PERFECT COMPETITION, EFFICIENCY and EXTERNALITIES by Jon D

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

PERFECT COMPETITION, EFFICIENCY and EXTERNALITIES by Jon D 1 ENVIRONMENTAL AND NATURAL RESOURCE ECONOMICS Part 1: PERFECT COMPETITION, EFFICIENCY AND EXTERNALITIES by Jon D. Harford (Last updated January, 2005) (Note: references to Tietenberg are to his book Environmental and Natural Resource Economics, 7th edition, published by Addison Wesley. Perfect Competition without Externalities (Tietenberg discusses this type of material in Chapter 2 of his book.) Perfect competition is an ideal form of a market economy which represents a simple starting point for analysis of real world economies. In perfect competition large numbers of buyers and sellers exist in each and every market and no one of them believes he has any influence over price. In addition, there is no uncertainty or imperfection in information and all decision makers are rational. Rationality for consumers means maximizing a well- defined utility function subject to an individual budget constraint, while rationality for each producer means each firm maximizes profits by its choice of inputs and output. For consumers, maximizing utility subject to the budget constraint leads to particular choices of consumption goods for each set of price and budget that the consumer faces. By varying the price of one particular good, other things the same, one can derive a relationship between the quantity of one particular good chosen and its price. This relationship is the individual demand curve of a consumer, a relationship which holds prices of other goods and income constant. Assuming that consumption of a unit of a good X by George affects no one except George, the demand curve of George for good X can be interpreted as reflecting the marginal benefit of units of 2 consumption. Referring to the demand curve in Figure 1a, it is seen that at price of $12, George would buy one unit of the good X. Accordingly, the value to George of the first unit of the good must be at least $12. At a price of $11, George would be willing to buy two units of X. From this we can infer that the second unit of X must be worth at least $11. Continuing in this reasoning it is seen that the third unit of X must be worth at least $10, the fourth unit must be worth $9, and the fifth unit must be worth at least $8. Accordingly, we would argue that the total of five units must be worth at least $(12+11+10+9+8)=$50. The total value of five units of the X good we shall call the total benefits of that consumption. Now suppose George faced a price of $8 for the X good and accordingly paid a total ($8)(5)=$40 to acquire five units. The difference between the amount George spent to acquire the five units and the total benefits of those units would be called his consumer surplus. George's consumer surplus is his net benefits of consuming five units of the good. That is, net benefits are the total benefits minus the total costs (his expenditures) of consuming the five units. We know that this net benefit is at least ($50-$40)=$10. The method of refining this estimate is to take ever smaller increments in the amount of the X good and calculate the highest price associated with acquiring that increment. If one takes this process to its ultimate limit, one finds that the total benefits equal the area under the demand curve up to the quantity consumed. Therefore, we can conclude that the value of consumer surplus is the area between the demand curve and the price line over to the quantity consumed. Marginal benefit is the rate of change of total benefits with respect to a change in the good consumed. An estimate of George's marginal benefit a given unit of X is the highest price at which that unit is purchased. Mathematically, 3 George's marginal benefit of consuming an infinitesimal amount of additional good X is the height of his demand curve. Individual demand curves are added horizontally (quantity addition) to obtain the market demand curve for good X. The total benefit, marginal benefit, and consumer surplus associated with the market demand curve for X are calculated in exactly the same fashion as with the individual demand curve. 4 While benefits come from consuming goods, costs come from producing them. Perfectly competitive firms maximize profits under conditions in which they take input and output prices as constants. In the short run this leads to a choice of output in which marginal cost equals price. In the long run equilibrium marginal cost and average cost both equal price. Thus, at the market output that is supplied for any given level of price it can be said that output is being produced at marginal cost. Of course, the supply curve only reflects private costs. That is, costs which the individual firms see as affecting their profits. Referring to Figure 1b, one sees that one unit of output will be produced when the price is $4, thus indicating that the cost to private producers of the first unit of output is no more than $4. At a price of $5, suppliers are willing to provide two units of the good. This indicates that the second unit of the good costs the firms no more than $5. Iterating, it is seen that the third unit 5 costs no more than $6, and the fourth unit costs no more than $7. If uses the same reasoning, but takes ever smaller increments to output, it is seen that the area under the supply curve up to the amount produced is the total private cost of production. Now suppose that suppliers receive $8 per unit for each of five units for a total of $40. Our method of cost accounting would indicate that the total private cost is no more than ($4+$5+$6+$7+$8)=$30. However, in the long run under perfect competition there must be zero economic profit and firms would therefore have revenues equal to opportunity costs. The difference in the two views of costs is that our estimate of $30 takes the view that part of the "costs" of firms are not costs from society's viewpoint, but economic rents. Economic rents are those payments to factors of production above the minimum necessary to keep them in an industry. In other words, economic rents are that part of the payments to factors such as a bricklayer, that is above his opportunity cost as represented, for example, by the level of wage he could receive by working in another industry. The collection of economic rents received by factors of production in an industry is called the producers' surplus. Producers' surplus is represented by the area between the price line, the supply curve, and the vertical axis, up to the quantity produced. The producers' surplus can be considered the net benefits of production to the supply side, just as consumer surplus can be consider the net benefits of consumption to the demand side of the market. It is one of the remarkable things about perfect competition is that it is perfectly efficient given certain conditions. Some of the conditions for its efficiency are merely the conditions for its existence. These include perfect information by all parties about all prices and products, no uncertainty, that economies of scale disappear at output levels small compared to the market 6 demand at a price that reflects average cost, and that goods have attributes that make private ownership possible. An additional condition for the efficiency of perfect competition is that there are no externalities or third-party effects. Since the subject of environmental economics is basically one of applying the notion of externalities to problems such as pollution and congestion, we will have much more to say about this subject. For now, let us turn to Figure 2 to illustrate how perfect competition produces efficiency under the ideal circumstances indicated. By efficiency, it is simply meant that overall benefits minus costs are maximized. In the Figure, it is seen that output Q* clears the market and that area N is consumer surplus, and area M is producer surplus. The total benefits of the production and consumption of Q* is the sum of producers' and consumer surplus. Now suppose that we consider the costs and benefits of expanding output to Q1. One cannot know how the benefits and costs would fall on various parties without 7 describing the policy that would bring about such and increase in output, but we can know what the effect on net benefits would have to be. Specifically, the increase in benefits associated with greater consumption of the good would be represented by area G, while the increase in production cost associated with the increased output would be (G+H). This implies that net benefits would go down by an amount equal to H. One can perform a similar analysis to demonstrate that a reduction in output would also reduce net benefits because consumption benefits would be decreasing faster than the reduction in production costs. Under the circumstances assumed, no form of government intervention can improve efficiency. A POLLUTION EXTERNALITY: THE OUTPUT DIMENSION We now consider a situation in which a perfectly competitive industry produces pollution in direct proportion to the amount of output it produces. In other words, it is assumed that the ratio of pollution (Z) to output (Q) is a constant equal to w=(Z/Q). This pollution creates an external cost to society. For example, it z were an air pollutant, the external cost would be manifested in an increased incidence of respiratory ailments in the general population, reduced visibility, and damage to the surfaces of buildings, cars, and clothing.
Recommended publications
  • A Reconsideration of Full-Cost Pricing
    A Reconsideration of Full-Cost Pricing Methodological Aspects of Marginalism and Theoretical Explanations of Pricing Behaviour Inaugural-Dissertation zur Erlangung des Grades Doctor oeconomiae publicae (Dr. oec. publ.) an der Ludwig-Maximilians-Universität München 2010 vorgelegt von Elmar Nubbemeyer Referent: Ekkehart Schlicht Korreferent: Kenneth Coutts Datum der mündlichen Prüfung: 8. November 2010 Promotionsabschlussberatung: 17. November 2010 Acknowledgements This thesis was written in the years 2007-2010 during my time as a research and teaching assistant at the Seminar für Theorie und Politik der Einkom- mensverteilung at the Ludwig-Maximilians-Universität München and my stay at the University of Cambridge, UK. First and foremost, I would like to thank my supervisor Ekkehart Schlicht. His trust, universal support and strong interest in my research ideas were cru- cial for the success of this project. He always took time for my requests, in- spired me with countless suggestions and was a great mentor in matters both academic and not. Furthermore, I thank Ken Coutts, who invited me to a re- search visit at the University of Cambridge, UK and later agreed to act as my secondary supervisor. I am very grateful for his generous hospitality and his interest in my work. I also want to thank Florian Englmaier, who kindly agreed to act as my third examiner. Many friends and co-workers supported me in the course of this work. My dear colleagues and friends Roberto Cruccolini and Christoph Stoeckle helped me in many ways and contributed to a great working atmosphere. Maria Mor- genroth took care of all administrative tasks and often provided good advice.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter # 2 the Essenceof Economics
    LIGHTHOUSE CPA SOCIAL SCIENCES DEPARTMENT AP ECONOMICS STUDY GUIDE # 2 - THE ESSENCE OF ECONOMICS - THE ART OF DECISION MAKING CHAPTER LEARNING OBJECTIVES 1. STUDENTS WILL BE ABLE TO EXPLAIN THE FIRST LAW OF ECONOMICS AND LIFE 2. STUDENTS WILL BE ABLE TO EXPLAIN THE CONCEPT OF OPPORTUNITY COSTS AND ILLUSTRATE AN EXAMPLE 3. IN ECONOMIC TERMS , STUDENTS WILL BE ABLE TO EXPLAIN THE CONCEPT OF “ THINKING AT THE MARGIN ” AND ILLUSTRATE AN EXAMPLE OF USING MARGINAL ANALYSIS 4. STUDENTS WILL BE ABLE TO IDENTIFY THE 3 BASIC FOCAL POINTS OF A COST BENEFIT ANALYSIS 5. STUDENTS WILL BE ABLE TO EXPLAIN AND ILLUSTRATE THE FOLLOWING LAWS AND PRINCIPLES : 1. MARGINAL PRODUCT OF LABOR NEEDS & WANTS 2. INCREASING MARGINAL RETURNS 3. DIMINISHING MARGINAL RETURNS 4. NEGATIVE MARGINAL RETURNS 5. DIVISION OF LABOR 6. SPECIALIZATION 7. HOW PROFIT IS DETERMINED ____________________________________________________________________________ DECISION MAKING STEP # 1 > WE NEED TO UNDERSTAND THE HIGHLY VALUED , AND SECRET FIRST LAW OF ECONOMICS AND LIFE : WHAT DOES THE WORD “ FREE ” MEAN ? ARE THERE ANY “ FREE ” GOODS ? WHAT IS THE FIRST LAW OF ECONOMICS AND LIFE ? WHAT ARE THE FOUR REASONS WHY YOU WANT TO HAVE A BETTER UNDERSTANDING ABOUT HOW TO MAKE DECISIONS ? 1. 2. 3. 4. DECISION MAKING STEP # 2 > WE NEED TO UNDERSTAND HOW TO EFFECTIVELY HANDLE “ TRADE OFFS ” : NEED WANT VALUE / COST 1 2 3 4 WHAT IS “ OPPORTUNITY COST ” ? EXAMPLE # 1 > ILLUSTRATES OPPORTUNITY COSTS > PENNY PICKUP PICKED UP NOT PICKED UP EXAMPLES # 2 AND 3 > ILLUSTRATES OPPORTUNITY COSTS > BODY
    [Show full text]
  • Econ272 Foundations of Economic Analysis Text: an Economic Way of Thinking
    Econ272 Foundations of Economic Analysis Text: An Economic Way of Thinking 4th Edition Table of Contents Chapter 1: An Economic Way of Thinking ........................................................................................................ 7 Economists and Normal People ...................................................................................................................... 7 Some Keys to Understanding the Way Economists Think ............................................................................. 7 The Basic Economic Problem Scarcity, Choice and Cost .............................................................................. 9 Alternative Approaches to the Basic Economic Problem ............................................................................. 11 Economic Systems and the Basic Economic Problem .................................................................................. 12 The Science of Economics: Observation, Theory and Models ..................................................................... 16 A Model of an Economy: The Production Possibility Frontier I .................................................................. 18 A Model of a College Student’s Basic Economic Problem: The Production Possibility Frontier II ............ 21 Saving, Capital and Growth: The Production Possibility Frontier III .......................................................... 22 The Circular Flow Economic Model ...........................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Unit 1 Scope of Managerial Economics
    This course material is designed and developed by Indira Gandhi National Open University (IGNOU), New Delhi. OSOU has been permitted to use the material. Master Of Commerce (MCOM) MCO-11 Managerial Economics Block-1 Introduction to Managerial Economics Unit-1 Scope of Managerial Economics Unit-2 Firm: Stakeholders, Objectives & Decision Issues Unit-3 Basic Techniques of Managerial Economics Introduction to UNIT 1 SCOPE OF MANAGERIAL Microbes ECONOMICS Objectives After studying this unit, you should be able to: understand the nature and scope of managerial economics; familiarize yourself with economic terminology; develop some insight into economic issues; acquire some information about economic institutions; understand the concept of trade-offs or policy options facing society today. Structure 1.1 Introduction 1.2 Fundamental Nature of Managerial Economics 1.3 Scope of Managerial Economics 1.4 Appropriate Definitions 1.5 Managerial Economics and other Disciplines 1.6 Economic Analysis 1.7 Basic Characteristics: Decision-Making 1.8 Summary 1.9 Self-Assessment Questions 1.10 Further Readings 1.1 INTRODUCTION For most purposes economics can be divided into two broad categories, microeconomics and macroeconomics. Macroeconomics as the name suggests is the study of the overall economy and its aggregates such as Gross National Product, Inflation, Unemployment, Exports, Imports, Taxation Policy etc. Macroeconomics addresses questions about changes in investment, government spending, employment, prices, exchange rate of the rupee and so on. Importantly, only aggregate levels of these variables are considered in the study of macroeconomics. But hidden in the aggregate data are changes in output of a number of individual firms, the consumption decision of consumers like you, and the changes in the prices of particular goods and services.
    [Show full text]
  • Water Utility Management International • September 2014 News Contents
    SEPTEMBER 2014 I water VOLUME 9 ISSUE 3 utility management INTER N ATIONAL COMMUNICATIONS ENERGY EFFICIENCY Saving energy and cutting water treatment costs on the US-Mexico border TARIFFS CUSTOMER SERVICES Incorporating marginal costs in water supply tariffs: prospects for change Improving utility customer services: the case of Eau de Paris PLUS ... A new data paradigm for water management NEWS Research finds common coagulant could corrode sewers research team at the University of that take up the hydrogen sulphide and effect for sewers downstream. AQueensland has discovered that a oxidise it to form sulphuric acid. The researchers undertook a two-year common coagulant used in drinking water The team, led by Professor Zhiguo sampling programme in South East treatment can be a prime contributor to Yuan, concluded that to reduce sulphide Queensland, conducted an industry survey global sewer corrosion. formation, it was necessary to reduce either across the country, and undertook a global Aluminium sulphate (alum) is widely the sulphate or the organics in wastewater, literature review and a comprehensive used as a coagulant as it is relatively the latter not being a viable option. They model-based scenario analysis of the cheap and widely available. The paper, recommended that utilities move to sul - various possible sources of sulphate to published in the journal Science, reveals phate-free coagulants, in order to reduce reach its conclusions. that the coagulant is the main source concrete corrosion by 35% after just ten The team also recommends a of over 50% of the sulphate found in hours and up to 60% over a longer period more fully integrated approach to wastewater, which in turn is indirectly of time, generating potentially large savings urban water management to identify the primary source of hydrogen sulphide.
    [Show full text]
  • Downloaded from Elgar Online at 09/25/2021 01:07:14PM Via Free Access
    1. Decision rules William K. Bellinger ABSTRACT Benefit-cost analysis is the cornerstone of the economic analysis of public policy, and is closely aligned with basic rational choice and market concepts from microeconomics. Information and other constraints often block the direct application of marginal decision rules for policy decisions, but the conceptual role of marginalism can still be useful in interpreting benefit-cost analysis. While all policy analysis texts that emphasize the economic dimensions of policy cover the basics of marginal analysis, the sources of market inefficiency, and basic decision rules for policy analysis, the connections between marginal and non-marginal policy decision rules are seldom emphasized. This chapter limits its discussion of marginal analysis to the concepts of optimal quantity and optimal allocation rather than the market-based concepts of surplus, equilibrium and elasticity which are discussed in later chapters. This chapter begins by reviewing marginal and non-marginal concepts and measures for policy decisions, and then discusses a set of basic decision rules that can be informed by these concepts. Student exercises are included and answered in the appendix to the chapter. MARGINAL AND NON-MARGINAL FUNDAMENTALS There are two marginal concepts that inform common policy decision rules. The first defines the optimal quantity of any activity as the point where marginal benefits equal marginal costs, given that net benefits are decreasing in the neighborhood of the equality. If these conditions apply, one should continue to invest in a project as long as the marginal benefits of the project are greater than its marginal costs, and should choose one’s scale for the project where the marginal benefits and marginal costs are equal.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Reconsidering the Early Marginal Productivity
    ♦ Reconsidering the early marginal productivity theory of distribution and interest Arrigo Opocher INTRODUCTION The 1960s’ critique of capital theory argued that one cannot explain income distribution on the basis of ‘social’ marginal productivities of given (and fully employed) endowments of labour, land and capital. In the words of Pasinetti: ‘Very far from embodying the relevant features of the general case, and from being a simplified way of expressing it, the one-commodity infinite-techniques construction is (…) revealed to be an entirely isolated case. As such, it can have no theoretical or practical relevance whatever. At the same time the whole traditional idea that lower and lower rates of profit are the natural and necessary consequence of further and further additions to “capital” is revealed to be false’ (Pasinetti, 1969, pp. 522-3). The ‘traditional idea’ referred to by Pasinetti was developed in the XXth century and may be exemplified in Hicks’s Theory of Wages1 . This theory, in turn, is generally thought to have been the natural development of the early marginal productivity theory, put forward in the 1890s by a group of mathematically oriented economists such as Wicksteed (1894), Walras (1896), Barone (1896) and Wicksell (1893 and 1901) 2. Yet the early theory -which was much less ambitious than its XXth century versions and, with the exception of Wicksell, is immune to capital theoretic criticism- is interesting in its own and it is open to different ♦ I thank Ian Steedman and Carlo Panico for his useful comments and participants at a meeting on ‘Growth and distribution’ in Catania, 23-4 January 2004, for further stimulus.
    [Show full text]
  • History of Economic Thought Paola Tubaro
    History of economic thought Paola Tubaro To cite this version: Paola Tubaro. History of economic thought. Rhona C. Free. 21st Century Economics: A Reference Handbook, 1, Sage, pp.3-11, 2010, 9781412961424. hal-01372974 HAL Id: hal-01372974 https://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-01372974 Submitted on 29 Nov 2016 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. Distributed under a Creative Commons Attribution - NonCommercial - ShareAlike| 4.0 International License Part I Scope and Methodology of Economics 1 SCOPE AND METHODOLOGY OF ECONOMICS History of Economic Thought 1 HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT Paola Tubaro University of Greenwich, Business School, London; Centre Maurice Halbwachs, Paris Like economic history, the history of economic thought (HET) investigates economic issues in long-run perspective. Yet the two fields are distinct and should not be confounded: HET does not study economic facts such as the 1929 financial crisis but rather economic theories and economic literature. It focuses on the historical roots of economic ideas and takes into account a wide array of schools of thought; in conjunction with pure theory and the history of facts, it constitutes part of a comprehensive approach to the study of the economic bases of modern societies.
    [Show full text]
  • Mr Marx and the Neoclassics
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive Mr Marx and the neoclassics Freeman, Alan the University of Greenwich July 1996 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/1291/ MPRA Paper No. 1291, posted 04 Feb 2007 UTC MR MARX AND THE NEOCLASSICS Alan Freeman University of Greenwich September 1996 ABSTRACT This article, presented to the Annual Conference of the History of Economics Society, Vancouver July 1996, gives a historical analysis of the origins of the general equilibrium or comparative static approach and demonstrates that economic thought as a whole is divided, in each of its schools of thought, between the equilibrium paradigm and its alternative, the temporal paradigm. This applies across the board with, for example, the divergence between Post-Keynesian or Kaleckian economics, between Austrian economics and Walrasian general equilibrium, and in many other contexts . The article demonstrates the difference between the equilibrium and temporal approach using a demonstration of ‘adjustment’ effects in a simple corn-cycle model. It goes on to analyse the reasons why, in the history of thought, adjustment or dynamic effects have been considered as ignorable when in fact they are not. It suggests that the traditional division of the succession of ideas in economic thought – physiocracy, the classics, Marx, marginalism – needs to be reviewed in this light, and argues for a reconsideration of the contribution of Marx to economics, placing him as the first and in many ways the most consistent in a suppressed non-equilibrium tradition in economic thought. It suggests that in this light, Marx has more in common with Austrian and Post-Keynesian thinking than with Ricardo and Smith, among whose ranks he is normally and commonly grouped.
    [Show full text]
  • Managerial Economics Theory and Practice.Pdf
    Managerial Economics Theory and Practice ThisPageIntentionallyLeftBlank Managerial Economics Theory and Practice Thomas J. Webster Lubin School of Business Pace University New York, NY Amsterdam Boston Heidelberg London New York Oxford Paris San Diego San Francisco Singapore Sydney Tokyo This book is printed on acid-free paper. Copyright © 2003, Elsevier (USA). All Rights Reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic or mechanical, including photocopy, recording, or any information storage and retrieval system, without permission in writing from the publisher. Permissions may be sought directly from Elsevier’s Science & Technology Rights Department in Oxford, UK: phone: (+44) 1865 843830, fax: (+44) 1865 853333, e-mail: [email protected]. You may also complete your request on-line via the Elsevier Science homepage (http://elsevier.com), by selecting “Customer Support” and then “Obtaining Permissions.” Academic Press An imprint of Elsevier Science 525 B Street, Suite 1900, San Diego, California 92101-4495, USA http://www.academicpress.com Academic Press 84 Theobald’s Road, London WC1X 8RR, UK http://www.academicpress.com Library of Congress Catalog Card Number: 2003102999 International Standard Book Number: 0-12-740852-5 PRINTED IN THE UNITED STATES OF AMERICA 03040506077654321 To my sons, Adam Thomas and Andrew Nicholas ThisPageIntentionallyLeftBlank Contents 1 Introduction What is Economics 1 Opportunity Cost 3 Macroeconomics Versus Microeconomics 3 What is Managerial
    [Show full text]
  • The Welfare Analysis of Fiscal Policy: a Simple Unified Account
    The Welfare Analysis of Fiscal Policy: A Simple Unified Account James E. Anderson Will Martin Boston College World Bank 30 April, 1996 Abstract A simple general equilibrium model of an economy with distortionary taxes and public goods is used to extend, unify and clean up the welfare analysis of changes in taxation, redistribution and the provision of public goods. We clarify the distinction between compensation and money metric measures of the welfare impact of fiscal changes and show that the equivalent variation measure dominates other measures. We provide an integrated approach to marginal tax and public good changes when public goods have real resource costs and must be financed by distortionary taxation using the concepts of the marginal cost of funds, the fiscal price of public goods and the virtual price of public goods. Here too, the compensation version of these concepts dominates the money metric version. An earlier version of this paper was presented to the Mid-West International Economics Meetings, Fall, 1993. University of Wisconsin, Madison, September 10-12, 1993. JEL Classification: H21, H40 Keywords: marginal cost of funds, fiscal price, virtual price, duality. Correspondence to: James E. Anderson, Dept. of Economics, Boston College, Chestnut Hill MA 02167 The Welfare Analysis of Fiscal Policy The literature on the welfare impact of tax changes and public goods changes is a formidable thicket of different methods (primal vs. dual), results from special cases (initial undistorted equilibrium, lump sum distribution, additively separable public goods) and loose claims about approximation. There are distinct and consequential differences in the methods advocated in the literature, with no obvious reason to select one over the others.
    [Show full text]
  • Threshold Concepts in Economics: Implications for Teaching, Learning and Assessment
    The Handbook for Economics Lecturers Threshold Concepts in Economics: implications for teaching, learning and assessment Peter Davies and Jean Mangan, Institute for Education Policy Research, The Business School, Staffordshire University 1 Introduction 2 2 Threshold concepts 3 3 Implications: four principles for teaching and learning 7 4 The teaching and learning activities 9 5 Case study 12 6 Assessment 14 7 Where next? 18 Acknowledgement 19 References 19 Appendices 1 Reflective Exercise Example: Taxing imports – what’s the problem? 20 2 Problem Focused Exercise Example: Cruise Ship Pollution – an economic problem? 25 3 Threshold Network Exercise Example: Taxation during recession 29 The Handbook for Economics Lecturers 1 Introduction This chapter provides an introduction to the work on threshold concepts in economics and the teaching and learning materials developed within the Embedding Threshold Concepts project. This Fund for the Development of Teaching and Learning project was led by Staffordshire University with Coventry, Durham and the West of England Universities as partners. There is evidence from various sources that many students in economics ‘acquire’ a set of concepts but this has little impact on the way that they experience economic phenomena. Many struggle to apply concepts to new situations in their work or personal life. The majority of lecturers can identify students who are struggling with underpinning theory and resort to verbatim learning of isolated aspects of the subject. Frank (1998, p.14), for example, writes of a particular manifestation of these problems: ‘..... most students leave the introductory course never having fully grasped the essence of microeconomics. Thus, the opportunity cost concept, so utterly central to our understanding of what it means to think like an economist, is but one among hundreds of other concepts that go by in a blur.’ There is already a considerable body of work, for example in the other chapters in the Economics Network Handbook series and in the books by Becker and Watts (1998) and Becker et al.
    [Show full text]