Portfolio Theory of Three Tales: Risk-Adjusted Returns, Liquidity, and Leverage

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Portfolio Theory of Three Tales: Risk-Adjusted Returns, Liquidity, and Leverage Portfolio Theory of Three Tales: Risk-adjusted Returns, Liquidity, and Leverage Chanaka Edirisinghe* Lally School of Management, Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute, NY, U.S.A., [email protected] Jingnan Chen Singapore University of Technology and Design, Singapore, jingnan [email protected] Jaehwan Jeong College of Business and Economics, Radford University, VA, U.S.A., [email protected] January 16, 2018 We study the Pareto-efficiency between risk-adjusted return and leverage level of a portfolio when asset prices evolve continuously under liquidity impact. We show analytically the Sharpe-maximizing unlevered portfolio is no longer a tangency portfolio, and proportionate-leveraging is not an optimal strategy under liquidity risk. As target return increases, the required minimum portfolio-leverage increases at an increasing- rate, while the Sharpe-Leverage frontiers are progressively-dominated. These results are in contrast to the classical portfolio theory that assumes no liquidity risk. We perform empirical analysis to verify our analytical findings, which shows that ignoring liquidity impact can lead to severe portfolio under-performance. Keywords: Price impact of illiquidity, portfolio leverage, risk-adjusted returns, portfolio optimization, Pareto- efficiency JEL Codes: G11, C61, C44 * Corresponding author, Tel: 518-276-3336 1 2 1. Introduction A well-known quote from Tukey (1962, p. 13) states: \Far better an approximate answer to the right question, which is often vague, than an exact answer to the wrong question, which can always be made precise.". In this paper, the right question is: how does the economic performance of a portfolio of risky assets change when leveraging is used as a managerial choice to enhance target- return in a market scenario where illiquidity risk is inevitable? Answer to this question can be substantially-simplified when liquidity impact is completely-ignored from the question to obtain closed-form theoretical relationships, a.k.a. the modern portfolio theory (Markowitz 1952). As this study shows, the theory of leveraged portfolios is quite different when liquidity risk is taken into account. There are two related consequences of the modern portfolio theory: first, the emergence of the CAPM, see Sharpe (1964),1 in which portfolio excess return forms a linear relationship with mar- ket's excess return. The second is Tobin's (1958) separation theorem whereby portfolio choice is separated into two stages: finding an efficient (tangency) portfolio of the risky assets where risk aversion does not play a role, and then, determining the fraction of wealth to invest in the effi- cient portfolio versus a risk-free asset based on risk aversion. We show in this paper that, when illiquidity-related market impact2 is incorporated ex-ante into portfolio analysis, the above conse- quences become more complex in nature, and the conclusions are drastically-different, providing new economic insights for the three tales of a portfolio: risk-adjusted returns, leverage, and liquidity. The right question is framed in the context of rebalancing a portfolio of multiple risky assets, and a risk-free asset, in a one-period economy where trading is started at date 0, and is completed by date 1. Under a continuous-time trading paradigm facing market illiquidities, asset prices evolve under trading to affect portfolio performance adversely, evaluated at date 1. For details on how trading mechanisms affect the price formation process, see the vast literature on market micro- structure, including the seminal work in Roll (1984), Kyle (1985), and the excellent review in Hasbrouck (2007). The impact of liquidity and leveraging on portfolio performance has been addressed in the literature, but as two separate topics of interest. Our goal is to integrate liquidity and leveraging in a unified discussion toward addressing three important issues related to the right question: first, what is the potential degradation in economic performance of a portfolio designed by ignoring liquidity 1 CAPM was also introduced independently by Treynor (1961), Lintner (1965), and Mossin (1966). 2 Illiquidity may be thought of as, hypothetically, the difficulties or costs associated with reversing a trade instanta- neously after a trade is executed, which depends on market depth, volume of the trade, bid-ask spread, intermediation, and transaction costs. In this paper, we use the two terms, market impact of trading and cost of liquidity risk, in an asset synonymously. 3 risk, in comparison to an ex-ante optimal portfolio that accounts for price impact explicitly?, second, how is this performance shortfall further impacted due to portfolio leveraging?, and third, what economic insights can be gained for setting leverage and target return levels for a portfolio in a market scenario with significant liquidity risk? In the literature on impact of liquidity, it is established empirically that asset returns are sensitive to liquidity and that sensitivity is priced, see e.g. Pastor and Staumbaugh (2003), the survey in Amihud et al. (2005), or Rahi and Zigrand (2008) who employ a general equilibrium model to measure liquidity. On the other hand, Acharya and Pedersen (2005) derive a liquidity-adjusted CAPM to explain the empirical findings within a unified framework, but without any impact of leveraging. Our focus here is neither on creating a measure of liquidity nor about modifying an existing asset pricing model with a liquidity risk premium. The issue of increasing leverage to improve portfolio performance, without liquidity concerns, has also received some attention in the literature; Jacobs and Levy (2012, 2013) proposed to augment the mean-variance (MV) utility function with an additional term for leverage aversion since the standard MV paradigm fails to capture the risks faced by leveraged portfolios. However, their model is free of market impact costs of trading, hence a liquidity impact on leveraging is absent, and their focus is to fix the MV-optimal portfolios to have leverage levels more consistent with the real-world. Leverage risks stem from over-exposure in portfolio debt that may result in, for instance, the possibility of margin calls and forced liquidations at adverse prices, and losses beyond the capital invested due to unforeseen and exogenous events or sudden price changes, see Jacobs and Levy (2012). Historical events such as the 1998 financial crisis which witnessed the downfall of Long- Term Capital Management are reminders of leverage risks.3 In the financial crisis in 2008, Lehman Brothers filed for bankruptcy due to a combination of high leverage (as much as 31:1 in 2007), risky investments, and liquidity problems. Moreover, excessive-leverage poses a real risk not only to a portfolio but also in propagating a market crisis, see Acharya et al. (2012). Despite the above leverage-related risks, fund managers often seek increased leverage in order to achieve higher return targets. Usually, an unlevered portfolio of an acceptable risk profile is further invested in by incurring a debt capital, which amplifies any risks or imbalances that exist in the unlevered portfolio, but potentially leading to a gain in portfolio's returns. It is under this premise that the so-called risk parity (RP) asset allocation strategies have emerged.4 In the logic of RP, 3 The Russian devaluation of its currency and default on its treasury's debt led to the financial crisis in August 1998, and LTCM, which once leveraged their equity as much as 30:1, lost a staggering 44% of its equity during the month of August due to massive losses under forced liquidation of the holdings to cover margin requirements. 4 RP strategies garnered popularity in the aftermath of the recent global financial crisis. By August 2015, AUM using RP strategies was close to $500B, according to J.P. Morgan Markets Research. Early development of RP can be traced to Qian (2006), and further work is discussed in, e.g., Chaves et al. (2011), Maillard et al. (2010), Choueifaty and Coignard (2008), and Carvalho et al. (2012). 4 mean Portfolio B A ݉ Unlevered portfolio T ்݉ Portfolio T proportionately‐ Tangency leveraged portfolio ݎ ଴ Risk‐free return Portfolio Std Dev 0 ߪ் ߪ஻ ߪ஺ Figure 1 Leveraging a low-risk portfolio to improve expected return (when liquidity costs are ignored) liquidity concerns are absent: choose a low-risk unlevered portfolio that allocates more weight to lower risk assets, hence, a lower portfolio return as well (e.g., the tangency portfolio or the GMV), and then, the unlevered portfolio is levered-up (referred to as proportionate-leveraging) to gain superior portfolio returns without sacrificing its risk-profile, a process referred to as generating a leverage risk premium.5 Conceptually, the notion of leverage risk premium is rooted in Tobin's separation result, as illustrated in Figure 1: given a target return m, instead of choosing a high-risk (or risk-concentrated) portfolio A, a low-risk (or risk-diversified) tangency-portfolio T with return mT may be levered-up to obtain portfolio B (incurring leverage risk) to achieve the target return m (> mT ). In so-doing, B has lowered the variance risk relative to A, i.e., σB < σA. We note, however, that the increased levels of trading required to establish the positions in B (having the same composition as T ) encounters a higher degree of the aforementioned price-effects due to asset illiquidity, thereby making the anticipated performance of B questionable. That is, the expected leverage risk premium in B faces erosion due to illiquidities, which makes the superior gains expected in RP more-hypothetical. In fact, increased leverage is only going to exacerbate the effects of liquidity risk, leading to even greater impact on performance, particularly during severe market swings. As such, an analysis of leverage premium without the context of liquidity impact on portfolio performance is a vacuous exercise.6 5 Frazzini and Pedersen (2014) presented a plausible rationale based on \leverage risk aversion and low volatility asset returns" for the existence of a leverage risk premium; the cross-sectional equity risk anomaly was first documented by Ang et al.
Recommended publications
  • Analysis of Securitized Asset Liquidity June 2017 an He and Bruce Mizrach1
    Analysis of Securitized Asset Liquidity June 2017 An He and Bruce Mizrach1 1. Introduction This research note extends our prior analysis2 of corporate bond liquidity to the structured products markets. We analyze data from the TRACE3 system, which began collecting secondary market trading activity on structured products in 2011. We explore two general categories of structured products: (1) real estate securities, including mortgage-backed securities in residential housing (MBS) and commercial building (CMBS), collateralized mortgage products (CMO) and to-be-announced forward mortgages (TBA); and (2) asset-backed securities (ABS) in credit cards, autos, student loans and other miscellaneous categories. Consistent with others,4 we find that the new issue market for securitized assets decreased sharply after the financial crisis and has not yet rebounded to pre-crisis levels. Issuance is below 2007 levels in CMBS, CMOs and ABS. MBS issuance had recovered by 2012 but has declined over the last four years. By contrast, 2016 issuance in the corporate bond market was at a record high for the fifth consecutive year, exceeding $1.5 trillion. Consistent with the new issue volume decline, the median age of securities being traded in non-agency CMO are more than ten years old. In student loans, the average security is over seven years old. Over the last four years, secondary market trading volumes in CMOs and TBA are down from 14 to 27%. Overall ABS volumes are down 16%. Student loan and other miscellaneous ABS declines balance increases in automobiles and credit cards. By contrast, daily trading volume in the most active corporate bonds is up nearly 28%.
    [Show full text]
  • Asset Securitization
    L-Sec Comptroller of the Currency Administrator of National Banks Asset Securitization Comptroller’s Handbook November 1997 L Liquidity and Funds Management Asset Securitization Table of Contents Introduction 1 Background 1 Definition 2 A Brief History 2 Market Evolution 3 Benefits of Securitization 4 Securitization Process 6 Basic Structures of Asset-Backed Securities 6 Parties to the Transaction 7 Structuring the Transaction 12 Segregating the Assets 13 Creating Securitization Vehicles 15 Providing Credit Enhancement 19 Issuing Interests in the Asset Pool 23 The Mechanics of Cash Flow 25 Cash Flow Allocations 25 Risk Management 30 Impact of Securitization on Bank Issuers 30 Process Management 30 Risks and Controls 33 Reputation Risk 34 Strategic Risk 35 Credit Risk 37 Transaction Risk 43 Liquidity Risk 47 Compliance Risk 49 Other Issues 49 Risk-Based Capital 56 Comptroller’s Handbook i Asset Securitization Examination Objectives 61 Examination Procedures 62 Overview 62 Management Oversight 64 Risk Management 68 Management Information Systems 71 Accounting and Risk-Based Capital 73 Functions 77 Originations 77 Servicing 80 Other Roles 83 Overall Conclusions 86 References 89 ii Asset Securitization Introduction Background Asset securitization is helping to shape the future of traditional commercial banking. By using the securities markets to fund portions of the loan portfolio, banks can allocate capital more efficiently, access diverse and cost- effective funding sources, and better manage business risks. But securitization markets offer challenges as well as opportunity. Indeed, the successes of nonbank securitizers are forcing banks to adopt some of their practices. Competition from commercial paper underwriters and captive finance companies has taken a toll on banks’ market share and profitability in the prime credit and consumer loan businesses.
    [Show full text]
  • Asset Pricing with Liquidity Risk∗
    Asset Pricing with Liquidity Risk∗ Viral V. Acharyay and Lasse Heje Pedersenz First Version: July 10, 2000 Current Version: September 24, 2004 Abstract This paper solves explicitly an equilibrium asset pricing model with liq- uidity risk — the risk arising from unpredictable changes in liquidity over time. In our liquidity-adjusted capital asset pricing model, a security's re- quired return depends on its expected liquidity as well as on the covariances of its own return and liquidity with market return and market liquidity. In addition, the model shows how a negative shock to a security's liquidity, if it is persistent, results in low contemporaneous returns and high predicted future returns. The model provides a simple, unified framework for under- standing the various channels through which liquidity risk may affect asset prices. Our empirical results shed light on the total and relative economic significance of these channels. ∗We are grateful for conversations with Andrew Ang, Joseph Chen, Sergei Davydenko, Fran- cisco Gomes, Joel Hasbrouck, Andrew Jackson, Tim Johnson, Martin Lettau, Anthony Lynch, Stefan Nagel, Lubos Pastor, Tano Santos, Dimitri Vayanos, Luis Viceira, Jeff Wurgler, and semi- nar participants at London Business School, London School of Economics, New York University, the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) Summer Institute 2002, the Five Star Confer- ence 2002, Western Finance Association Meetings 2003, and the Texas Finance Festival 2004. We are especially indebted to Yakov Amihud and to an anonymous referee for help and many valuable suggestions. All errors remain our own. yAcharya is at London Business School and is a Research Affiliate of the Centre for Eco- nomic Policy Research (CEPR).
    [Show full text]
  • Liquidity Risk Management
    BASEL III FRAMEWORK Liquidity Risk Management Rules and Guidelines November 2018 Table of Contents TABLE OF CONTENTS ...................................................................................................................................... 2 LIST OF ACRONYMS ......................................................................................................................................... 4 PART I – LIQUIDITY RISK MANAGEMENT FRAMEWORK ............................................................... 5 1. BACKGROUND AND OVERVIEW ............................................................................................................................ 5 2. SCOPE OF APPLICATION ...................................................................................................................................... 5 3. STATEMENT OF OBJECTIVES ................................................................................................................................ 5 4. ONGOING LIQUIDITY MANAGEMENT ................................................................................................................... 5 5. MEASURING AND MONITORING LIQUIDITY REQUIREMENTS ............................................................................. 7 6. MANAGING MARKET ACCESS .............................................................................................................................. 9 7. CONTINGENCY PLANNING ...................................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • IBOR to RFR Transition
    Changing the world’s most important number IBOR to RFR transition March 2021 home.kpmg/in 2 Foreword For more than three decades, London Interbank all 35 LIBOR settings at once, giving firms a Offered Rate (‘LIBOR’) has been integrated in clear set of deadlines across all currencies and financial markets, serving as the benchmark tenors. FCA issued that all seven tenors for for borrowings, loans and derivative contracts. both euro and Swiss franc LIBOR, overnight, LIBOR has hence been called the ‘world’s one-week, two-month and 12-month sterling most important number’ as it is hardwired LIBOR, spot next, one-week, two-month and in all financial activities, such as treasury, 12-month yen LIBOR and one-week and two- risk management, accounting including month U.S. dollar LIBOR will permanently hedge accounting, valuation and commercial cease immediately after 31 December 2021. contracts. Following the global financial crisis, Overnight and 12-month U.S. dollar LIBOR regulators discovered that the banks entrusted settings publication will cease immediately after to set the rates underpinning hundreds of 30 June 2023. trillions of dollars of financial assets had been In response, the regulators and market manipulating them to their advantage, raising participants across the globe have been questions about the future sustainability of developing new benchmarks to replace Libor LIBOR. Regulators globally have signaled clearly by the end of 2021. With 31 December 2021, that institutions should transition away from in plain sight, and FCA announcement on the Interbank Offered Rate (IBOR) to alternative LIBOR cessation, preparation for the transition overnight risk-free rates (RFRs).
    [Show full text]
  • Securitization, Monetary Policy and Bank Stability
    Securitization, Monetary Policy and Bank Stability Mohamed Bakousha,1,∗, Tapas Mishraa,2, Simon Wolfea,3, aSouthampton Business School, University of Southampton, UK Abstract We provide new evidence about the effect of securitization activities on bank stability and systemic risk in the run-up to and following the global financial crisis by consid- ering the role of monetary policy interest rates. In so doing, we propose S{score as a new measure of the net effect of securitization activities on bank stability. Analyzing the dynamics of this measure at the individual bank level and the banking system level shows that securitization activities have a destabilizing effect on banks. We also find that securitization increases commonality of asset returns among banks leading to increased interconnectedness and systemic risk. We also find that low monetary policy interest rates in the aftermath of the global financial crisis have mitigated the destabilizing effect of securitization on banks. Keywords: Securitization, Bank Profitability, Bank Risk, Bank Stability, Systemic Risk; Monetary Policy JEL Classification: G21; G10 ∗Corresponding Author (Email: [email protected]). 1Mohamed Bakoush is an Assistant Professor in Banking and Finance, Southampton Business School, University of Southampton. (Email: [email protected]) 2Tapas Mishra is a Professor of Banking and Finance, Southampton Business School, University of Southampton. (Email: [email protected]) 3Simon Wolfe is a Professor of Banking and Finance, Southampton Business School, University of Southampton.(Email: [email protected]) Preprint submitted to Elsevier December 31, 2019 1. Introduction Securitization has fundamentally altered the way in which financial intermediation is organized as it has provided banks with an innovative way to improve efficiency and performance.
    [Show full text]
  • COVID-19 Impact on Bank Liquidity Risk Management and Response
    COVID-19 impact on bank liquidity risk management and response Overview As a result of COVID-19 and the actions In response to the recent adverse market the economy during adverse situations taken by governments and businesses activity, the Federal Reserve Board such as the impacts of COVID-19 and to to help mitigate the impact, financial (the Fed) has taken steps to stabilize the enable banks to continue lending. The Fed is institutions have been challenged in their financial markets through the purchase of encouraging banks to use their capital and ability to manage and report on their Treasuries and government guaranteed liquidity buffers as they make loans available liquidity positions and funding capabilities. mortgage-backed securities, reviving to households and businesses affected by Regulatory requirements put in place the Primary Dealer Credit Facility to offer the COVID-19 restrictions, assuming this after 2008 were designed to improve loans to securities firms, reestablishing lending is done in a safe and sound manner2. banks’ ability to meet funding obligations the Money Market Mutual Fund Facility, by establishing liquidity buffers, and to and substantially expanding its repo Industry challenges in liquidity implement contingency funding plans operations1 The Fed has also encouraged and funding risk management (CFPs) to guide banks during times of crisis. banks to start borrowing from its discount However, recent equity market volatility, window and regulators have extended the Although the Fed has taken steps to stabilize liquidity tightening, widening funding timeline for certain regulatory requirements the market and make funding available, spreads, operational fails, and (e.g. the Current Expected Credit Losses many banks have already activated their other challenges have put significant implementation) in an effort to reduce CFPs and are actively managing and pressure on bank liquidity some pressure on bank resources.
    [Show full text]
  • Basel III: the Liquidity Coverage Ratio and Liquidity Risk Monitoring Tools
    This standard has been integrated into the consolidated Basel Framework: https://www.bis.org/basel_framework/ Basel Committee on Banking Supervision Basel III: The Liquidity Coverage Ratio and liquidity risk monitoring tools January 2013 This publication is available on the BIS website (www.bis.org). © Bank for International Settlements 2013. All rights reserved. Brief excerpts may be reproduced or translated provided the source is cited. ISBN 92-9131- 912-0 (print) ISBN 92-9197- 912-0 (online) Contents Introduction ............................................................................................................................ 1 Part 1: The Liquidity Coverage Ratio ..................................................................................... 4 I. Objective of the LCR and use of HQLA ......................................................................... 4 II. Definition of the LCR ..................................................................................................... 6 A. Stock of HQLA ..................................................................................................... 7 1. Characteristics of HQLA ............................................................................. 7 2. Operational requirements ........................................................................... 9 3. Diversification of the stock of HQLA.......................................................... 11 4. Definition of HQLA ...................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Liquidity (Risk) Concepts Definitions and Interactions
    WORKING PAPER SERIES NO 1008 / FEBRUARY 2009 LIQUIDITY (RISK) CONCEPTS DEFINITIONS AND INTERACTIONS by Kleopatra Nikolaou WORKING PAPER SERIES NO 1008 / FEBRUARY 2009 LIQUIDITY (RISK) CONCEPTS DEFINITIONS AND INTERACTIONS 1 by Kleopatra Nikolaou 2 In 2009 all ECB publications This paper can be downloaded without charge from feature a motif http://www.ecb.europa.eu or from the Social Science Research Network taken from the €200 banknote. electronic library at http://ssrn.com/abstract_id=1333568. 1 This paper was written in partial fulfilment of the ECB Graduate Program 2006. The author is indebted for useful conversations and constructive comments to Nuno Cassola. The author would also like to thank the participant of the ECB Graduate Program Presentation Series, as well as the Editorial Board of the ECB Working Paper Series for useful comments. The author alone is responsible for any errors that may remain and for the views expressed in the paper. 2 European Central Bank, Kaiserstrasse 29, D-60311 Frankfurt am Main, Germany; email: [email protected] © European Central Bank, 2009 Address Kaiserstrasse 29 60311 Frankfurt am Main, Germany Postal address Postfach 16 03 19 60066 Frankfurt am Main, Germany Telephone +49 69 1344 0 Website http://www.ecb.europa.eu Fax +49 69 1344 6000 All rights reserved. Any reproduction, publication and reprint in the form of a different publication, whether printed or produced electronically, in whole or in part, is permitted only with the explicit written authorisation of the ECB or the author(s). The views expressed in this paper do not necessarily refl ect those of the European Central Bank.
    [Show full text]
  • Liquidity Risk: Management and Supervisory Challenges
    Basel Committee on Banking Supervision Liquidity Risk: Management and Supervisory Challenges February 2008 Requests for copies of publications, or for additions/changes to the mailing list, should be sent to: Bank for International Settlements Press & Communications CH-4002 Basel, Switzerland E-mail: [email protected] Fax: +41 61 280 9100 and +41 61 280 8100 © Bank for International Settlements 2005. All rights reserved. Brief excerpts may be reproduced or translated provided the source is stated. ISBN print: 92-9131-754-3 ISBN web: 92-9197-754-3 Table of Contents Liquidity Risk: Management and Supervisory Challenges........................................................1 I. Introduction......................................................................................................................1 II. Liquidity risk management challenges ............................................................................2 A. The challenge of liquidity risk management ...........................................................2 B. Funding from capital markets.................................................................................2 C. Securitisation..........................................................................................................3 D. Complex financial instruments ...............................................................................3 E. Collateral usage .....................................................................................................4 F. Payments systems and intraday liquidity
    [Show full text]
  • Liquidity Regulation, Bail-Ins and Bailouts∗
    Liquidity Regulation, Bail-ins and Bailouts∗ Mathias Dewatriponty and Jean Tirolez June 8, 2018 Abstract: A major regulatory innovation in the wake of the 2008 financial crisis was the introduction of liquidity requirements for banks in the Basel framework. While the philosophy of such requirements is intuitive, policymakers received little guidance from academia on a number of specific questions such as the measure of the liquidity buffer, its possible decomposition into multiple tiers (as is done for capital requirements), the treat- ment of interbank exposures or of the securitization of legacy assets, or the recognition of central-bank-eligible assets as part of the buffer. More fundamentally, the consistency between liquidity and solvency regulations has been under-researched. Accordingly, the introduction of layers of “bail-inable” liabilities to complement the Basel III framework occurred without conceptual framework for thinking about liquidity and solvency regu- lation. The paper develops such a framework, integrates the asset and liability sides into an overall design of prudential regulation and assesses the regulatory reform. Keywords: Liquidity weighted assets (LWA), prudential regulation, bailouts, bail-ins, fire sales, baseload and peakload liquidity, central bank liquidity support, central bank eligible assets. JEL numbers: D82, G21, M48. ∗The authors are grateful to Paul-Henri Moisson for excellent research assistance. This project has received funding from the European Research Council (ERC) under the European Union’s Horizon 2020 research and innovation programme (grant agreement n◦ 669217 - ERC MARKLIM). We thank Jeremy Stein and participants at the “New Frontiers in Banking” conference (Rome) and seminars at AFSE, Banque Nationale de Belgique, Berkeley and CUHK (Shenzhen) for helpful comments.
    [Show full text]
  • Asset Securitisation
    Superseded document Basel Committee on Banking Supervision Consultative Document Asset Securitisation Supporting Document to the New Basel Capital Accord Issued for comment by 31 May 2001 January 2001 Superseded document Superseded document Table of Contents OVERVIEW .............................................................................................................................................1 I. THE TREATMENT OF EXPLICIT RISKS ASSOCIATED WITH TRADITIONAL SECURITISATION........................................................................................................................1 A. THE STANDARDISED APPROACH .............................................................................................2 1. The treatment for originating banks..........................................................................2 (a) Minimum operational requirements for achieving a clean break.................................3 (b) Minimum capital requirements for credit enhancements ............................................3 (c) Minimum operational requirements for revolving securitisations with early amortisation features .............................................................................................................4 2. The treatment for investing banks ............................................................................6 (a) Minimum capital requirements for investments in ABS...............................................6 (b) Treatment of unrated securitisations ..........................................................................7
    [Show full text]