discrete Choice Models
    Discrete Choice Modeling William Greene* Abstract We detail the basic theory for models of discrete choice. This encompasses methods of estimation and analysis of models with discrete dependent variables. Entry level theory is presented for the practitioner. We then describe a few of the recent, frontier developments in theory and practice. Contents 0.1 Introduction 0.2 Specification, estimation and inference for discrete choice models 0.2.1 Discrete choice models and discrete dependent variables 0.2.2 Estimation and inference 0.2.3 Applications 0.3 Binary Choice 0.3.1 Regression models 0.3.2 Estimation and inference in parametric binary choice models 0.3.3 A Bayesian estimator 0.3.4 Semiparametric models 0.3.5 Endogenous right hand side variables 0.3.6 Panel data models 0.3.7 Application 0.4 Bivariate and multivariate binary choice 0.4.1 Bivariate binary choice 0.4.2 Recursive simultaneous equations 0.4.3 Sample selection in a bivariate probit model 0.4.4 Multivariate binary choice and the panel probit model 0.4.5 Application 0.5 Ordered choice 0.5.1 Specification analysis 0.5.2 Bivariate ordered probit models 0.5.3 Panel data applications 0.5.4 Applications 0.6 Models for counts 0.6.1 Heterogeneity and the negative binomial model 0.6.2 Extended models for counts: Two part, zero inflation, sample selection, bivariate 0.6.3 Panel data models 0.6.4 Applications 0.7 Multinomial unordered choices 0.7.1 Multinomial logit and multinomial probit models 0.7.2 Nested logit models 0.7.3 Mixed logit and error components models 0.7.4 Applications 0.8 Summary and Conclusions To appear as “Discrete Choice Modeling,” in The Handbook of Econometrics: Vol.
    [Show full text]