Before and After the COVID-19 Pandemic

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Before and After the COVID-19 Pandemic The Trade & Government Procurement Policy Nexus: Before and After The COVID-19 Pandemic Simon J. Evenett1 University of St. Gallen2 and the St. Gallen Endowment for Prosperity Through Trade3 21 December 2020 To be published in In Sue Arrowsmith, Luke Butler & Christopher Yukins (eds.) Public Procurement in (a) Crisis: global lessons from the COVID-19 pandemic. Hart Publishing. 2021. 1 The author thanks Professor Sue Arrowsmith and Robert Anderson for comments on an earlier version of this chapter 2 Professor of International Trade & Economic Development. Email address: [email protected]. 3 Founder of the new non-profit Foundation to house the Global Trade Alert and other commercial policy- related initiatives. I. Introduction Since being declared a pandemic by the World Health Organization on 11 March 2020, COVID- 19 has spread to every continent. There has been an attendant surge in demand for medical goods, medical equipment, and medicines. That public sector organisations are responsible for sourcing these essential items implicates government procurement policy. That patterns of international specialisation imply that sourcing can come from abroad implicates trade policy. The COVID-19 pandemic amounts to nothing less than a major stress test for the extant trade and government policy nexus. How well did current institutional arrangements and practices fare? If the statements of senior policymakers in the major trading powers are to be believed, the curt answer is: Not well at all. Should policymakers’ words translate into deeds then there could be implications for national procurement policies, for the conduct of unilateral trade policy, and for the negotiation and possible renegotiation of relevant provisions in regional trade agreements and for the plurilateral Agreement on Government Procurement (GPA) at the World Trade Organization (WTO). Nine months into the pandemic the purpose of this chapter is to reflect on the implications of this stress test for the trade and government procurement nexus. Drawing on data collected on government policy response and on the recent analyses of others, this chapter will ask whether current arrangements and practices are fit for purpose. If not, why not? Do any deficiencies reflect lacunae, blind spots, or implicit assumptions that turned out to be false? Perhaps any failings reflect the fact that the extant nexus was not designed to cope with pandemics in the first place? It is not claimed that these observations are the final word—after all, at the time of writing (December 2020) there is no end in sight for the pandemic. Two thoroughly tested vaccines have been approved but global distribution of vaccines has barely begun. The remainder of this chapter proceeds as follows. The next section describes the organising logic of what is termed the trade and procurement policy nexus before the pandemic hit. As will become evident, this logic had three important consequences which were to come to light once the pandemic results in a surge in demand for medical kit. The third section of this chapter describes the initial trade policy responses as governments scrambled to source medical kit and the consequences for the international supply chains implicated. The backlash against those supply chains that followed and its consequences for the trade and government procurement nexus is discussed in the fourth section. The concluding section of this chapter draws out three root causes that must be faced if a more effective trade and government procurement nexus is to be designed. II. The Trade & Procurement Policy Nexus before the Pandemic This section describes the organising logic and consequences of the inter-relationship between trade and government procurement policies before the COVID-19 pandemic. Although it refers to a nexus this does not mean to imply that there is a global accord or understanding concerning the relationship between these two policies. Nor it is implied that the better practices that follow 2 of 16 have been implemented everywhere. Rather the goal is to describe how this nexus was supposed to work and then to highlight three facets of that nexus that were ultimately cast in a poor light as the pandemic unfolded. The starting point is the assumption, as discussed in chapter 2, that value for money in public procurement is best achieved through competitive tendering processes. For those goods and services where cross-border supply is technically feasible, suppliers based abroad are a potentially valuable source of competition. It follows that public purchasing policies and practices should be adopted that encourage bids from suitably qualified foreign firms. In turn this has implications for the transparency of public procurement procedures (including the publication of tender announcements in international languages, such as English) and for due process rights of bidders, as again was discussed in chapter 2. It also implies eschewing price preferences, bans on sourcing from any group of technically qualified bidders, and other forms of discrimination.4 Trade policy can be aligned with this logic as well. Governments can commit not to charge import tariffs on goods sold to public bodies. They could also refuse to undertake anti-dumping and countervailing duty investigations against foreign bidders for state contracts. Regional trade agreements can be signed that reduce or eliminate discrimination against foreign bidders, locking in what trade diplomats refer to as ‘market access’ to public procurement systems.5 The range of public bodies covered by those market access ‘disciplines’ can be negotiated as well. On this logic, greater coverage of public bodies in trade accords is better. Similar initiatives have been undertaken by the members of the plurilateral GPA.6 4 The international dimension to public procurement processes are handily described and assessed in the contributions to A Georgopoulous, B Hoekman, and P Mavroidis, (eds) The Internationalization of Government Procurement Regulation (New York, Oxford University Press, 2018). A factual overview of the size of national public procurement markets and the means that governments deploy to favour locally-based firms can be found in J Goudron and J Messent, ‘How Government Procurement Measures Can Affect Trade’ (2019) 53 Journal of World Trade 679. 5 For an overview of government procurement provisions in regional trade agreements see R Anderson, A Müller, K Osei-Lah, J de Leon, and P Pelletier, ‘Government procurement provisions in regional trade agreements: a stepping stone to GPA Accession?’ in S Arrowsmith and R Anderson (eds) The WTO Regime on Government Procurement: Challenge and Reform (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 2011). For a finding that after competition policy provisions, among other behind-the-border policies it is the government procurement provisions of regional trade agreements that have the largest positive effect on the level of bilateral trade see K Hayakawa, F Kimura, and K Nabeshima, ‘Nonconventional Provisions in Regional Trade Agreements: Do They Enhance International Trade?’ (2014) 17 Journal of Applied Economics 113. 6 For a timely account of the flexibilities available to members of the GPA, a subject also discussed in chapter xx of the present volume, see R Anderson and A Müller, ‘Keeping Markets Open While ensuring Due Flexibility for Governments in a Time of Economic and Public Health Crisis: The Role of the WTO Agreement on Government Procurement (GPA)’ (2020) 29 Public Procurement Law Review 189. For assessments of the working of the GPA before the pandemic see R Anderson and N Sporysheva, ‘The Revised WTO Agreement on Government Procurement: Evolving Global Footprint, Economic Impact and Policy Significance’ (2019) 28 Public Procurement Law Review 71, B Hoekman, ‘Reducing Home Bias in 3 of 16 At this point in the argument three considerations that are implicit in, or that arise from, the organising logic described immediately above should be emphasised. The first observation is that it is only the public sector practices of the importing jurisdiction that mattered. When sourcing occurs from abroad no consideration was given in the argument above to the government policies of the nations where firms export from. To the extent that international trade agreements included provisions on government procurement, the ‘problem’ being tackled was the behaviour of the importing nation’s government, not the policies of exporting nations. The second observation is that, according to this organising logic, one advantage of sourcing from abroad is that it is risk reducing. Cross-border sourcing is seen as particularly valuable if there is a sharp, unexpected reduction in the capacity of domestic or locally-based firms to supply goods to public bodies. From the perspective of any one government, the option to source from abroad was seen as a plus. The consequences of other governments having the same option was either overlooked or known but regarded as unimportant. The third observation is that, to the extent that the emphasis on value for money results in intense price-based competition bidding firms have strong incentives to keep costs as low as possible. Private sector firms designed and executed supply chains based on so called Just In Time principles in response to these incentives. Those supply chains typically involve constituent firms holding few inventories of parts, components, and final produced goods as well as maintaining as little redundant production capacity as possible. The goal here is not to denounce this organising logic—the author has based policy recommendations on this logic many times in the past and is yet to be persuaded by an alternative logic.7 Instead, as is argued in the next section, the pandemic has rudely called into question the validity of the three observations outlined immediately above. III. The Initial Trade Policy Response to the Pandemic In many nations governments are directly responsible for the supply of public health services. In those nations where private sector provision of health care is the norm, the state is still seen as having overall responsibility for public health.
Recommended publications
  • Chapter 2 New Challenges to the Export Oriented Growth Model
    Chapter 2 New Challenges to the Export Oriented Growth Model Song Hong Institute of World Economics and Politics (IWEP), Chinese Academy of Social Sciences (CASS) December 2012 This chapter should be cited as Song, H. (2012), ‘New Challenges to the Export Oriented Growth Model’, in Zhang, Y., F. Kimura and S. Oum (eds.), Moving Toward a New Development Model for East Asia- The Role of Domestic Policy and Regional Cooperation . ERIA Research Project Report 2011-10, Jakarta: ERIA. pp.27-54. CHAPTER 2 New Challenges to the Export Oriented Growth Model SONG HONG Institute of World Economics and Politics (IWEP), Chinese Academy of Social Sciences (CASS) The export-oriented strategy played a crucial role for the successful development of East Asian economies after the World War II. They first exported low-technology manufactured goods, then gradually upgraded and transformed their export goods packages and finally caught up with the developed countries. Export oriented strategy in East Asia has been based on a series of internal and external conditions. Those conditions includes an open international environment, the existence of a certain size of external market, a stable supply of raw materials, as well as good and convenient navigation, and some internal conditions. Global financial crisis badly changed some of these conditions. For example, the external market was very unstable and was growing very slow; after the financial crisis, international raw material and energy prices experienced sharp volatility, which caused great challenges to the countries and enterprises seeking to implement an export oriented strategy. However, after the financial crisis the changes in international and domestic environments did not change the nature and trends of globalization, only temporarily slowed the pace of this process.
    [Show full text]
  • Innovation in E-Procurement: the Italian Experience E-Government Series
    IBM Business Consulting Services Innovation in e-procurement: the Italian experience e-government series Prepared for the IBM Centre for the Business of Government Mita Marra Research Fellow Institute for the Study of Mediterranean Societies Italian National Research Council November 2004 3 Innovation in e-procurement The Italian experience Contents Page 5 Foreword Page 6 Executive Summary Page 10 Introduction Page 14 From Supply-Side to Demand-Side E-Procurement • What Is Consip? • The Urge to Rationalise Public Spending as the Driver for Centralised Procurement • The Shift to Decentralisation • The Spillover of Consip Experience at the Local and International Levels Page 30 Toward Enhanced Customisation of Public Procurement • Adopting IT Services: The Issues of Compatibility and Complexity • Addressing the Legal Challenges Domestically and at the European Level • Managing Contracts at the Agency Level and the Need for Tailored Capacity Building • Opening Up to Competition and Levelling the Playing Field for Large and Small Suppliers Page 41 Findings and Recommendations • Findings • Recommendations Page 47 Appendices • Appendix I: Analytical Framework, Research Design, and Methods • Appendix II: The Case of SIEP in the Province of Salerno, Italy Page 56 End notes Page 57 Bibliography Page 60 About the Author Page 61 Key Contact Information Page 62 Centre Reports Available 3 Innovation in e-procurement The Italian experience 5 Innovation in e-procurement The Italian experience Foreword November 2004 On behalf of the IBM Centre for The Business of Government, we are pleased to present this report, ‘Innovation in e-procurement: The Italian Experience,’ by Mita Marra. This publication is the first in a new series of reports that the IBM Centre for The Business of Government will publish examining public-sector innovation in Europe.
    [Show full text]
  • Are You Ready for Eprocurement? Guide to Electronic Procurement Reform
    Are you ready for eProcurement? Guide to Electronic Procurement Reform Are you ready for eProcurement? Guide to Electronic Procurement Reform Are you ready for eProcurement? Guide to Electronic Procurement Reform 2015 Are you ready for eProcurement? Guide to Electronic Procurement Reform 4 Preface Electronic procurement in the public sector (eProcurement) is the business-to-government tendering and sale of goods, services and works through online platforms as well as other networking systems, such as electronic data interchange and procurement planning facilities. Typically, eProcurement solutions allow for registered and qualified economic operators – suppliers and contractors active in the market – to compete for public contracts in response to tenders published online by contracting entities. In essence, eProcurement replaces traditional bureaucratic paper-based public procurement procedures with interactive online processes (online e-tendering and reverse e-auctions) making procurement processes accessible to all interested suppliers and contractors, uniform, less time consuming and cheaper for all stakeholders. In 2010 the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD), through its Legal Transition Programme, conducted an assessment of public procurement regulatory frameworks in the EBRD countries of operations. The assessment highlighted that much of the recorded “success stories” in public procurement reforms was linked to the implementation of electronic procurement and that since the 2008 financial crisis governments’
    [Show full text]
  • PDF Hosted at the Radboud Repository of the Radboud University Nijmegen
    PDF hosted at the Radboud Repository of the Radboud University Nijmegen The following full text is a publisher's version. For additional information about this publication click this link. http://hdl.handle.net/2066/32054 Please be advised that this information was generated on 2021-10-02 and may be subject to change. THE CONTINUOUS RELEVANCE OF THE NATION- STATE THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY IN EGYPT De voortdurende relevantie van de natie-staat De politieke economie van de farmaceutische industrie in Egypte Een wetenschappelijke proeve op het gebied van de Sociale wetenschappen Proefschrift ter verkrijging van de graad van doctor aan de Radboud Universiteit Nijmegen op gezag van de rector magnificus prof. mr. S.C.J.J Kortmann, volgens besluit van het College van Decanen in het openbaar te verdedigen op maandag 14 januari 2008 om 13.30 uur precies door Arsalan Alshinawi geboren op 02 oktober 1964 te Baghdad Promotor: Prof. dr. Robert H. Lieshout Copromotor: Dr. Wil Hout, International Institute of Social Studies, Den Haag Manuscriptcommissie: Prof. dr. Harry Garretsen, Universiteit van Utrecht Prof. dr. Mohamed Salih, International Institute of Social Studies, Den Haag Prof. dr. Bertjan Verbeek THE CONTINUOUS RELEVANCE OF THE NATION-STATE THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY IN EGYPT An academic essay in Social Sciences Doctoral Thesis To obtain the degree of Doctor from Radboud University Nijmegen, on the authority of the Rector Magnificus, Prof. dr. S.C.J.J. Kortmann, according to the decision of the Council of Deans, to be defended on Monday 14 January, 2008 at 13:30 hrs By ARSALAN ALSHINAWI Born in Baghdad, on 02 October 1964 Doctoral Supervisor: Prof.
    [Show full text]
  • Strategic Economics of Network Industries
    STRATEC Economics of Network Industries Hans W. Gottinger Part A: Network Economics 1. Introduction In traditional industries the economic model conventionally used to estimate the market function is perfect competition. Perfect competition theory assumes that individual economic agents have no market power . The agents in the economy are price takers. It is generally believed that competition will drive the market price down to the competitive level (equal to the marginal costs) and consumer welfare is improved through allocative and production efficiencies. The perfect competition or nearly perfect market is remised on the assumption in a market containing many equally efficient firms, each firm in the market faces a perfectly horizontal demand curve for a homogeneous product, and that firms freely enter or exit the industry. It is against this benchmark that network industries are a world apart. In their markets products are heterogeneous, differentiation in products is common, the life cycles of products are short, sunk cost is significant, innovation is essential and sometimes 'only the paranoid survive' (A. Grove). In some industries only a handful of participants are in the market and the dominant firms may easily raise the barriers of market entry to exclude competitors. In other words, in network industries, markets usually involve enormous capital and highly risky investment, economies of scale, intensive and interdependent technologies owned by different market players, network externalities of products, and tendency of product standardization. In view of this, market failures in those industries appear significant. In this chapter I give a fairly extensive characterization of network industries and discuss some of the policy conclusions 2.
    [Show full text]
  • The Revised Wto Agreement on Government Procurement (Gpa): Key Design Features and Significance for Global Trade and Development
    ARTICLES THE REVISED WTO AGREEMENT ON GOVERNMENT PROCUREMENT (GPA): KEY DESIGN FEATURES AND SIGNIFICANCE FOR GLOBAL TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT ROBERT D. ANDERSON AND ANNA CAROLINE MULLER¨ * ABSTRACT The World Trade Organization’s (WTO’s) plurilateral Agreement on Govern­ ment Procurement (GPA or “the Agreement”) is an important ongoing success story for the Organization. In the spring of 2012, the GPA Parties completed a full revision of the Agreement, with regard to both its text and market access commitments under it. Since then, the revised GPA has entered into force, and its membership has gradually broadened. These developments are of importance not only in themselves, but also for the international trading system and its potential future evolution. The GPA’s successful renegotiation, the continuing growth of its membership, and its vitality as an instrument of public policy were not achieved through happenstance. This Article discusses a number of specific design features of the GPA that clearly facilitated the successful conclusion of the renegotiation and that, as such, may in the future be relevant to other areas of global trade liberalization. In addition to the Agreement’s plurilateral nature, of particular interest are the approach taken with respect to application of the most-favored­ nation treatment (MFN) principle in the Agreement; the GPA’s continuing strong emphasis on principles of reciprocity in market access concessions; and its * Robert D. Anderson: Counsellor and Team Leader for Government Procurement and Competition Policy, Intellectual Property, Government Procurement and Competition Division, WTO Secretariat; Honorary Professor, School of Law, University of Nottingham, UK; External Faculty Member, World Trade Institute, University of Bern, Switzerland.
    [Show full text]
  • Government Procurement: Market Access, Transparency, and Multilateral Trade Rules*
    Government Procurement: Market Access, Transparency, and Multilateral Trade Rules* Simon J. Evenett World Trade Institute and CEPR Hallerstrasse 6, 3012 Berne, Switzerland [email protected] and Bernard M. Hoekman World Bank and CEPR 1818 H Street NW, Washington DC 20433, USA [email protected] Revised October 2002 Abstract: The effects on national welfare and market access of two important public procurement practices (discrimination and non-transparency) are analyzed with an eye to the ongoing international discussions on procurement reform in the Doha Round as well as regional integration agreements. The analysis suggests that the welfare payoffs of adopting mechanisms that foster domestic competition and transparency are likely to be greater than the return to efforts to ban international discrimination. However, improved transparency is unlikely to result in significant enhancements in market access, which in turn raises questions about the likely enforceability of a WTO transparency agreement. Keywords: Government procurement, public purchasing, WTO, transparency, corruption, Doha Round JEL classification: F13, H57 * We are grateful to Richard Baldwin, Fernando Branco, Aaditya Mattoo, Marcelo Olarreaga, Garry Pursell, David Tarr and participants in seminars and workshops at the World Bank, CEPR, and the Brookings Institution for helpful comments and discussions on earlier versions of this paper. The views expressed are personal and should not be attributed to the World Bank. Government Procurement: Market Access, Transparency, and Multilateral Trade Rules Simon J. Evenett and Bernard M. Hoekman Introduction With the conclusion of the Uruguay Round and the creation of the World Trade Organization (WTO), multilateral disciplines applying to all WTO members were established in many areas.
    [Show full text]
  • Changing Commercial Policy in Japan During 1985–2010
    ADBI Working Paper Series Changing Commercial Policy in Japan During 1985–2010 Masahiro Kawai and Shujiro Urata No. 253 November 2010 Asian Development Bank Institute Masahiro Kawai is the Dean of ADBI. Shujiro Urata is Professor of Economics, Graduate School of Asia-Pacific Studies, Waseda University. This paper is prepared for the Oxford Handbook on International Commercial Policy. The authors are grateful to Mordechai Kreinin and Michael Plummer for their comments on an earlier version of the paper and to Barnard Helman for his competent editorial assistance. The views expressed in this paper are the views of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views or policies of ADBI, the Asian Development Bank (ADB), its Board of Directors, or the governments they represent. ADBI does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this paper and accepts no responsibility for any consequences of their use. Terminology used may not necessarily be consistent with ADB official terms. The Working Paper series is a continuation of the formerly named Discussion Paper series; the numbering of the papers continued without interruption or change. ADBI’s working papers reflect initial ideas on a topic and are posted online for discussion. ADBI encourages readers to post their comments on the main page for each working paper (given in the citation below). Some working papers may develop into other forms of publication. Suggested citation: Kawai. M., and S. Urata. 2010. Changing Commercial Policy in Japan During 1985–2010. ADBI Working Paper 253. Tokyo: Asian Development Bank Institute. Available: http://www.adbi.org/working-paper/2010/11/19/4220.changing.commercial.policy.japan/ Please contact the author(s) for information about this paper.
    [Show full text]
  • International Aspects of U.S. Government Procurement
    International Aspects of U.S. Government Procurement Erin Felix Government Contracts Attorney National Contract Management Association- San Diego Chapter Luis F. Arandia, Jr. March 12, 2020 International Trade and Customs Attorney Overview • Export Controls & Sanctions Basics • EAR & ITAR General Overview • Encryption & Huawei Controls • OFAC Sanctions • Trade Agreement Issues • BAA / TAA / Berry • USMCA & Tariffs • Other Supply Chain Issues • FARS/DFARS Prohibitions Export Controls Basics Overview of U.S. Government Export Laws • Exports are highly controlled for various reasons • National Security • Trade Secrets • Statistics Who Controls U.S. Exports? U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Industry and Security (BIS) • Export Administration Regulations (EAR) • Dual-use items and lower level military • Commerce Control List (CCL) U.S. Department of State, Directorate of Defense Trade Controls (DDTC) • International Traffic in Arms Regulations (ITAR) • Defense articles, or items • United States Munitions List (USML) Who Controls U.S. Exports? Homeland Security, U.S. Customs and Border Protection • “Police” the borders • Enforce exports at all U.S. borders Department of Commerce, Census Bureau • Collects and reports trade statistics Department of Treasury, Office of Foreign Assets Control • Enforces U.S. mandated embargoes and sanctions Structure of the EAR and ITAR • The Export Administration Regulations (EAR) • 15 CFR Parts 730-744 • Commerce Control List (CCL) • The International Traffic in Arms Regulations (ITAR) • 22 CFR Parts 120-130 • U.S. Munitions List (USML) EAR • Dual Use Goods • Commercial items that can also be used in a military application • “600” series items • ITAR controlled items that moved to the EAR as a result of export control reform • Require a license or exemption to export ITAR • Hardware • Rockets, fighter jets, body armor, etc.
    [Show full text]
  • Trade, Trade Policy and Industrialization Reconsidered
    UNU World Institute for Development Economics Research (UNU/WIDER) World Development Studies 6 Trade, Trade Policy and Industrialization Reconsidered G. K. Helleiner UNU World Institute for Development Economics Research (UNU/WIDER) A research and training centre of the United Nations University The Board of UNU/WIDER Philip Ndegwa Sylvia Ostry Maria de Lourdes Pintasilgo, Chairperson Antti Tanskanen George Vassiliou Ruben Yevstigneyev Masaru Yoshitomi Ex Officio Heitor Gurgulino de Souza, Rector of UNU Mihaly Simai, Director of UNU/WIDER UNU World Institute for Development Economics Research (UNU/WIDER) was established by the United Nations University as its first research and training centre and started work in Helsinki, Finland, in 1985. The principal purpose of the Institute is policy-oriented research on the main strategic issues of development and international cooperation, as well as on the interaction between domestic and global changes. Its work is carried out by staff researchers and visiting scholars in Helsinki and through networks of collaborating institutions and scholars around the world. UNU World Institute for Development Economics Research (UNU/WIDER) Katajanokanlaituri 6 B 00160 Helsinki, Finland Copyright © UNU World Institute for Development Economics Research (UNU/WIDER) Cover photograph: Town and Oil Refinery, Minatitlan, Mexico, by Alex Webb, Magnum Photos, copyright Finnish Press Agency Camera-ready typescript prepared by Liisa Roponen at UNU/WIDER Printed at KP Paino, 1995 The views expressed in this publication
    [Show full text]
  • E-Procurement Final Document
    Edited Version This volume was edited by Maria Fiore, Valeria Russo, Mauro Bucci, Ottavio Janni and Aidan McCann. Under the supervision of Giuseppe Pennella Director, C.A.I.MED (Centre for Administrative Innovation in the euro-Mediterranean Region), Head of Research and Development – Formez. Final edits and formatting for English publication: OECD. 2 PRESENTATION OF THE VOLUME E-Government – of which e-procurement is an integral part – is one of the most valuable ICT-based administrative innovation reforms; it can render public policy more effective, efficient and responsive to social and political needs. The two World Summits on Information Society organised by the United Nations demonstrated how public e-procurement, as part of an e-government strategy, can play a fundamental role in achieving good governance. Through its Initiative on e-Government and ICT for Development, Italy played a crucial role in these events. Additionally, e-procurement reinforces one of the fundamental rules of information and communication technologies: technological and organisational aspects must be linked within the overall innovation process. The Seminar discussions showed that changes in public procurement management – facilitated and promoted by the use of ICT – embrace both technological innovations and organisational and cultural transformations, especially with regard to know-how and practical skills. Italian institutions like Formez (Study and Training Centre) and C.A.I.MED. (Centre for Administrative Innovation in the Euro-Mediterranean Region) have worked with local, national and international public administrations in support of public policies for cohesion and development to achieve excellent, widely published results. Projects have focused on training, experimentation/assistance, applied research, creation of Communities of Practice, diffusion/reinterpretation of best practices and benchmarking.
    [Show full text]
  • Government Procurement Agreement
    - 7 - AGREEMENT ON GOVERNMENT PROCUREMENT Parties to this Agreement (hereinafter referred to as "Parties"), Recognizing the need for an effective multilateral framework of rights and obligations with respect to laws, regulations, procedures and practices regarding government procurement with a view to achieving greater liberalization and expansion of world trade and improving the international framework for the conduct of world trade; Recognizing that laws, regulations, procedures and practices regarding government procurement should not be prepared, adopted or applied to foreign or domestic products and services and to foreign or domestic suppliers so as to afford protection to domestic products or services or domestic suppliers and should not discriminate among foreign products or services or among foreign suppliers; Recognizing that it is desirable to provide transparency of laws, regulations, procedures and practices regarding government procurement; Recognizing the need to establish international procedures on notification, consultation, surveillance and dispute settlement with a view to ensuring a fair, prompt and effective enforcement of the international provisions on government procurement and to maintain the balance of rights and obligations at the highest possible level; Recognizing the need to take into account the development, financial and trade needs of developing countries, in particular the least-developed countries; Desiring, in accordance with paragraph 6(b) of Article IX of the Agreement on Government Procurement done on 12 April 1979, as amended on 2 February 1987, to broaden and improve the Agreement on the basis of mutual reciprocity and to expand the coverage of the Agreement to include service contracts; Desiring to encourage acceptance of and accession to this Agreement by governments not party to it; Having undertaken further negotiations in pursuance of these objectives; Hereby agree as follows: - 8 - Article I Scope and Coverage 1.
    [Show full text]