Climatic Change and Fisheries Management

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Climatic Change and Fisheries Management Volume 23 Issue 1 Winter 1983 Winter 1983 Climatic Change and Fisheries Management Ricahrd Frye Recommended Citation Ricahrd Frye, Climatic Change and Fisheries Management, 23 Nat. Resources J. 77 (1983). Available at: https://digitalrepository.unm.edu/nrj/vol23/iss1/7 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Law Journals at UNM Digital Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Natural Resources Journal by an authorized editor of UNM Digital Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected], [email protected], [email protected]. Richard Frye* Climatic Change and Fisheries Management' INTRODUCTION Human economic activity has been susceptible to climatic change throughout history and may have been responsible for changes in regional micro-climates through deforestation, overgrazing, and desertification. Recently, the scientific community has devoted considerable attention to investigating the possibility that human activity is likely to have global climatic consequences. Of particular concern are the effects of carbon dioxide accumulation due to the combustion of carbon-based fuels,' and the additional effects of trace gases2 and aerosols released into the at- mosphere by human activity. This paper investigates the possible economic impacts of climatic change on world fisheries by tracing the relationships among climatic change, ocean circulation, fisheries ecology, and fisheries management. Section 1 summarizes the mechanisms by which scientists expect carbon dioxide (CO2) accumulation in the atmosphere to induce global climatic change. Section 2 investigates the possible implications of C0 2-induced climatic change for ocean circulation patterns. Section 3 considers how changes in ocean circulation may affect productivity of marine ecosystems. Section 4 addresses the potential management implications of C0 2-induced per- turbations of marine fisheries. 1. CO2 AND ATMOSPHERIC CIRCULATION The concentration of CO 2 in the atmosphere has increased continuously from 315 parts per million by volume (ppmv) in 1958, when regular measurement began, to 334 ppmv in 1979, and is currently increasing at about 1.5 ppmv per year at current rates of fossil fuel combustion. In contrast, scientists estimate that preindustrial atmospheric concentration *Ph.D. in Economics, Bellingham, Washington. tThis article was supported with funds from the National Science Foundation. Research for the article was performed at Batelle Pacific Northwest Laboratories in Richmond, Washington, while the author was an Assistant Professor at Huxley College of Environmental Studies, Western Wash- ington University, Bellingham, Washington. 1. COUNCIL ON ENVIRONMENTAL QUALITY, GLOBAL ENERGY FUTURES AND THE CARBON DIOXIDE PROBLEM (1981). 2. Toon & Pollack, Atmospheric Aerosols and Climate, 68 AM. SCIENTIST 268 (1980). NATURAL RESOURCES JOURNAL [Vol. 23 3 of CO 2 was about 290 ppmv. Future concentrations of C02 will depend on the magnitude of carbon sources and sinks4 over time, and particularly on the cumulative levels of combustion of organic fuels. Accumulation of CO 2 affects climate directly and through the ampli- fying effects of a number of feedback mechanisms.' The primary climatic consequence of CO 2 accumulation is the so-called "greenhouse" effect: CO2 is transparent to incoming shortwave solar radiation, but absorbs outgoing terrestrial, infrared radiation, causing a heating of the lower atmosphere. A primary feedback mechanism occurs as a result of in- creased evaporation, humidity, and sensible and latent heat flux,6 which increase atmospheric warming, effectively doubling the temperature in- crease that would be anticipated from CO 2 absorption alone. A second important positive feedback mechanism occurs as atmo- spheric warming increases the melting of polar snow and ice, thereby reducing the reflectivity of the planetary surface, and increasing the amount of solar radiation absorbed. This snow-ice albedo7 feedback mechanism could add about another 40 percent to the temperature effect of CO2 alone." Some scientists anticipate that the combined effects of infrared ab- sorption, latent heat feedback, and ice-albedo feedback associated with a doubling of preindustrial CO2 concentrations will result in an average global warming of about 2.4 degrees Centigrade (C). A number of in- dependent studies using global climate simulation models and other tech- niques support these figures.9 Climate researchers generally agree that a doubling of atmospheric CO2 will lead to an average global temperature 3. NATIONAL RESEARCH COUNCIL CLIMATE RESEARCH BOARD, CARBON DIOX- IDE AND CLIMATE: REPORT OF AN AD HOC STUDY GROUP ON CARBON DIOXIDE AND CLIMATE, NATIONAL ACADEMY OF SCIENCES (1979) [hereinafter cited as NATIONAL RE- SEARCH COUNCIL]; Watts, Climate Models and C0 2-induced Climate Change, 2 CLIMATE CHANGE 387 (1980). 4. Carbon continuously cycles through the environment in a variety of forms. Of particular interest to climate researchers are the processes by which carbon enters the atmosphere (carbon sources to the atmosphere) and leaves the atmosphere (carbon sinks). 5. Positive feedback occurs when atmospheric warming initiates a sequence of events which amplify the initial warming. Negative feedback occurs if atmospheric warning causes events which lead to atmospheric cooling, reducing the impact of the initial warming. 6. Sensible heat flux is heat transport associated with warming and movement of the air mass; latent heat flux is atmospheric heat transport associated with evaporation and cooling at one location, with subsequent movement of water vapor and condensation and warming at other locations. 7. Planetary albedo measures the fraction of incident solar radiation reflected by the planetary surface. 8. NATIONAL RESEARCH COUNCIL, supra note 3. 9. Useful summaries of several climate modeling experiments are given in: Washington, Climate Responses Due to Increased C02 : Status of Model Experiment and the Possible Role of the Oceans, in U.S. DEP'T OF ENERGY, PROCEEDINGS OF THE CO 2 AND CLIMATE RESEARCH PRO- GRAM CONFERENCE (1980) [hereinafter cited as U.S. DEP'T OF ENERGY, PROCEEDINGS]. See also Watts, supra note 3. January 1983] CLIMATIC CHANGE AND FISHERIES MANAGEMENT increase of 2-4'C at low and mid-latitudes, magnified by a factor of three to four (10-12C) in polar regions.' 0 Cloud and ocean interaction feedbacks from C0 2-induced warming have not yet been successfully incorporated into climate simulation models. Increasing cloudiness at low and middle altitudes could produce a neg- ative, or cooling feedback, while an increase in high-altitude cloudiness could result in a positive, warming feedback effect. Atmosphere-ocean feedbacks include important regional climatic effects of fast western boundary currents like the Gulf Stream, dissolution of CO 2 into the oceans at the air-sea interface, and equatorial upwelling. " Heat exchange among the atmosphere, surface, and mixed and deep layers of the ocean,' 2 and the interactive effects of winds on these processes and on ocean circulation may also affect climatic conditions. Accurate modeling of ocean circu- lation will be necessary before scientists are able to predict future climatic change on a regional basis.' 3 A fundamental problem with assessing the future impacts of C0 2- induced climatic change is inadequate understanding of the global carbon cycle. Not only are sources of CO 2 from human activity subject to con- siderable variation in response to social and economic variables; at the same time the disposition of CO2 in the atmosphere, oceans, and biosphere remains poorly understood. Data available since about 1950 suggest that tropical forests have probably been a large net source of CO 2. In contrast, agriculture and grassland soils have probably been a small net source, while forests and soils in temperate zones have been moderate net sinks. As a result, the biosphere is thought to have been a minor net source of CO2 since 1950. " Future projections of CO 2 concentration are uncertain, not only because information and understanding of the carbon cycle are limited, but also because the terrestrial carbon cycle is highly susceptible to perturbations by human activity. Management of forests, wetlands, water resources, 10. The Arctic will display a substantially higher temperature increase than the Antarctic, primarily due to the greater southern ocean area and the much greater thickness and stability of Antarctic ice. 11. Wind stress over water induces motion of surface waters (Ekman transport) perpendicular to wind direction. At the equator, prevailing trade winds cause surface waters to move northward in the Northern Hemisphere, southward in the Southern Hemisphere. This divergence of equatorial surface waters effectively pumps cooler, deeper water to the surface near the equator, cooling the atmosphere. See text, infra, accompanying note 30. 12. Surface action caused by winds, tides, currents, etc., "mixes" the ocean near the surface. Deeper water, below this layer of interaction, tends to be much more stable than the mixed layer with respect to velocity, temperature, and salinity. 13. WORLD METEROLOGICAL ORGANIZATION, GLOBAL ATMOSPHERIC RESEARCH PROJECT, THE PHYSICAL BASIS OF CLIMATE AND CLIMATE MODELING, GARP PUB. SERIES NO. 16 (1975) [hereinafter cited as G.A.R.P.]. 14. Loucks, Recent Resultsfrom Studies of Carbon Cycling in the Atmosphere, in CO 2 and Climate Research, supra note 9. NATURAL RESOURCES JOURNAL [Vol. 23 agriculture, energy resources,
Recommended publications
  • Economics and the Resumption of Commercial Whaling
    WORKSHOP IN POLITICAL THEORY AND POLICY ANALYSIS 613 NORTH PARK INDIANA UNIVERSITY BLOOMINGTON, IN 47408-3695 U.SLA, Economics and the Resumption of Commercial Whaling by Jon Conrad and Trend BjomdaT The authors are Professors at Cornell University and the Norwegian School of Economics and Business Administration, respectively. Economics and the Resumption of Commercial Whaling ,..,„.. , :vr<; *Yi ABSTRACT " X •"•,'/! .1;>'A7; • There is now strong scientific evidence that several species of baleen whale and possibly the sperm whale, have recovered to levels that would support commercial harvest. The stock of fin whales (Balaenoptera physalus) off the eastern coast of Iceland and the minke whale (Balaenoptera acutorostrata) in the Northeast Atlantic, off the coast of Japan and in the Southern Ocean are prime candidates for commercial harvest. Should commercial whaling be resumed? If so, what role should economics play in determining the level of harvest and management policies? A bioeconomic model for baleen whales is developed and applied to the stock of minke whales in the Northeast Atlantic. A delay- difference equation is used to model the population dynamics and an exponential production function is estimated relating harvest, to population size and the number of catcher vessels. If whaling is resumed, the optimal stock size and harvest may critically depend on the price-cost ratio and catcher productivity. We identify plausible combinations of price, cost and productivity where whaling is not optimal and the minke whale population in the Northeast Atlantic equilibrates at about 82,000 adult animals. Under a high price-cost ratio and high catcher productivity, the optimal stock ranges from 51,000 to 59,000 whales supporting a harvest of 1,600 to 1,750 whales by 90 to 115 catchers.
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Incentives and Overfishing: a Bioeconomic Vulnerability Index
    Vol. 530: 223–232, 2015 MARINE ECOLOGY PROGRESS SERIES Published June 18 doi: 10.3354/meps11135 Mar Ecol Prog Ser Contribution to the Theme Section ‘Economics of marine ecosystem conservation’ FREE ACCESS Economic incentives and overfishing: a bioeconomic vulnerability index William W. L. Cheung1,*, U. Rashid Sumaila2 1Changing Oceans Research Unit and 2Fisheries Economics Research Unit, University of British Columbia, 2202 Main Mall, Vancouver, BC V6T 1Z4, Canada ABSTRACT: Bioeconomic theory predicts that the trade-offs between maximization of economic benefits and conservation of vulnerable marine species can be assessed using the ratio between the discount rate of fishers and the intrinsic rate of growth of the exploited populations. In this paper, we use this theory to identify areas of the global ocean where higher vulnerability of fishes to overfishing would be expected in the absence of management. We derive an index to evaluate the level of vulnerability by comparing discount rates and fishes’ intrinsic population growth rates. Using published discount rates of countries that are reported to fish in the ocean and estimating the intrinsic population growth rate for major exploited fishes in the world, we calculate the vulnerability index for each 0.5° latitude × 0.5° longitude grid for each taxon and each fishing country. Our study shows that vulnerability is inherently high on the northeastern coast of Canada, the Pacific coast of Mexico, the Peruvian coast, in the South Pacific, on the southern and southeastern coast of Africa, and in the Antarctic region. It should be noted that this index does not account for the management regime currently in place in different areas, and thus mainly reflects the vulnerability resulting from the intrinsic life history characteristics of the fish species being targeted and the discount rates of the fishers exploiting them.
    [Show full text]
  • Study on the Economic Benefits of Marine Protected Areas Literature Review Analysis
    Study on the economic benefits of Marine Protected Areas Literature review analysis Written by ICF Consulting Services Limited, in association with IEEP and PML Sept 2017 EUROPEAN COMMISSION Executive Agency for Small and Medium-sized Enterprises (EASME) Unit A.3 — EMFF E-mail: [email protected] European Commission B-1049 Brussels EUROPEAN COMMISSION Study on the economic benefits of Marine Protected Areas Literature review analysis Executive Agency for Small and Medium-sized Enterprises (EASME) Contract No EASME/EMFF/2015/1.3.1.8/SI2.737373 2018 EN Study on the economic benefits of Marine Protected Areas Europe Direct is a service to help you find answers to your questions about the European Union. Freephone number (*): 00 800 6 7 8 9 10 11 (*) The information given is free, as are most calls (though some operators, phone boxes or hotels may charge you). LEGAL NOTICE This document has been prepared for the European Commission however it reflects the views only of the authors, and the Commission cannot be held responsible for any use which may be made of the information contained therein. More information on the European Union is available on the Internet (http://www.europa.eu). Luxembourg: Publications Office of the European Union, 2018 ISBN 978-92-9202-379-9 DOI 10.2826/40733 © European Union, 2018 Study on the economic benefits of Marine Protected Areas Report authors Pantzar, Mia (IEEP) Russi, Daniela (IEEP) Hooper, Tara (PML) Haines, Rupert (ICF) Quality review Rayment, Matt (ICF) Kettunen, Marianne (IEEP) Study on the economic benefits of Marine Protected Areas Table of Contents Executive summary ..........................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Economics of Marine Protected Areas As a Tool for Fisheries Management
    Economics of Marine Protected Areas as a Tool for Fisheries Management Greenville, J.W. Agricultural and Resource Economics, The University of Sydney, E-mail: [email protected] Keywords: Fisheries Management; Marine Protected Areas; Bioeconomics EXTENDED ABSTRACT greater the benefits from protected area establishment as more of the biomass that occurs The use of marine protected areas as a fishery within the protected area is likely to flow to the management tool has been suggested as a hedge surrounding fishery, offsetting the effects of against management failures and variation in reduced fishing area. The value of small sized harvests. If successful, protected areas have the protected areas is enhanced through the density- potential to increase the level of resource rent dependent flows. Under sink-source flows, derived from the extraction of fishery resources. differences in relative densities do not encourage In this paper, a stochastic bioeconomic model of a increased flows from the protected areas due to multi-species fishery is used to test the differences in patch population density, making the performance of protected areas as a management level of dispersal more dependent on protected area tool in a two patch, two species fishery with size. Given this, when sink-source flows are likely, heterogeneous environments. The differences in a minimum size protected area is required before the environments occur through each patch benefits to the fishery can be obtained. having its own growth rates and internal dynamics. Protected areas are analyzed under The creation of a marine protected area in the density-dependent and sink-source dispersal Manning Bioregion is likely to have different relationships between the environments within the distributional effects on the two fisheries examined fishery.
    [Show full text]
  • Food Security Implications of Global Marine Catch Losses Due to Overfishing
    J Bioecon (2010) 12:183–200 DOI 10.1007/s10818-010-9090-9 Food security implications of global marine catch losses due to overfishing U. Thara Srinivasan · William W. L. Cheung · Reg Watson · U. Rashid Sumaila Published online: 18 August 2010 © Springer Science+Business Media, LLC. 2010 Abstract Excess fishing capacity and the growth in global demand for fishery products have made overfishing ubiquitous in the world’s oceans. Here we describe the potential catch losses due to unsustainable fishing in all countries’ exclusive eco- nomic zones (EEZs) and on the high seas over 1950–2004. To do so, we relied upon catch and price statistics from the Sea Around Us Project as well as an empirical rela- tionship we derived from species stock assessments by the U.S. National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration. In 2000 alone, estimated global catch losses amounted to 7–36% of the actual tonnage landed that year, resulting in a landed value loss of between $6.4 and 36 billion (in 2004 constant US$). From 1950–2004, 36–53% of commercial species in 55–66% of EEZs may have been overfished. Referring to a species-level database of intrinsic vulnerability (V) based on life-history traits, it appears that susceptible species were depleted quickly and serially, with the aver- age V of potential catch losses declining at a similar rate to that of actual landings. Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (doi:10.1007/s10818-010-9090-9) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users. U. T. Srinivasan (B) Pacific Ecoinformatics and Computational Ecology Lab, Berkeley, CA 94702, USA e-mail: [email protected] W.
    [Show full text]
  • Mathematical Bioeconomics And
    Mathematical Bioeconomics and the Evolution of Fisheries Economics Revisited Gordon Munro Department of Economics and Fisheries Centre, University of British Columbia; CEMARE, University of Portsmouth Introduction • Twenty-one years ago, I participated in a conference to honour Colin on his 60th birthday – I gave a paper reviewing Colin’s contributions to fisheries economics, with the title: •Mathematical Bioeconomics and the Evolution of Modern Fisheries Economics • Today, I am revisiting this paper and will ask if my earlier conclusions have held up, and, if so, will then ask what has happened over the intervening two decades The Major Contributions • In that earlier conference , I said that Colin’s major contributions were twofold, and closely interlinked: – A. firmly establishing fisheries economics within the framework of the economist’ s theories of capital and investment – dynamic vs. static economics models of the fishey – B. constructing a bridge between fisheries economics and marine biology Colin’ s Predecessors • No one suggests that Colin was first to recognize significance of capital theory and biology to fisheries economics • recognized decades earlier – e.g. Anthony Scott, H. Scott Gordon, even some marine biologists recognized of capital theory for fisheries management – Pacific halibut, 1937 • Nonetheless, up until 1970s, capital theory and biology pushed well into the background in fisheries economics The Last Two Decades • What has happened over the past two decades? – basically, the fisheries economics that Colin did so much to develop has come into its own – will argue that many key fisheries managementit issues can be a ddresse did in economics terms, only with the aid of dynamic analysis ,e.g.
    [Show full text]
  • Determining the Best Uses of Mangrove Areas: an Application of Dynamic Optimization to the Case of Shrimp Mariculture in Ecuador
    University of Rhode Island DigitalCommons@URI Open Access Master's Theses 1993 Determining the Best Uses of Mangrove Areas: An Application of Dynamic Optimization to the Case of Shrimp Mariculture in Ecuador Exequiel Gonzalez Poblete University of Rhode Island Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.uri.edu/theses Recommended Citation Gonzalez Poblete, Exequiel, "Determining the Best Uses of Mangrove Areas: An Application of Dynamic Optimization to the Case of Shrimp Mariculture in Ecuador" (1993). Open Access Master's Theses. Paper 1240. https://digitalcommons.uri.edu/theses/1240 This Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by DigitalCommons@URI. It has been accepted for inclusion in Open Access Master's Theses by an authorized administrator of DigitalCommons@URI. For more information, please contact [email protected]. DETERMINING THE BEST USES OF MANGROVE AREAS: AN APPLICATION OF DYNAMIC OPTIMIZATION TO THE CASE OF SHRIMP MARICULTURE IN ECUADOR BY EXEQUIEL GONZALEZ POBLETE A THESIS SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF MASTER OF SCIENCE IN RESOURCE ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF RHODE ISLAND 1993 MASTER OF SCIENCE THESIS OF EXEQUIEL GONZALEZ POBLETE APPROVED: Thesis Committee Major Professor SCHOOL UNIVERSITY OF RHODE ISLAND 1993 ABSTRACT This research aims to determine the best uses of mangrove areas, with special emphasis on the shrimp mariculture industry in Ecuador. Traditionally, mangrove areas have been considered useless resources with no economic value except through development. Consequent conversion or exploitation of mangrove areas for urban infrastructural development, agricultural development and, more recently, shrimp mariculture has been taking place in several developing countries.
    [Show full text]
  • WRITTEN EVIDENCE of the CITY of VANCOUVER APPENDIX 83 Written Evidence of Rashid Sumaila, Phd
    WRITTEN EVIDENCE OF THE CITY OF VANCOUVER APPENDIX 83 Written Evidence of Rashid Sumaila, PhD {00224463v1} National Energy Board Hearing into Trans Mountain Expansion Project Direct Written Evidence of Rashid Sumaila Prepared for the City of Vancouver May 19, 2015 Table of Contents 1. Introduction and summary of witness qualification 1 2. Summary of Conclusions 3 3. Summary of Analysis 6 Appendix A: CV of Rashid Sumaila Appendix B: Report of Sumaila R, Hotte N and Bjarnason H, Potential economic impacts of a tanker spill on ocean-dependent activities in Vancouver, British Columbia (May 2015) Appendix C: CV of Ngaio Hotte Appendix D: CV of Harmony Bjarnason Appendix E: Certificate of Expert's Duty 1 INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY OF QUALIFICATIONS 2 Q.l Please state your name, occupation and business address. 3 A.l My name is Ussif Rashid Sumaila and I am a Professor and Director of the 4 Fisheries Economics Research Unit at UBC Fisheries Centre. 5 My address is 6 UBC Fisheries Centre, 7 2202 Main Mall 8 Vancouver, BC V6T 1Z4 9 Q.2 What is your academic background? 10 A.2 I have a Ph.D. in Economics from the University of Bergen, a Master of Science 1 1 degree in Economics from the University of Bergen and a Bachelor of Science from 1 2 Ahmadu Bello Univeristy. 1 3 Q.3 Please outline your principal areas of research. 14 A.3 I specialize in hioeconomics, marine ecosystem valuation and the analysis of 15 global issues such as fisheries subsidies, IUU (illegal, unreported and unregulated) 16 fishing and the economics of oil spills, high and deep seas fisheries.
    [Show full text]
  • Green Growth in Fisheries and Aquaculture Production and Trade
    Green Growth in Fisheries and Aquaculture Production and Trade Frank Asche* *Professor Department of Industrial Economics, University of Stavenger, Norway [email protected] 1 TABLE OF CONTENTS CONTRIBUTION TO OECD SYNTHESIS REPORT ON GREEN GROWTH ........................ 3 Green Growth in Fisheries and Aquaculture Production and Trade .......................................... 3 1. Introduction............................................................................................................................ 3 2. Background ............................................................................................................................ 4 3. Trends in wild capture fisheries ............................................................................................. 7 4. Trends in aquaculture .......................................................................................................... 12 5. Biodiversity and climate change .......................................................................................... 19 6. Energy use ........................................................................................................................... 20 7. New uses of the sea .............................................................................................................. 22 8. Trade, markets and socioeconomic impacts ........................................................................ 23 9. International and national policies ......................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Developing a More Equitable Framework for EU Fishing Agreements
    Marine Policy ] (]]]]) ]]]–]]] Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect Marine Policy journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/marpol Who gets what? Developing a more equitable framework for EU fishing agreements Le Manach Fre´de´rica,b,n, Andriamahefazafy Mialyc, Harper Saraha, Harris Alasdairc, Hosch Gillesd, Lange Glenn-Mariee, Zeller Dirka, Sumaila Ussif Rashida,f a Sea Around Us Project, Fisheries Centre, University of British Columbia, 2202 Main Mall, Vancouver, Canada V6T1Z4 b Institut de Recherche pour le De´veloppement (IRD), UMR EME 212, Centre de Recherches Halieutiques Me´diterrane´ennes et Tropicales, Avenue Jean Monnet, BP 171, 34203 Sete Cedex, France c Blue Ventures Conservation, Level 2 Annex, Omnibus Business Centre, 39-41 North Road, London N7 9DP, UK d Fisheries Planning & Management, 14 via Antonio Bertoloni, Rome 00197, Italy e Environment Department, The World Bank, 1818 H St. NW, Washington, DC 20433, USA f Fisheries Economics Research Unit, Fisheries Centre, University of British Columbia, 2202 Main Mall, Vancouver, Canada V6T 1Z4 article info abstract Article history: The reform of the European Union’s Common Fisheries Policy (CFP) is focusing attention on EU distant Received 15 February 2012 water fishing activities, including the agreements signed with developing coastal states. Here, the EU’s Received in revised form fishing agreement with Madagascar, among the poorest countries to hold such an agreement, is 2 June 2012 examined. Incomes received by Madagascar since the first agreement with the EU in 1986 are Accepted 2 June 2012 documented, in both nominal and real terms, and discussed in the context of other conditions tied to the agreement, in particular support provided by the EU to improve Madagascar’s fisheries Keywords: management capacity.
    [Show full text]
  • World Bank Document
    Sunk_fm.qxd 10/6/08 8:53 PM Page i 46193 Public Disclosure Authorized The Sunken Billions The Economic Justification Public Disclosure Authorized for Fisheries Reform October 2008 AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT Sustainable Development Network Public Disclosure Authorized ADVANCE EDITION Public Disclosure Authorized THE WORLD BANK FAO Washington, DC Rome Sunk_fm.qxd 10/6/08 8:53 PM Page ii © 2008 The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank 1818 H Street, NW Washington, DC 20433 Telephone: (202) 473-1000 Internet: www.worldbank.org/rural E-mail: [email protected] All rights reserved. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed herein are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Board of Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent. The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The boundaries, colors, denominations, and other information shown on any map in this work do not imply any judgment on the part of the World Bank concerning the legal sta- tus of any territory or the endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries. Rights and Permissions The material in this work is copyrighted. Copying and/or transmitting portions or all of this work without permission may be a violation of applicable law. The World Bank encourages dissemination of its work and will normally grant permission promptly. For permission to photocopy or reprint any part of this work, please send a request with complete information to the Copyright Clearance Center, Inc., 222 Rosewood Drive, Danvers, MA 01923, USA, telephone (978) 750-8400, fax (978) 750-4470, www.copyright.com.
    [Show full text]
  • Modelling the Potential Impacts of Fisheries on Ecosystem Dynamics Using Tropho-Dynamic Models Esther Nazi Fondo Msc (Biology of Conservation)
    Modelling the potential impacts of fisheries on ecosystem dynamics using tropho-dynamic models Esther Nazi Fondo MSc (Biology of Conservation) A thesis submitted for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy at The University of Queensland in 2019 School of Biological Sciences Abstract Despite many studies of the effects of fisheries on ecosystem dynamics, the consequences of removing food subsidies or predators from marine ecosystem are still unclear. In this thesis, I addressed two key areas in relation to our understanding of how fisheries affect ecosystem processes: (i) food subsidies and (ii) the effects of removal of predators. These two specific areas were selected as they have a potential of modifying ecosystems, and may lead to loss of the essential goods and services ecosystems provide. There are several threats to marine ecosystems, one of them being overfishing. The impacts of overfishing include changes in biological assemblages and modification of ecosystems. The Ecosystem Based Management (EBM) in fisheries has been widely advocated as it encompasses interactions within the ecosystem; and ecosystem models, which are able to address various scientific questions in ecosystems, have been widely used as a tool for advancing this process. In my thesis, I aimed to understand the effects of discarding and selective overfishing on ecosystem dynamics. Studies on the effects of discards on ecosystem dynamics have produced variable results, which creates uncertainty in concluding how ecosystems respond to discards, and presents a management challenge. It is still unclear whether discards should have similar impacts on all ecosystem types. To address this problem, in Chapter 2, I performed a global meta-analysis of 23 studies that were manipulated to explore the effects of discards on ecosystem functions (productivity, respiration and consumption).
    [Show full text]