The Rhetoric of Economics Author(S): Donald N

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Rhetoric of Economics Author(S): Donald N American Economic Association The Rhetoric of Economics Author(s): Donald N. McCloskey Source: Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 21, No. 2 (Jun., 1983), pp. 481-517 Published by: American Economic Association Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2724987 Accessed: 24/10/2009 16:06 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=aea. Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of Economic Literature. http://www.jstor.org Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XXI (June 1983), pp. 481-517 The Rhetoric of Economics By DONALD N. MCCLOSKEY The Universityof Iowa The length of the acknowledgments here testifies to an unexplored feature of the rhetoric of economics, the role of the audience: like oratory, scholarship depends for its virtues on the virtues of its audience. I have been fortunate in mine. I must apologize for my amateurish understanding of what is happening in philosophy, mathematics, literary criticism, rhetorical studies, and other places beyond my competence, and ask that practitioners in these fields assist in my further education. For their early attempts I thank Evan Fales, Paul Hernadi, John Lyne, Michael McGee,Allan Megill, John Nelson, and Jay Semel of the Colloquium on Applied Rhetoric at The University of Iowa; Wayne Booth, Ira Katznelson, and others at the University of Chicago in the program in Politics, Rhetoric and Law, before which the earliest version was delivered; Robert Boynton, Bernard Cohn,John Comaroff;Otis Dudley Duncan, James 0. Freedman, Clifford Geertz, William Kruskal, Donald Levine, Laura McCloskey,Richard Rorty, Renato Rosaldo; and the Humani- ties Society at the University of Iowa. That the economists on whom I have inflicted the argument have reacted with such intelligent skepticism and generous encouragement suggests, as the paper does, that we are better scholars than our methodology would allow. I thank my colleagues in economics at Iowa, especially the Sanctuary Seminar in Economic Argument; Seminars at the World Bank and the National Science Foundation; my colleagues at the Institute of Advanced Studies and the Faculty of Economics at the Australian National University; seminars at the universities of Adelaide, Auck- land, Melbourne, New South Wales, Tasmania and WesternAustra- lia; at Monash, and Iowa State universities; Victoria University of Wellington; and an assemblage of economists elsewhere: William Breit, Ronald Coase,Arthur Diamond, Stanley Engerman, J. M. Fin- ger, Milton Friedman, Allan Gibbard, Robert Goodin, Gary Hawke, Robert Higgs, Albert Hirschman, Eric Jones, Arjo Klamer, Harvey Leibenstein, David Levy, Peter Lindert, Neil de Marchi, Michael McPherson, Amartya Sen, Robert Solow, Larry Westphal, Gordon Winston, and Gavin Wright. Thomas Mayer's encouragement at an early stage and his detailed comments as refereefor this Journal at a later stage were exceptionally heartening and useful. 481 482 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXI (June 1983) ECONOMISTS DO NOT FOLLOW the laws ism labels such issues "meaningless" or of enquiry their methodologies lay "nonscientific" or "just matters of opin- down. A good thing, too. If they did they ion." Yet even positivists actually behave would stand silent on human capital, the as though the matters are discussable. In law of demand, random walks down Wall fact, most discussion in most sciences, and Street, the elasticity of demand for gaso- especially in economics, arises from them. line, and most other matters about which Nothing is gained from clinging to the Sci- they commonly speak. In view of the volu- entific Method, or to any methodology ex- bility of economists the many official cept honesty, clarity, and tolerance. Noth- methodologies are apparently not the ing is gained because the methodology grounds for their scientific conviction. does not describe the sciences it was once Economists in fact argue on wider thought to describe, such as physics or grounds, and should. Their genuine, mathematics; and because physics and workaday rhetoric, the way they argue in- mathematics are not good models for eco- side their heads or their seminar rooms, nomics anyway; and because the method- diverges from the official rhetoric. Econo- ology is now seen by many philosophers mists should become more self-conscious themselves to be uncompelling; and be- about their rhetoric, because they will cause economic science would stop pro- then better know why they agree or dis- gressing if the methodology were in fact agree, and will find it less easy to dismiss used; and, most important, because eco- contrary arguments on merely methodo- nomics, like any field, should get its stan- logical grounds. Philosophy as a set of nar- dards of argument from itself, not from rowing rules of evidence should be set the legislation of philosopher kings. The aside in scientific argument, as even many real arguments would then be joined. philosophers have been saying now for fifty years. I. Rhetoric Is Disciplined Conversation Economics will not change much in sub- stance, of course, when economists recog- These points, elaborated below, amount nize that the economic emperor has posi- to an appeal to examine the rhetoric of tively no clothes. He is the same fellow economics. By "rhetoric" is not meant a whether philosophically naked or clothed, verbal shell game, as in "empty rhetoric" in reasonably good health aside from his or "mere rhetoric" (although form is not sartorial delusion. But the temper of argu- trivial, either: disdain for the form of ment among economists would improve words is evidence of a mind closed to the if they recognized on what grounds they varieties of argument). In Modern Dogma were arguing. They claim to be arguing and the Rhetoric of Assent Wayne Booth on grounds of certain limited matters of gives many useful definitions. Rhetoric is statistical inference, on grounds of posi- "the art of probing what men believe they tive economics, operationalism, behavior- ought to believe, rather than proving ism, and other positivistic enthusiasms of what is true according to abstract meth- the 1930s and 1940s. They believe that ods"; it is "the art of discovering good rea- these are the only grounds for science. But sons, finding what really warrants assent, in their actual scientific work they argue because any reasonable person ought to about the aptness of economic metaphors, be persuaded"; it is "careful weighing of the relevance of historical precedents, more-or-less good reasons to arrive at the persuasiveness of introspections, the more-or-less probable or plausible conclu- power of authority, the charm of symme- sions-none too secure but better than try, the claims of morality. Crude positiv- would be arrived at by chance or unthink- McCloskey: The Rhetoric of Economics 483 ing impulse"; it is the "art of discovering century after Descartes rose from the warrantable beliefs and improving those dead. The faith built on these miracles is beliefs in shared discourse"; its purpose known in literary studies as the New Rhet- must not be "to talk someone else into a oric, new in the 1930s and 1940s from preconceived view; rather, it must be to the hands of I. A. Richards in Britain and engage in mutual inquiry" (Booth, 1974, Kenneth Burke in America (Richards, pp. xiii, xiv, 59, 137). It is what economists, 1936; Burke, 1950). In philosophy John like other dealers in ideas, do anyway: as Dewey and Ludwig Wittgenstein had al- Booth says elsewhere, "We believe in mu- ready begun to criticize Descartes' pro- tual persuasion as a way of life; we live gram of erecting belief on a foundation from conference to conference" (Booth, of skepticism. More recently Karl Popper, 1967, p. 13). Rhetoric is exploring thought Thomas Kuhn, and Imre Lakatos among by conversation. others have undermined the positivist The word "rhetoric"is doubtless an ob- supposition that scientific progress does in stacle to understanding the point, so de- fact follow Descartes' doubting rules of based has it become in common parlance. method. The literary, epistemological, If "pragmatism"and "anarchism"had not and methodological strands have not yet already suffered as much, unable to keep wound into one cord, but they belong to- clear of irrelevant associations with the gether. On the eve of the Cartesian revo- bottom line or the bomb, the title might lution the French philosopher and educa- better have been "Pragmatism'sConcep- tional reformer, Peter Ramus (fi. 1550), tion of Truth in Economics" or "Outline brought to completion a medieval ten- of an Anarchistic Theory of Knowledge dency to relegate rhetoric to mere elo- in Economics" (WilliamJames, 1907; Paul quence, leaving logic in charge of reason. Feyerabend, 1975). But the enemies of so- In the textbooks that Descartes himself phisticated pragmatism and gentle anar- read as a boy probable argument was chism, as of honest rhetoric, have used the made thus for the first time wholly subser- weapons at hand.
Recommended publications
  • A Study of Paul A. Samuelson's Economics
    Copyright is owned by the Author of the thesis. Permission is given for a copy to be downloaded by an individual for the purpose of research and private study only. The thesis may not be reproduced elsewhere without the permission of the Author. A Study of Paul A. Samuelson's Econol11ics: Making Economics Accessible to Students A thesis presented in partial fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Economics at Massey University Palmerston North, New Zealand. Leanne Marie Smith July 2000 Abstract Paul A. Samuelson is the founder of the modem introductory economics textbook. His textbook Economics has become a classic, and the yardstick of introductory economics textbooks. What is said to distinguish economics from the other social sciences is the development of a textbook tradition. The textbook presents the fundamental paradigms of the discipline, these gradually evolve over time as puzzles emerge, and solutions are found or suggested. The textbook is central to the dissemination of the principles of a discipline. Economics has, and does contribute to the education of students, and advances economic literacy and understanding in society. It provided a common economic language for students. Systematic analysis and research into introductory textbooks is relatively recent. The contribution that textbooks play in portraying a discipline and its evolution has been undervalued and under-researched. Specifically, applying bibliographical and textual analysis to textbook writing in economics, examining a single introductory economics textbook and its successive editions through time is new. When it is considered that an economics textbook is more than a disseminator of information, but a physical object with specific content, presented in a particular way, it changes the way a researcher looks at that textbook.
    [Show full text]
  • Freedom, Democracy and Economic Welfare
    copyright The Fraser Institute copyright The Fraser Institute LORD BAUER RAMON DIAZ MILTON FRIEDMAN RAYMOND D GASTIL TIBOR R MACHAN DOUGLASS NORTH SVETOZAR PEJOVICH ALVIN RABUSHKA INGEMAR STAHL LINDSAY M WRIGHT PROCEEDINGS OF AN INTERNATIONAL EDITED BY MICHAEL A WALKER SYMPOSIUM copyright The Fraser Institute Proceedings of an International Symposium on Economic, Political, and Civil Freedom, held October 5-8, 1986 in Napa Valley, California. This event is part of the programme of Liberty Fund Inc., under the direction of its President, Dr W. W. Hill. This Symposium was managed by The Fraser Institute and organized by its Director, Dr. Michael A. Walker. Canadian Cataloguing in Publication Data Main entry under title: Freedom, democracy and economic welfare Symposium held Oct 5-8, 1986 in Napa Valley, Calif. Includes bibliographical references. ISBN 0-88975-116-1 1.Capitalism – Congresses. 2. Liberty – Congresses. 3. Economics – Political aspects – Congresses. 4. Economics – Philosophy – Congresses. I. Walker, Michael 1945 – II.Fraser Institute (Vancouver, BC.) HB501.F74 1988 330.12’2 C88-091102-6 Copyright 1988 by the Fraser Institute. All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reproduced in any manner whatsoever without written permission except in the case of brief quotations embodied in critical arti- cles and reviews. Printed in Canada copyright The Fraser Institute CONTENTS Participants / vii Preface, Michael A. Walker / ix PART ONE POLITICAL, ECONOMIC AND CIVIL FREEDOMS: A CONCEPTUAL, HISTORICAL AND STATISTICAL OVERVIEW 1 INSTITUTIONS, ECONOMIC GROWTH AND FREEDOM: AN HISTORICAL INTRODUCTION, Douglass C. North / 3 Discussion / 26 2 CAPITALISM AND FREEDOM, Milton Friedman / 47 Discussion / 59 3 THE STATE OF THE WORLD POLITICAL AND ECONOMIC FREEDOM, Raymond D.
    [Show full text]
  • Xerox University Microfilms
    INFORMATION TO USERS This malarial was produced from a microfilm copy of the original document. While the most advanced technological means to photograph and reproduce this document have been used, the quality is heavily dependent upon the quality of the original submitted. The following explanation of techniques is provided to help you understand markings or patterns which may appear on this reproduction. 1. The sign or "target" for pages apparently lacking from the document photographed is "Missing Page(s)". If it was possible to obtain the missing page(s) or section, they are spliced into the film along with adjacent pages. This may have necessitated cutting thru an image and duplicating adjacent pages to insure you complete continuity. 2. When an image on the film is obliterated with a large round black mark, it is an indication that the photographer suspected that the copy may have moved during exposure and thus cause a blurred image. You will find a good image of the page in the adjacent frame. 3. When a map, drawing or chart, etc., was part of the material being photographed the photographer followed a definite method in "sectioning" the material. It is customary to begin photoing at the upper left hand corner of a large sheet and to continue photoing from left to right in equal sections with a small overlap. If necessary, sectioning is continued again - beginning below the first row and continuing on until complete. 4. The majority of users indicate that the textual content is of greatest value, however, a somewhat higher quality reproduction could be made from "photographs" if essential to the understanding of the dissertation.
    [Show full text]
  • Religion, Economy, and State: Economic Thought of Al-Mawardi in Adab Al-Dunya Wa-Al-Din by Aan JAELANI
    Journal of Economics Library www.kspjournals.org Volume 3 September 2016 Issue 3 Religion, Economy, and State: Economic Thought of al-Mawardi in Adab al-Dunya wa-al-Din By Aan JAELANIa† Abstract. The relation between religion, economy and the country became a major topic in the development of public welfare systems. Humans are political creatures that have the potential to realise the level of moral conscience to meet the needs of a better life, but humans as spiritual beings must have a balance between religious morality and economic morality. With economic ethics are supported by religious morality, the welfare system can be realised systemically if the state, communities and individuals can realise the six- dimensional form: religious observance, good governance, justice, national security, the prosperity of society and the nation's vision. Keywords. Religion, Economy, State, Ethics, Welfare state. JEL. B30, I30, N30, P50, Z12. 1. Introduction or the analysis of the public welfare, al-Mawardi al-Baghdadi (d. 450/1058) start a discussion philosophically about political ethics and Muslim character F with an emphasis on the role of individuals and communities to create integrity and social balance. In fact, the goal was set to realise the happiness of living in the world and in the hereafter (al-Arzanjani, 1328: 221-223). By applying philosophical postulates for a solid religious grounds, al-Mawardi describes human beings as political creatures (Arkoun, 2000: 250). If a man is a political creature, because he is basically weak (QS. Al-Nisa ', 4: 28), then he can not live without the help of others, in contrast to animals capable of living independently (al-Mawardi, 1996: 92- 93; al-Arzanjani, 1328: 218-219).
    [Show full text]
  • How Far Is Vienna from Chicago? an Essay on the Methodology of Two Schools of Dogmatic Liberalism
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Paqué, Karl-Heinz Working Paper — Digitized Version How far is Vienna from Chicago? An essay on the methodology of two schools of dogmatic liberalism Kiel Working Paper, No. 209 Provided in Cooperation with: Kiel Institute for the World Economy (IfW) Suggested Citation: Paqué, Karl-Heinz (1984) : How far is Vienna from Chicago? An essay on the methodology of two schools of dogmatic liberalism, Kiel Working Paper, No. 209, Kiel Institute of World Economics (IfW), Kiel This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/46781 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Kieler Arbeitspapiere Kiel Working Papers Working Paper No.
    [Show full text]
  • Discussion Paper: 11.09 November 2011 Aristotle's
    MASSEY UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE DISCUSSION PAPER: 11.09 NOVEMBER 2011 JAMES E. ALVEY ARISTOTLE’S ETHICS AND ECONOMICS PART II: POLITICS (HIGH AND LOW) This series contains work in progress at the School of Economics and Finance, Massey University. Comments and criticism are invited. Quotations may be made on explicit permission of the author(s). The Secretary School of Economics and Finance Massey University Private Bag 11222 Palmerston North 4442 NEW ZEALAND Phone: 06 356 9099 Extn 7744 Fax: 06 350 5660 Discussion Paper 11.09 ISSN 1179-0474 (Online) ∗ Aristotle’s Ethics and Economics Part II: Politics (High and Low) James E. Alvey School of Economics and Finance Massey University Palmerston North New Zealand ABSTRACT This paper on Aristotle (384-322 BC) is part of a long-term research programme on the ancient Greeks. It is a companion to other work, which deals with the ancient Greek context, and the thought/work of Socrates (469-399 BC), Plato (427-347 BC), and Xenophon (434- 355 BC). The framework for the investigations is shaped by the Capabilities approach developed by Amartya Sen. This is the second of three papers concerning Aristotle. The first paper considered Aristotle’s ethics. The projected paper will focus on his economics. The current paper focuses on Aristotle’s politics. Aristotle distinguishes between a narrow and a broad definition of politics (politikē). The peak of politics in the polis, the legislative art, fundamentally affects private behaviour (and choice and character) by individuals through enactment of law. Political science, in this sense, is the ‘architectonic’ or ‘master’ science i.e.
    [Show full text]
  • Strength in Numbers: the Rising of Academic Statistics Departments In
    Agresti · Meng Agresti Eds. Alan Agresti · Xiao-Li Meng Editors Strength in Numbers: The Rising of Academic Statistics DepartmentsStatistics in the U.S. Rising of Academic The in Numbers: Strength Statistics Departments in the U.S. Strength in Numbers: The Rising of Academic Statistics Departments in the U.S. Alan Agresti • Xiao-Li Meng Editors Strength in Numbers: The Rising of Academic Statistics Departments in the U.S. 123 Editors Alan Agresti Xiao-Li Meng Department of Statistics Department of Statistics University of Florida Harvard University Gainesville, FL Cambridge, MA USA USA ISBN 978-1-4614-3648-5 ISBN 978-1-4614-3649-2 (eBook) DOI 10.1007/978-1-4614-3649-2 Springer New York Heidelberg Dordrecht London Library of Congress Control Number: 2012942702 Ó Springer Science+Business Media New York 2013 This work is subject to copyright. All rights are reserved by the Publisher, whether the whole or part of the material is concerned, specifically the rights of translation, reprinting, reuse of illustrations, recitation, broadcasting, reproduction on microfilms or in any other physical way, and transmission or information storage and retrieval, electronic adaptation, computer software, or by similar or dissimilar methodology now known or hereafter developed. Exempted from this legal reservation are brief excerpts in connection with reviews or scholarly analysis or material supplied specifically for the purpose of being entered and executed on a computer system, for exclusive use by the purchaser of the work. Duplication of this publication or parts thereof is permitted only under the provisions of the Copyright Law of the Publisher’s location, in its current version, and permission for use must always be obtained from Springer.
    [Show full text]
  • The New Rhetoric Project As a Response to Anti-Semitism: Chaïm Perelman’S Reflections on Assimilation1
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Open Research Exeter The New Rhetoric Project as a Response to Anti-Semitism: Chaïm Perelman’s Reflections on Assimilation1 Michelle Bolduc Chaïm Perelman and Lucie Olbrechts-Tyteca have both been recognized for their tireless efforts on behalf of Jews: Perelman, himself a Jew, was praised for his work with the Jewish Resistance group, the Comité de la Défense des Juifs [CDJ], which was founded in his living room in June 1942; he was also noted for his postwar activities, including the Aliyah Bet movement immediately following the war.2 Olbrechts-Tyteca, for her part, was honored as one of the ‘Righteous among the Nations’ by Yad Vashem in 1980 for her work on the Comité des Marraines [Godmother Committee] founded by Fela Perelman, which hid Belgian Jewish children during the second World War.3 The present study does not have Perelman’s and Olbrechts-Tyteca’s work on behalf of the Jews as its subject; this has been amply described elsewhere (by, among others, Frank 1997, 2003, 2004, 2014; Steinberg 1978; Gross and Dearin 2003). It is rather an exploration of how they (and Perelman in particular) translate their experiences (direct and indirect) of anti-Semitism into the philosophical meditations of the Traité and the other writings that make up the New Rhetoric Project [NRP].4 If, as Amos Kiewe has pointed out, “scholarship on anti-Semitism from a rhetorical perspective is almost none existent” (vii), scholarship on the NRP’s response to anti-Semitism is, to date, slim.
    [Show full text]
  • Frank Knight 1933-2007 After Receiving His Ph.D
    Frank Knight 1933-2007 After receiving his Ph.D. from Princeton University in 1959, Frank Knight joined the mathematics department of the University of Minnesota. Frank liked Minnesota; the cold weather proved to be no difficulty for him since he climbed in the Rocky Mountains even in the winter time. But there was one problem: airborne flour dust, an unpleasant output of the large companies in Minneapolis milling spring wheat from the farms of Minnesota. Frank discovered that he was allergic to flour dust and decided that he would try to move to another location. His research was already recognized as important. His first four papers were published in the Illinois Journal of Mathematics and the Transactions of the American Mathematical Society. At that time, J.L. Doob was one of the editors of the Illinois Journal and attracted some of the best papers in probability theory to the journal including some of Frank's. He was hired by Illinois and served on its faculty from 1963 until his retirement in 1991. After his retirement, Frank continued to be active in his research, perhaps even more active since he no longer had to grade papers and carefully prepare his classroom lectures as he had always done before. In 1994, Frank was diagnosed with Parkinson's disease. For many years, this did not slow him down mathematically. He also kept physically active. At first, his health declined slowly but, in recent years, more rapidly. He died on March 19, 2007. Frank Knight's contributions to probability theory are numerous and often strikingly creative.
    [Show full text]
  • The Death of Welfare Economics: History of a Controversy
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Igersheim, Herrade Working Paper The death of welfare economics: History of a controversy CHOPE Working Paper, No. 2017-03 Provided in Cooperation with: Center for the History of Political Economy at Duke University Suggested Citation: Igersheim, Herrade (2017) : The death of welfare economics: History of a controversy, CHOPE Working Paper, No. 2017-03, Duke University, Center for the History of Political Economy (CHOPE), Durham, NC This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/155466 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu The death of welfare economics: History of a controversy by Herrade Igersheim CHOPE Working Paper No. 2017-03 January 2017 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2901574 The death of welfare economics: history of a controversy Herrade Igersheim December 15, 2016 Abstract.
    [Show full text]
  • Ancient Economic Thought, Volume 1
    ANCIENT ECONOMIC THOUGHT This collection explores the interrelationship between economic practice and intellectual constructs in a number of ancient cultures. Each chapter presents a new, richer understanding of the preoccupation of the ancients with specific economic problems including distribution, civic pride, management and uncertainty and how they were trying to resolve them. The research is based around the different artifacts and texts of the ancient East Indian, Hebraic, Greek, Hellenistic, Roman and emerging European cultures which remain for our consideration today: religious works, instruction manuals, literary and historical writings, epigrapha and legal documents. In looking at such items it becomes clear what a different exercise it is to look forward, from the earliest texts and artifacts of any culture, to measure the achievements of thinking in the areas of economics, than it is to take the more frequent route and look backward, beginning with the modern conception of economic systems and theory creation. Presenting fascinating insights into the economic thinking of ancient cultures, this volume will enhance the reawakening of interest in ancient economic history and thought. It will be of great interest to scholars of economic thought and the history of ideas. B.B.Price is Professor of Ancient and Medieval History at York University, Toronto, and is currently doing research and teaching as visiting professor at Massachusetts Institute of Technology. ROUTLEDGE STUDIES IN THE HISTORY OF ECONOMICS 1 Economics as Literature
    [Show full text]
  • GEORGE J. STIGLER Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago, 1101 East 58Th Street, Chicago, Ill
    THE PROCESS AND PROGRESS OF ECONOMICS Nobel Memorial Lecture, 8 December, 1982 by GEORGE J. STIGLER Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago, 1101 East 58th Street, Chicago, Ill. 60637, USA In the work on the economics of information which I began twenty some years ago, I started with an example: how does one find the seller of automobiles who is offering a given model at the lowest price? Does it pay to search more, the more frequently one purchases an automobile, and does it ever pay to search out a large number of potential sellers? The study of the search for trading partners and prices and qualities has now been deepened and widened by the work of scores of skilled economic theorists. I propose on this occasion to address the same kinds of questions to an entirely different market: the market for new ideas in economic science. Most economists enter this market in new ideas, let me emphasize, in order to obtain ideas and methods for the applications they are making of economics to the thousand problems with which they are occupied: these economists are not the suppliers of new ideas but only demanders. Their problem is comparable to that of the automobile buyer: to find a reliable vehicle. Indeed, they usually end up by buying a used, and therefore tested, idea. Those economists who seek to engage in research on the new ideas of the science - to refute or confirm or develop or displace them - are in a sense both buyers and sellers of new ideas. They seek to develop new ideas and persuade the science to accept them, but they also are following clues and promises and explorations in the current or preceding ideas of the science.
    [Show full text]