Productivity Growth and the New Economy

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Productivity Growth and the New Economy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³ZHOOPHDVXUHG´ RXWSXW5 DQG UHO\LQJ RQ LQ3RPHVLGH GDWD5 SURYLGHV D XVHIXO VXSSOHPHQW WR H[LVWLQJ GDWD VHWV 6H3RQG5 WKHUH KDV 3OHDUO\ EHHQ D UHERXQG LQ ODERUSURGX3WLYLW\ JURZWK LQ UH3HQW \HDUV $OO WKUHH VH3WRUDO GHILQLWLRQV VKRZ D PDMRU D33HOHUDWLRQ LQ ODERU SURGX3WLYLW\ LQ WKH ODVW WKUHH \HDUV RI WKH SHULRG A±C UHODWLYH WR WKH ±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± DQG 1%(5 ZLOOLDPQRUGKDXV#\DOHHGX I. Introduction and Summary 1 Variations in productivity growth have proven one of the most durable puzzles in macroeconomics. After growing rapidly for a quarter century, productivity came to a virtual halt in the early 1970s. There was no shortage of explanations for the productivity-growth slowdown. The explanations included rising energy prices, high and unpredictable inflation, rising tax rates, growing government, burdensome environmental and health regulation, declining research and development, deteriorating labor skills, depleted inventive possibilities, and societal laziness. These explanations seemed increasingly inadequate as inflation fell, tax rates were cut, regulatory burdens stabilized, government’s share output fell, research and development and patents granted grew sharply, energy prices fell back to pre-1973 levels, and a burst of invention in the new economy and other sectors fueled an investment boom in the 1990s. One of the major puzzles in the mid-1990s revolved around the inability of increasingly sophisticated and powerful computers and software to give an upward boost to productivity growth. This puzzle was expressed in the famous Solow paradox, “Computers are everywhere except in the productivity statistics.” Notwithstanding the ubiquitous computer, through thin and thick labor-productivity growth seemed to be on a stable track of slightly over 1 percent per year. However, in the late 1990s, productivity growth rebounded sharply. Over the period from 1995 to mid-2000, productivity growth in the business sector grew at a rate close to that in the pre- 1973 period. The causes of the rebound were widely debated, but at least part was clearly due to astonishing productivity growth in the “new economy” sectors of information and communications. The present study is the last of three papers devoted to developing new data and methods for measuring productivity growth and examining the extent and sources of the current productivity 1The author is grateful for comments from Ray Fair. Version is [d1284jrn.wpd] rebound. In addition to examining recent productivity behavior, the current study adds a few new features to the analysis. First, it examines the welfare-theoretic basis of productivity measures and proposes an “ideal” index of productivity growth. Second, it lays out a different way of decomposing productivity growth which divides aggregate productivity trends into factors that increase average productivity growth from the changing shares of the sizes of different sectors. Third, we develop an alternative way of measuring aggregate and industrial productivity based on industrial data built up from the income side rather than the product side of the accounts. By relying on the industrial data, we can focus on different definitions of output and get sharper estimates of the sources of productivity growth. Fourth, by working with the new industrial data, we can make more accurate adjustments for the contribution of the “new economy” than has been the case in earlier studies. Finally, this new data set allows us to create a new economic aggregate, which we call “well- measured output,” that allows us to remove those sectors where output is poorly measured or measured by inputs. Because the study is heavily methodological and data-intensive, we summarize the approach and major results in this introductory section. 1. The present study introduces a new approach to measuring industrial productivity. It develops an income-side data base, currently available to 1997–98, on labor productivity relying on data that are published by the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA). The data are internally consistent in that both inputs and outputs are income-side measures of value added, whereas the usual productivity measures combine expenditure-side output measures with income-side input measures. The advantage of the unified income-side measures is that they present a consistent set of industrial accounts. The disadvantages are that they are only available for the period 1977–98 and that they do not contain a set of capital accounts, so we can only examine labor productivity. 2. We have constructed a set of labor productivity measures for four different definitions of output: • GDP from the income side • BLS’s business sector output from the income side • A new measure called “well-measured output,” which includes only those sectors for which output is relatively well measured • The “new economy” as defined below 3. The constructed measures of labor productivity are reasonably consistent with the most widely studied measure, the BLS’s measure of labor productivity in the business sector. Over the period of investigation, the difference between the labor-productivity growth rate estimates of the income-side and product-side constructs is 0.05 percentage points per year. However, in the last three years, productivity from the income-side series grew more than 1 percentage point more rapidly, primarily because of the movement in the statistical discrepancy between output and income side measures. 4. There has clearly been a rebound in productivity growth since 1995. The rebound is found in all three sectoral definitions developed for this study. The labor productivity acceleration in the last three years of the period (1996–98) relative to the 1978–95 period was 1.2 percentage points for GDP, 1.8 percentage points for business sector, and 2.1 percentage points for well-measured output. 5. We have developed a new technique for decomposing changes in labor-productivity growth between different sources. This decomposition identifies a pure productivity effect (which is a fixed weighted average of the productivity growth rates of different industries); the Denison effect (which captures the effect of changing shares of employment on aggregate productivity); and the Baumol effect (which captures the interaction between the differences in productivity growth and the changing hours shares of different industries over time). Total productivity growth is the sum of these three effects. 6. Our estimates show that the pure productivity effect in recent years has been substantially above total productivity growth. For example, in the business sector for the period 1996–98, total labor-productivity growth has been 3.19 percent per year while the pure productivity effect was 3.61 percent per year. The difference was primarily due to the Baumol effect, with a rising share of hours in services accompanying slow labor-productivity growth in services. The Baumol and Denison effects are relatively small for well-measured output. 7. The first companion paper to this study provides a rigorous definition of the appropriate measure of productivity growth from a welfare-theoretic point of view. The present paper applies the ideal measure to the new data set. We find that the ideal measure is higher than other commonly used measures of labor-productivity growth in every period. The differences are relatively small in the most recent period, but they are substantial in earlier periods. On average, the ideal or welfare- theoretic measure over the 1978–98 period is about 0.2 percentage points per year higher than the other measures. 8. One key question is the contribution of the new economy to the productivity rebound. For the purpose of this study, we define the new economy as machinery, electric
Recommended publications
  • A Study of Paul A. Samuelson's Economics
    Copyright is owned by the Author of the thesis. Permission is given for a copy to be downloaded by an individual for the purpose of research and private study only. The thesis may not be reproduced elsewhere without the permission of the Author. A Study of Paul A. Samuelson's Econol11ics: Making Economics Accessible to Students A thesis presented in partial fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Economics at Massey University Palmerston North, New Zealand. Leanne Marie Smith July 2000 Abstract Paul A. Samuelson is the founder of the modem introductory economics textbook. His textbook Economics has become a classic, and the yardstick of introductory economics textbooks. What is said to distinguish economics from the other social sciences is the development of a textbook tradition. The textbook presents the fundamental paradigms of the discipline, these gradually evolve over time as puzzles emerge, and solutions are found or suggested. The textbook is central to the dissemination of the principles of a discipline. Economics has, and does contribute to the education of students, and advances economic literacy and understanding in society. It provided a common economic language for students. Systematic analysis and research into introductory textbooks is relatively recent. The contribution that textbooks play in portraying a discipline and its evolution has been undervalued and under-researched. Specifically, applying bibliographical and textual analysis to textbook writing in economics, examining a single introductory economics textbook and its successive editions through time is new. When it is considered that an economics textbook is more than a disseminator of information, but a physical object with specific content, presented in a particular way, it changes the way a researcher looks at that textbook.
    [Show full text]
  • Rolling the DICE: William Nordhaus's Dubious Case for a Carbon
    SUBSCRIBE NOW AND RECEIVE CRISIS AND LEVIATHAN* FREE! “The Independent Review does not accept “The Independent Review is pronouncements of government officials nor the excellent.” conventional wisdom at face value.” —GARY BECKER, Noble Laureate —JOHN R. MACARTHUR, Publisher, Harper’s in Economic Sciences Subscribe to The Independent Review and receive a free book of your choice* such as the 25th Anniversary Edition of Crisis and Leviathan: Critical Episodes in the Growth of American Government, by Founding Editor Robert Higgs. This quarterly journal, guided by co-editors Christopher J. Coyne, and Michael C. Munger, and Robert M. Whaples offers leading-edge insights on today’s most critical issues in economics, healthcare, education, law, history, political science, philosophy, and sociology. Thought-provoking and educational, The Independent Review is blazing the way toward informed debate! Student? Educator? Journalist? Business or civic leader? Engaged citizen? This journal is for YOU! *Order today for more FREE book options Perfect for students or anyone on the go! The Independent Review is available on mobile devices or tablets: iOS devices, Amazon Kindle Fire, or Android through Magzter. INDEPENDENT INSTITUTE, 100 SWAN WAY, OAKLAND, CA 94621 • 800-927-8733 • [email protected] PROMO CODE IRA1703 Rolling the DICE William Nordhaus’s Dubious Case for a Carbon Tax F ROBERT P. M URPHY he 2007 Nobel Peace Prize awarded to Al Gore and the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) underscores the public’s growing aware- T ness of and concern about anthropogenic (man-made) global warming. Many climatologists and other relevant scientists claim that emissions of greenhouse gases (GHGs) from human activity will lead to increases in the earth’s temperature, which in turn will spell potentially catastrophic hardship for future generations.
    [Show full text]
  • Paul Samuelson and Global Public Goods
    Paul Samuelson and Global Public Goods William D. Nordhaus Yale University1 May 5, 2005 A commemorative essay for Paul Samuelson ________________________________________________________ It is both easy and hard to write an essay commemorating Paul Samuelson’s contributions to economics. Easy, because he has created so much of modern economics that you could write on virtually anything – stabilization policy, economic growth, international trade, welfare economics, or just about any topic that caught your fancy. Hard, because, like Buridan’s ass, you could easily procrastinate forever in deciding which of the many treasures of his ideas to draw from. In the end, I chose to draw from Paul’s writings on public goods. In two and one-half pages, he reshaped the way economists and political philosophers think about the distinction between private goods and public goods.2 Once those concepts are learned, we can never again forget why the allocational questions for bread are fundamentally different from those of lighthouses. I will focus on an important example of this topic, and one that poses particularly thorny practical 1 The author is Sterling Professor of Economics at Yale University. 2 Paul Samuelson, “The Pure Theory of Public Expenditure,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 36, No. 4, Nov. 1954, pp. 387-389. - 1 - issues, which is the case of global public goods. A brief intellectual history of the concepts is appended. What great blessings or scourges have befallen humanity? Consider issues as disparate as greenhouse warming and ozone depletion, the Internet and William Shakespeare, terrorism and money laundering, the discovery of antibiotics and nuclear proliferation.
    [Show full text]
  • The Role of Models and Probabilities in the Monetary Policy Process
    1017-01 BPEA/Sims 12/30/02 14:48 Page 1 CHRISTOPHER A. SIMS Princeton University The Role of Models and Probabilities in the Monetary Policy Process This is a paper on the way data relate to decisionmaking in central banks. One component of the paper is based on a series of interviews with staff members and a few policy committee members of four central banks: the Swedish Riksbank, the European Central Bank (ECB), the Bank of England, and the U.S. Federal Reserve. These interviews focused on the policy process and sought to determine how forecasts were made, how uncertainty was characterized and handled, and what role formal economic models played in the process at each central bank. In each of the four central banks, “subjective” forecasting, based on data analysis by sectoral “experts,” plays an important role. At the Federal Reserve, a seventeen-year record of model-based forecasts can be com- pared with a longer record of subjective forecasts, and a second compo- nent of this paper is an analysis of these records. Two of the central banks—the Riksbank and the Bank of England— have explicit inflation-targeting policies that require them to set quantita- tive targets for inflation and to publish, several times a year, their forecasts of inflation. A third component of the paper discusses the effects of such a policy regime on the policy process and on the role of models within it. The large models in use in central banks today grew out of a first generation of large models that were thought to be founded on the statisti- cal theory of simultaneous-equations models.
    [Show full text]
  • Political Business Cycles 40 Years After Nordhaus Eric Dubois
    Political Business Cycles 40 Years after Nordhaus Eric Dubois To cite this version: Eric Dubois. Political Business Cycles 40 Years after Nordhaus. Public Choice, Springer Verlag, 2016, 166 (1-2), pp.235-259. 10.1007/s11127-016-0313-z. hal-01291401 HAL Id: hal-01291401 https://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-01291401 Submitted on 21 Mar 2016 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. Political Business Cycles 40 Years after Nordhaus Eric Dubois1 Abstract: The aim of this article is to survey the huge literature that has emerged in the last four decades following Nordhaus’s (1975) publication on political business cycles (PBCs). I first propose some developments in history of thought to examine the context in which this ground-breaking contribution saw the light of the day. I also present a simplified version of Nordhaus’s model to highlight his key results. I detail some early critiques of this model and the fields of investigations to which they gave birth. I then focus on the institutional context and examine its influence on political business cycles, the actual research agenda. Finally, I derive some paths for future research.
    [Show full text]
  • Political Business Cycle and Economic Instability - Literature Review
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Tiganas, Claudiu-Gabriel; Peptine, Claudiu Article Political Business Cycle and Economic Instability - Literature Review CES Working Papers Provided in Cooperation with: Centre for European Studies, Alexandru Ioan Cuza University Suggested Citation: Tiganas, Claudiu-Gabriel; Peptine, Claudiu (2012) : Political Business Cycle and Economic Instability - Literature Review, CES Working Papers, ISSN 2067-7693, Alexandru Ioan Cuza University of Iasi, Centre for European Studies, Iasi, Vol. 4, Iss. 4, pp. 853-865 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/198221 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend
    [Show full text]
  • 1017-04 BPEA/Nordhaus 12/30/02 15:01 Page 211
    1017-04 BPEA/Nordhaus 12/30/02 15:01 Page 211 WILLIAM D. NORDHAUS Yale University Productivity Growth and the New Economy What, another paper on the new economy? When financial markets are raking through the debris of $8 trillion in lost equity value, and “.com” is a reviled four-symbol word, a paper on the impact of the new economy on productivity would seem as welcome as an analysis of the role of whales in the lighting revolution. In fact, the new economy (or, more precisely, information technolo- gies) continues to raise important puzzles about productivity growth. Variations in productivity growth have proved to be one of the most durable puzzles in macroeconomics. After a period of rapid growth fol- lowing World War II, productivity stagnated in the early 1970s. There was no shortage of explanations offered, including rising energy prices, high and unpredictable inflation, rising tax rates, growing government, burdensome environmental and health regulation, declining research and development, deteriorating labor skills, depleted possibilities for inven- tion, and societal laziness.1 Yet these explanations seemed increasingly inadequate as inflation fell, tax rates were cut, regulatory burdens stabi- lized, government’s share of output fell, research and development and patents granted grew sharply, real energy prices fell back to pre-1973 lev- els, and a burst of invention in the new economy and other sectors fueled an investment boom in the 1990s. The productivity slowdown puzzle of the 1980s evolved into the Solow paradox of the early 1990s: computers were everywhere except in the The author is grateful for comments from Ray Fair, Robert Yuskavage, and members of the Brookings Panel.
    [Show full text]
  • The Economic Costs of a War in Iraq
    cepr CENTER FOR ECONOMIC AND POLICY RESEARCH Briefing Paper The Economic Costs of a War in Iraq: The Negative Scenario By Dean Baker and Mark Weisbrot1 December 9, 2002 CENTER FOR ECONOMIC AND POLICY RESEARCH 1621 CONNECTICUT AVE., NW, SUITE 500 • WASHINGTON , D.C. 20009 • (202) 293-5380 • <WWW.CEPR.NET> • EMAIL: [email protected] 1 Dean Baker and Mark Weisbrot are co-Directors of the Center for Economic and Policy Research. Simone Baribeau, Andrea Blatchford, Debayani Kar, Todd Tucker, John Schmitt, and Jefferson Beck provided helpful research and comments on earlier drafts of this paper. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY This paper examines the potential economic costs of a war with Iraq in a scenario in which the war is not over quickly. It follows loosely from the negative scenario developed in a recent study by William Nordhaus. The paper discusses several ways in which a war can impose large economic costs, that have not been seriously considered in policy debates to date. The paper notes that: 1) Nordhaus’ estimate of GDP loss in a negative war outcome, implies a loss of 1.6 million jobs in 2003 and 2004. It implies that the economy will have an average of 300,000 fewer jobs over the next seven years (2005-2011), as it gradually recovers from a war-related oil shock. Nordhaus’ estimate of the immediate impact of a war-related oil price shock is comparable to the high-end estimates of the job loss in the United States that would result from implementing a Kyoto-type agreement restricting the emission of greenhouse gases.
    [Show full text]
  • Employment- Unemployment
    EMPLOYMENT- UNEMPLOYMENT HEARINGS BEFORE THE JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES NINETY-FIFTH CONGRESS FIRST SESSION PART 10 MAY 6, JUNE 3, JULY 8, AND AUGUST 5, 1977 Printed for the use of the Joint Economic Committee U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE 98-520 0 WASHINGTON : 1977 For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Office Washington, D.C. 20402 Stock Number 052-070-04402-1 r' I ; \ I ) JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE (Created pursuant to see. 5(a) of Public Law 304, 79th Cong.) RICHARD BOLLING, Missouri, Chairman HUBERT H. HUMPHREY, Minnesota, Vice Chairman HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES SENATE HENRY S. REUSS, Wisconsin JOHN SPARKMAN, Alabama WILLIAM S. MOORHEAD, Pennsylvania WILLIAM PROXMIRE, Wisconsin LEE H. HAMILTON, Indiana ABRAHAM RIBICOFF, Connecticut GILLIS W. LONG, Louisiana LLOYD BENTSEN, Texas OTIS G. PIKE, New York EDWARD M. KENNEDY, Massachusetts CLARENCE J. BROWN, Ohio JACOB K. JAVITS, New York GARRY BROWN, Michigan WILLIAM V. ROTH, Ja., Delaware MARGARET M. HECKLER, Massachusetts JAMES A. McCLURE, Idaho JOHN H. ROUSSELOT, California ORRIN G. HATCH, Utah JOHN R. STAaK, Executive Director LouIs C. KRAUTHOFF II, Assistant Director RICHARD F. KAUFMAN, General Counsel ECONOMISTS 0. THOMAS CATOR KENT H. HUGHES PHILIP MCMARTIN WILLIAM A. Cox SARAH JACKSON DEBORAH NORELLI THOMAS F. DEaNBUaG JOHN R. KARLIK GEORGE R. TYLEa ROBERT D. HAMRIN L. DOUGLAS LEE MISNSETY CHARLES H. BRADFORD STEPHEN J. ENTIN GEORGE D. KRUMBHAAR, Ja. M. CATHERINE MILLER MARK R. PoLICINSKI (II) CONTENTS WITNESSES AND STATEMENTS FRIDAY, MAY 6, 1977 Long, Hon. Gillis W., member of the Joint Economic Committee: Opening Page statement -_----------_ -------- ___ -------- 1737 Shiskin, Hon.
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Policy When Models Disagree
    .V%J1H. V `Q$`:IIV7 0:C%: 1J$ .V HQJQI1H Q` C1I: V 1@ :JR ]]Q` %J1 1V 1J .V J%`:JHV VH Q` Economic policy when models disagree Pauline Barrieu and Bernard Sinclair Desgagné July 2009 Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy Working Paper No. 5 Munich Re Programme Technical Paper No. 1 Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and the Environment Working Paper No. 4 The Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy (CCCEP) was established by the University of Leeds and the London School of Economics and Political Science in 2008 to advance public and private action on climate change through innovative, rigorous research. The Centre is funded by the UK Economic and Social Research Council and has five inter-linked research programmes: 1. Developing climate science and economics 2. Climate change governance for a new global deal 3. Adaptation to climate change and human development 4. Governments, markets and climate change mitigation 5. The Munich Re Programme - Evaluating the economics of climate risks and opportunities in the insurance sector (funded by Munich Re) More information about the Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy can be found at: http://www.cccep.ac.uk. The Munich Re Programme is evaluating the economics of climate risks and opportunities in the insurance sector. It is a comprehensive research programme that focuses on the assessment of the risks from climate change and on the appropriate responses, to inform decision-making in the private and public sectors. The programme is exploring, from a risk management perspective, the implications of climate change across the world, in terms of both physical impacts and regulatory responses.
    [Show full text]
  • Integrating Nature and Knowledge Into Economics
    THE PRIZE IN ECONOMIC SCIENCES 2018 POPULAR SCIENCE BACKGROUND Integrating nature and knowledge into economics This year’s Prize in Economic Sciences rewards the design of methods that address some of the most fundamental and pressing issues of our time: long-run sustainable growth in the global economy and the welfare of the world’s population. The study of how humanity copes with limited resources is at the heart of economics and, since its inception as a science, economics has recognised that the most important constraints on resources refect nature and knowledge. Nature dictates the conditions in which we live and knowledge defnes our ability to manage these conditions. However, despite their central role, economists have generally not studied how nature and knowledge are afected by markets and economic behaviour. This year’s laureates, Paul M. Romer and William D. Nordhaus, have broadened the scope of economic analysis by designing the tools that are necessary to examine how the market economy has a long-term infuence on nature and knowledge. The work of both Laureates builds upon the Solow growth model, which received the Prize in Economic Sciences in 1987. Knowledge For more than a century, the overall global economy has grown at a remarkable and fairly steady pace. When a few per cent of economic growth per year accumulates over decades and centu- ries, it transforms people’s lives. However, growth has progressed much more slowly throughout most of human history. It also varies from country to country. So what explains when and where growth occurs? Economics’ conventional answer is technological change, where the growing volumes of know- ledge are embodied in technologies created by inventors, engineers, and scientists.
    [Show full text]
  • Harvard University Jeffrey B. Liebman Kennedy School of Government Spring 2019
    Harvard University Jeffrey B. Liebman Kennedy School of Government Spring 2019 API-102Z Economic Analysis of Public Policy Class: Monday and Wednesday, 10:15am-11:30am, Wexner 436 Review Session: Friday 10:15am-11:30am Wexner 332 Office: Taubman 318 Telephone: (617) 495-8518 E-mail: [email protected] Office Hours: By appointment, please contact Hope Patterson Faculty Assistant: Hope Patterson T319, Telephone: (617) 495-3158 e-mail: [email protected] The Course This course builds upon the foundation of API-101Z and develops microeconomic tools of analysis for policy problems using a variety of policy applications. The course is focused broadly on evaluating the rationale for government intervention in the economy and evaluating the efficiency, incentive, and distributional effects of government policies. Areas of application include cost- benefit analysis, taxation, income redistribution, health, education, infrastructure, and trade. Prerequisites The course presumes that students have prior preparation in microeconomics, typically API-101Z. This Z section assumes the ability to use calculus. Requirements The formal course requirements are: completion of daily problems, one policy memo, a midterm exam, and a final exam. Grades will be based 15% on the daily problems, 10% on the memo, 25% on the midterm, and 50% on the final. Assignments are due at the start of class on the days indicated. Late daily problems are not accepted. Late memos carry a penalty of one-third of a grade per day late. Students may skip two daily problems with no penalty. 1 Readings Readings or web links to readings are posted on the course web site.
    [Show full text]