Can Democracy Survive Capitalism's Erosion? a Comment on E.O. Wright

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Can Democracy Survive Capitalism's Erosion? a Comment on E.O. Wright Mudge 9/2019, not for circulation or citation Can Democracy Survive Capitalism’s Erosion? A Comment on Erik Olin Wright Stephanie L. Mudge September 27, 2019 DRAFT paper presented at “How To Be An Anti-Capitalist in the 21st Century: A One-Day Conference in Memory of Erik Olin Wright,” 9/26/2019. Word count: 7,077 Comments welcome: [email protected] Abstract This paper celebrates the memory of Erik Olin Wright via an extended critical engagement with his final work, How To Be An Anti-Capitalist in the 21st Century. Through a comparison of Wright’s and Wolfgang Streeck’s analyses on matters of capitalism, crisis and the state, and collective action I highlight that, despite a shared concern with how capitalism shapes human abilities for building and enacting anti-capitalist strategic political movements (either by sapping or inadvertently cultivating it), neither analysis gives a satisfactory account of the formation of historical persons—nor, indeed, for the existence of theorists like themselves. Instead, based on macro-theoretical analyses and broad historical knowledge both infer certain kinds of actors: hopeless self-medicating worker-consumers for Streeck; partially-embedded human repositories of values, beliefs, and identities, whose anti- capitalist impulses can be honed by way of strategic anti-capitalist theory, for Wright. The shared problem of assuming the nature of the capitalist subject, I argue, is entirely resolvable by making it an empirical matter, accessible via a long line of sociological thinking that is concerned with the historical conditions of critical reason. By incorporating these concerns into the normal methodological practices and orientations of sociological political economy, I argue, there is the possibility of bridging Wright’s future-oriented optimism with Streeck’s pessimistic history of the present. 1 Mudge 9/2019, not for circulation or citation Can Democracy Survive Capitalism’s Erosion? Erik Olin Wright’s How to be an Anti-Capitalist in the 21st Century offers a refreshingly optimistic take on future possibilities in a moment that is otherwise saturated with foreboding. Rather than succumbing to “gloom and doom” Wright imagined a societal order founded in equality and fairness, meaningful democratic freedom, and cooperative solidarity, making the case that a better world is possible—and, more importantly, plausible. In his final work Wright focused his energies on the question of the “vehicle,” or getting from here to there, advancing a strategic theory of “eroding capitalism” via a combination of resistance, avoidance, and head-on pursuit of legislative and political power. And yet, though Wright’s optimism is heartening, his final work is more sketch than history; it does not dwell in any great detail on our current predicament. Here we might contrast Wright’s utopian optimism with the decidedly darker and more deeply historical analysis of Wolfgang Streeck, who argues that a world of accelerating finance-saturated global capitalism and declining debt-cum-consolidation Western states adds up to a state of indeterminate decline that exceeds the analytical capacities of sociological theories. In Streeck’s words, “unexpected things can happen any time.” Streeck’s analysis can be read as a refutation of both the letter and the spirit of the Wrightian take—that is, of its analysis (the letter) as well as the very notion that theoretically-informed sociological political economy is able to contribute to transformational projects (the spirit). In Streeck’s view, future possibilities are both wide open and negatively skewed; they may include capitalism or democracy but not both (or maybe neither); the chance of a socialist future, if not foreclosed, 2 Mudge 9/2019, not for circulation or citation is exceedingly dim. Assuming that Streeck’s historical analysis is broadly correct1 we might ask, then, whether the political-economic ‘game’ is, in Elizabeth Warren’s favorite term, “rigged” such that “eroding capitalism”—which, in the United States, one could say is already underway in some corners—is more likely than not to culminate in something entirely less desirable than democratically-grounded emancipatory socialism that will remain beyond our grasp until it is upon us. In the spirit of Wrightian optimism, however, we cannot be content to leave it at that. Through a comparison of Wright’s and Streeck’s analyses on matters of capitalism, crisis and the state, and collective action I highlight that, despite a shared concern with how capitalism shapes human capacities for critical reason and, by extension, building and enacting anti- capitalist strategic political movements (either by sapping [Streeck] or inadvertently cultivating it [Wright]), neither analysis passes the litmus test learned by graduate students in their first sociological theory courses: there is no satisfactory account of the existence of the theorist—that is, of themselves. The more general criticism here is the absence of any sustained theory of the making of definite historical actors, anti-capitalist or otherwise. Instead, based on macro-theoretical analyses and broad historical knowledge (and, no doubt, personal experience), both infer certain kinds of actors: hopeless self-medicating worker- consumers for Streeck; partially-embedded human repositories of values, beliefs, and identities whose anti-capitalist impulses can be honed by way of strategic anti-capitalist theory, for Wright. 1 This is a big assumption; Streeck’s analysis has attracted criticism on various fronts. A recent article in Historical Materialism by Jerome Roos of the LSE characterizes Streeck’s take as an “exceedingly catastrophist worldview, devoid of any emancipatory potential” that, with its emphasis on the nation-state as a bulwark against the ever-deeper encroachments of market society, veers “dangerously close to the welfare chauvinism of the nationalist right” (Roos 2019, 248; see also Tooze 2019). I have my own, very different, criticisms— elaborated below. 3 Mudge 9/2019, not for circulation or citation This shared problem, I argue, points to a means of bridging Wright’s future-oriented optimism with Streeck’s pessimistic history of the present. Because many social theorists have taken up the problem of the making of certain kinds of historical persons, practices, and action-orientations—an incomplete list would include Marx, Weber, Durkheim, Du Bois, Mead, Dewey, Cooper, Gramsci, Fanon, de Beauvoir, Bourdieu, and more or less the whole of feminist, postcolonial and critical race theory—it also points the way to a needed corrective to Streeck’s troubling contention that sociological theory is rendered helpless in the face of crisis-laden indeterminacy. In short, my overarching claim is that, if the aim is an eleventh- thesis kind of theory—that is, an assessment of the present in light of the past capable of addressing the strategic question of what is to be done—then the practice of political economy needs to incorporate a meaningful analysis of the conditions of (im)possibility of transformative social actors. The letter: Wright vs Streeck—or, will “erosion” lead to socialism? Streeck’s recent work—including especially How Will Capitalism End? (2016 [2017]2) and Buying Time: The Delayed Crisis of Democratic Capitalism (2013 [2017])—can be read as a refutation of both the letter and the spirit of Wrightian optimism. In this section I focus on the letter. In particular, I work through a contrast of Wright and Streeck’s views of capitalism, crisis and the state, and collective action to arrive at a crucial question: whether “eroding capitalism” may kill the (already ill) democratic patient, lead down a path other than that Wright envisioned—one that may be entirely less desirable than a democratically-grounded, emancipatory socialism. However, lacking any sustained theory of the making of definite 2 How Will Capitalism End? features work published between 2011 and 2015. 4 Mudge 9/2019, not for circulation or citation historical actors (anti-capitalist, democratic, socialist, or otherwise—all of which, we might note, can be found in contemporary the world), despite a shared emphasis on the centrality of human capacity for strategic collective action, and no shortage of theories of the formation of different sorts of historical persons, neither perspective is capable of answering this question. Capitalism Wright defines capitalism as a two-fold “form of social organization” defined by “a class structure characterized by private ownership of the means of production” in which most people get by “selling their labor on a labor market” and a mode of “economic coordination organized through decentralized market exchange” (Wright 2006, 100). Two hallmarks, “poverty in the midst of plenty” and environmental destruction, are among its “gravest” failings (Wright 2018, 1). Prioritizing future-oriented normative critique over the more conventional Marxian concern with structural contradictions and the supposed necessities thereof, Wright makes the case that our starting point should not be whether things are better in a capitalist order over the “long run” but rather, looking forward from the present, whether an alternative economy would “be better for most people” (ibid). Wright’s notion of capitalism as a class structure plus market coordination contrasts with Streeck’s dynamic, sociological, “progressive” conception of “capitalist society”: … “a ‘progressive society’ in the sense of Adam Smith and the enlightenment … that has coupled its ‘progress’
Recommended publications
  • 1 Reading List for Field Exam in Stratification And
    1 Reading list for field exam in Stratification and Inequality Wednesday, November 14, 2012 Concepts Erik Olin Wright (ed.) 2005. Alternative Foundations of Class Analysis, Cambridge University Press. Duncan, Otis Dudley 1961. “A Socioeconomic Index for All Occupations”, Chapter 6 in Albert J. Reiss (ed.) Occupations and Social Status. Free Press. Hauser, Robert M. and John R. Warren. 1997. “Socioeconomic Indexes for Occupations: A Review, Update and Critique”. Sociological Methodology 27: 177-298. Weeden, Kim A. and David B. Grusky 2005. “The Case for a New Class Map” American Journal of Sociology 111: 141-212. Ganzeboom, Harry B. G., Paul M. DeGraaf, Donald J. Treiman. 1992. “A Standard International Socio-Economic Index of Occupational Status”. Social Science Research 21: 1-56. Sørenson, Aage B. 2000. “Toward a Sounder Basis for Class Analysis” American Journal of Sociology 105: 1523-58 (also following comments by Wright and Goldthorpe). Atkinson, Anthony B. 1983. The Economics of Inequality. Clarendon Press, Chapter 3. Inequality Davis, Kingsley and Wilbur E. Moore 1945. “Some Principles of Stratification” American Sociological Review 10: 242-49. Neckerman, Kathryn M. and Florencia Torche 2007. “Inequality: Causes and Consequences” Annual Review of Sociology 33: 335-357. Tumin, Melvin M. 1953. “Some Principles of Stratification: A Critical Analysis” American Sociological Review 18: 387-93. Treiman, Donald J. “Industrialization and Social Stratification” in Edward O. Laumann (ed) Social Stratification: Research and Theory for the 1970s. Bobbs-Merril, pp: 207-34. The Status Attainment Tradition 2 Blau, Peter M. and Otis Dudley Duncan. 1967. The American Occupational Structure Simon and Schuster, chapters 1 and 5.
    [Show full text]
  • Alec Campbell [email protected] Office Hours M 8-9 AM and by Apt Office A242
    Introduction to Sociology SOC 101 | Fall 2015 C164 | TTh 12:30-2:40pm Alec Campbell [email protected] Office Hours M 8-9 AM and by apt Office A242 Course Outcomes: After completing this class, students should be able to: Critically examine the social landscape in which you live and how life experiences differ according to race, class, gender and sexuality. Identify the ways in which cultural and social institutions shape the everyday experiences of individuals, groups and communities. Describe fundamental sociological concepts, and theories, and apply them to real-life situations. Texts There is no textbook for this class and no books to purchase. All class resources can be accessed through canvas or will be provided by the professor. Policies Student Attendance: Attendance is essential to your success in this course. I will take attendance every day and you will receive 10 points if you are in class on time and 5 points if you arrive late. There are 22 class meetings and a maximum of 200 attendance points so it is possible to miss two classes and still receive full credit for attendance. I will make accommodations for college sanctioned events (athletic contests, artistic performances, conferences) provided that you inform me of your anticipated absence in a timely fashion. An example of timely notification can be found in the tentative schedule. I will be attending a college sanctioned conference on November 5th and class is cancelled on that day. In any case, you will be responsible for material covered in your absence and for turning in any work due on the day of your absence.
    [Show full text]
  • Grodsky,Eric. Wisconsin. Spring 2016. Social Stratification
    Page 1 of 38 Sociology 923: Social Stratification Mondays, 2:10 to 4:40 PM, 6322 Sewell Office hours: Tuesday 2:30-3:30 or by appointment Instructor Eric Grodsky [email protected] 4454 Sewell Social Science Building Course Description This course is a graduate level seminar on social stratification. This is a difficult field to bound as it incorporates several subfields, including the study of gender, race/ethnicity, sociology of education and much of social demography. There’s a lot to cover. As a graduate seminar, this class relies heavily on your participation. I will seldom lecture, and when I do my lectures will be brief and most likely methodological in nature (enough information to get you through the readings). The substantive work of this course falls to you. I expect you to complete all of the readings on time, submit summaries in a timely fashion (described below), and attend every class unless you are SERIOUSLY ill or have some other very legitimate reason for not attending (religious, family emergency, etc.). You will take turns leading our discussions. Course format We will meet for 2 hours and 20 minutes each week, with a five-minute break somewhere in there. In addition to completing ALL of the readings that are required (denoted by a *), each of you will complete one or two article summaries most weeks. You will upload your summaries to the drop box on the course web page by 8:00 AM Friday each week. This will give your classmates time to review your summaries before we meet.
    [Show full text]
  • SOCIOLOGY 9191A Social Science in the Marxian Tradition Fall 2020
    SOCIOLOGY 9191A Social Science in the Marxian Tradition Fall 2020 DRAFT Class times and location Wednesday 10:30am -12:30pm Virtual synchronous Instructor: David Calnitsky Office Hours by appointment Department of Sociology Office: SSC 5402 Email: [email protected] Technical Requirements: Stable internet connection Laptop or computer Working microphone Working webcam “The philosophers have only interpreted the world, in various ways. The point, however, is to change it.” – Karl Marx That is the point, it’s true—but not in this course. This quote, indirectly, hints at a deep tension in Marxism. If we want to change the world we need to understand it. But the desire to change something can infect our understanding of it. This is a pervasive dynamic in the history of Marxism and the first step is to admit there is a problem. This means acknowledging the presence of wishful thinking, without letting it induce paralysis. On the other hand, if there are pitfalls in being upfront in your desire to change the world there are also virtues. The normative 1 goal of social change helps to avoid common trappings of academia, in particular, the laser focus on irrelevant questions. Plus, in having a set of value commitments, stated clearly, you avoid the false pretense that values don’t enter in the backdoor in social science, which they often do if you’re paying attention. With this caveat in place, Marxian social science really does have a lot to offer in understanding the world and that’s what we’ll analyze in this course. The goal is to look at the different hypotheses that broadly emerge out of the Marxian tradition and see the extent to which they can be supported both theoretically and empirically.
    [Show full text]
  • Erik Olin Wright, Editor
    Alternative Foundations of Class Analysis Erik Olin Wright, editor with contributions by Richard Breen David Grusky Jan Pakulski Aage Sorensen Elliott Weininger Erik Olin Wright December, 2002 Table of Contents Introduction page 1 Erik Olin Wright Chapter 1 Foundations of Class Analysis in the Marxist 6 Tradition Erik Olin Wright Chapter 2 Foundations of Class Analysis in the Weberian 41 Tradition Richard Breen Chapter 3 Foundations of Durkheimian class analysis 70 David Grusky Chapter 4 Foundations of Class Analysis in the work of 119 Bourdieu Elliott Weininger Chapter 5 Foundations of neo-Ricardian class analysis 180 Aage Sørensen Chapter 6 Foundations of Anti-Class analysis 215 Jan Pakulski INTRODUCTION In March 2001, on the morning BBC Radio news program, a report was presented discussing a new seven-category class scheme being used in the British Census. Listeners were invited to the BBC website to see what class they were in. Within a few days there were over 50,000 hits on the site, a record for this sort of thing. At least for the segment of the British population that listens to the BBC morning news, class remains a salient issue. In the broadcast a number of people were interviewed. One police inspector responded to being told that he was now classified in Class I along with doctors, lawyers and chief executives of corporations, by saying “Does it mean now I have to wear tennis whites when I go out to do my gardening?....I don’t see myself socially or economically in the same class as them.” In a subsequent “live chat” program with Professor David Rose of Essex University, the principle designer of the new census categories, many people called up complaining about the coding scheme.
    [Show full text]
  • Some Problems in Erik Olin Wright's Theory of Class
    International Letters of Social and Humanistic Sciences Online: 2014-06-27 ISSN: 2300-2697, Vol. 33, pp 20-40 doi:10.18052/www.scipress.com/ILSHS.33.20 CC BY 4.0. Published by SciPress Ltd, Switzerland, 2014 Some Problems in Erik Olin Wright’s Theory of Class Jacek Tittenbrun Faculty of Social Sciences, Adam Mickiewicz University, Wieniawskiego 1, Poznań, Poland E-mail address: [email protected] ABSTRACT Nowadays, Erik Olin Wright’s class theory is one of the most influential approaches to social differentiation, although in the mainstream social science the popularity of the so-called EGP class scheme is perhaps greater, Wright’s framework has virtually no rivals amongst Marxists and neo- Marxists. Both those considerations add to the relevance of the present paper, which is a critical analysis of some of the most salient issues present in the aforementioned framework. Indeed, it turns out that Wright’s flaws are more often than not shared by the remaining theorists dealing with social class or stratification. Nomen omen, one of those problems consists in failing to adequately distinguish between those two axes of differentiation. Perhaps the pivotal problem plaguing Wright’s framework concerns his flawed understanding of ownership that cannot but reflect on his definition of class and exploitation. Keywords: class; ownership; control; exploitation; Wright 1. INTRODUCTION Wright’s class theory involves several problems worthy of a more in-depth analysis. The objective of the paper is thus not a comprehensive presentation of Wright’s framework, but, rather, a discussion of some of those theoretical issues it raises.
    [Show full text]
  • The Legitimization of Bureaucratic Personality: an Exegesis of Weberian Theory
    THE LEGITIMIZATION OF BUREAUCRATIC PERSONALITY: AN EXEGESIS OF WEBERIAN THEORY By Scott M. Wallace A Thesis Presented to the Faculty of MCNAIR SCHOLARS PROGRAM UNIVERSITY OF WISCONSIN-SUPERIOR Under the Mentorship of Dr. Marshall Johnson, Sociology Superior, Wisconsin Summer, 2015 page 2 TABLE OF CONTENTS Abstract…………………………………………………………………………………..page 3 Introduction……………………………………………………………………………...page 3 Weber Reconsidered……………………………………………………………………..page 4 a. The Historical Context of Weber’s Social Theory…………………………… page 4 b. Bureaucracy and Rationalization………………………………………………page 5 c. The Nature of Political Interest and Domination………………………………page 7 Social Theory since Weber……………………………………………………………….page 10 a. The Cognitive Grounding of Bureaucratic Personalities………………………page 11 b. Contradictory Location of Bureaucrats………………………………………..page 14 c. Total Bureaucratization? A Case for Weber…………………………………..page 18 Sketches of the Modern Bureaucrat: Towards A Pilot Study……………………………page 21 Conclusion……………………………………………………………………………… page 22 References……………………………………………………………………………..... page 23 page 3 ABSTRACT The work of Max Weber has increasingly been seen as irrelevant to contemporary concerns within sociological theory. Although lauded as one of the foundational thinkers within the discipline, Weber has become a figure to either be dismissed as promoting archaic theories, or a pessimistic thinker that saw no way out of the ‘iron cage’ of rationalization. The present article establishes an alternative reading of Weber that pays close attention to his materialist understanding of how bureaucratic forms of power become legitimized through their being embodied in the habits of social agents socialized in bureaucratic institutions. A sketch for a future pilot study will also be presented based off of this reading of Weber. Introduction When one thinks about bureaucracy today, the most common images that come to peoples’ minds are largely negative: red tape, inefficiency, and lack of human warmth or connection.
    [Show full text]
  • Kearney 475 Syllabus Spring 2015
    Classical Sociological Theory Sociology 475 Spring 2015 Class meetings: 2:30-3:45 P.M. Mondays and Wednesdays Classroom: Ingraham 214 Instructor: Matthew Kearney E-mail: [email protected] Office location: Sewell Social Science Building, Room 3455 Office hours: 4-6 P.M. Mondays Introductory Comments This course has two complementary goals: 1. Students will learn how to construct theoretical arguments about empirical material. 2. Students will learn the basic concepts and approaches of canonical social theorists. Throughout the semester, we will attempt to bring these two goals together. That is, we will draw on canonical approaches in the process of constructing our own arguments about society. This means we understand what major theorists say, critique what they say, and then – potentially – modify their arguments to construct our own explanations of social phenomenon. The premise of this course is that we will construct better explanations after we have seriously studied the classical sociological theory. Notice that serious canonical study is not our end goal; it is only the first step. It is not enough to interpret the classical theories; the point is to change them. The class discussions, lectures, and paper assignments all aim at this goal: using the classical theorists to come to our own understanding of society. The fact that we are authorized to disagree with or modify canonical concepts does not mean we should do so lightly. We have to do serious study first, and we need to take that word 'serious' seriously. We do not discard a social theory until and unless we have an alternative theory of comparable scope with which to replace it.
    [Show full text]
  • Is a College Degree Still the Great Equalizer? Intergenerational
    Is a College Degree Still the Great Equalizer? Intergenerational Mobility across Levels of Schooling in the United States Author(s): Florencia Torche Reviewed work(s): Source: American Journal of Sociology, Vol. 117, No. 3 (November 2011), pp. 763-807 Published by: The University of Chicago Press Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/10.1086/661904 . Accessed: 10/11/2011 10:06 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. The University of Chicago Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to American Journal of Sociology. http://www.jstor.org Is a College Degree Still the Great Equalizer? Intergenerational Mobility across Levels of Schooling in the United States1 Florencia Torche New York University A quarter century ago, an important finding in stratification research showed that the intergenerational occupational association was much weaker among college graduates than among those with lower levels of education. This article provides a comprehensive assessment of the “meritocratic power” of a college degree. Drawing on five longitudinal data sets, the author analyzes intergenerational mobility in terms of class, occupational status, earnings, and household income for men and women. Findings indicate that the intergenerational association is strong among those with low educational attainment; it weakens or disappears among bachelor’s degree holders but reemerges among those with advanced degrees, leading to a U-shaped pattern of pa- rental influence.
    [Show full text]
  • Taking Socialism Seriously
    DRAFT Taking Socialism Seriously Edited by Anatole Anton and Richard Schmitt LEXINGTON BOOKS Lanham • Boulder • New York • Toronto • Plymouth, UK DRAFT Contents Introduction vii Richard Schmitt 1 Twenty-Five Questions about Socialism 1 Richard Schmitt 2 In Defense of Marxism 23 Milton Fisk 3 But What Is Your Alternative?: Reflections on Having a “Plan” 47 David Schweickart 1 Romantic Couple Love, the Affective Economy, and a Socialist-Feminist Vision 67 Ann Ferguson 5 Socialism, Post-Capitalism and the Division of Labor 85 Anatole Anton 6 Socialism and Human Nature 97 Karsten J. Struhl 7 Solidarity: The Elusive Road to Socialism 135 Richard Schmitt 8 Is Socialism Relevant in the “Networked Information Age”?: A Critical Assessment of The Wealth of Networks 155 Tony Smith 9 Beyond Capitalism and Socialism 185 Richard Schmitt 10 Social Movements and Struggles for Socialism 211 John L. Hammond DRAFT TEN Social Movements and Struggles for Socialism John L. Hammond [10.0] Social movements are the means by which masses of oppressed people struggle for social change. Relatively powerless people can amass and accumulate power, challenge their subordination, and win concessions from or overthrew existing power structures. The large numbers and strong commitment of participants can sometimes compensate for their lack of power. But they do more than struggle for power. They empower the participants themselves, create collective consciousness and organiza- tion, and shape the culture of the society in which they act. Participation in a social movement is a collective activity and thus is itself part of the preparation for life under socialism. [10.1] In this paper I examine the ways in which social movements can con- tribute to the struggle for socialism.
    [Show full text]
  • How Class Works in Popular Conception: Most Americans Identify with the Class Their Income, Occupation, and Education Implies for Them∗
    Final February 2007 How Class Works in Popular Conception: Most Americans Identify with the Class Their Income, Occupation, and Education Implies for Them∗ Michael Hout University of California, Berkeley Abstract Americans’ answers to questions about their social class show (1) awareness that class is an important aspect of American life and (2) reasonable patterns of strong associ- ation between subjective class identification and objective criteria like income, occu- pation, and education. Multivariate analysis of those responses shows that (3) class ambivalence and ambiguity is an issue for Americans whose jobs and incomes are inconsistent with their educations but (4) little evidence that other identities compete with objective class in forming class identities and (5) none of the trends that post- class theories suggest. Finally, subjective class identification correlates with a number of political attitudes and lifestyle indicators in ways that are consistent with canonical ideas about how class works. ∗This is a revision of the paper I presented at the conference “Social Class: How Does It Work?” held at New York University, 21-22 April 2006, sponsored by New York University and the Russell Sage Foundation. I thank Neil Fligstein, Michele Lamont, Annette Lareau, Jeff Manza, Erik Olin Wright, and two anonymous referees for their comments. Neither funders nor colleagues are responsible for the conclusions, opinions, or errors in this final version. 1 Introduction Marx and Engels founded class analysis with their famous claim, in The Communist Manifesto, that “The history of all hitherto existing societies is the history of class struggle.” Class analysts have struggled ever since to live down the founders’ boldness.
    [Show full text]
  • Beyond Neoliberalism
    BEYOND NEOLIBERALISM: SOCIAL JUSTICE AFTER THE WELFARE STATE Saturday, April 2, 8:30 am - 7 pm The Heyman Center Common Room, Columbia University Registration required; by invitation only, please (contact Lindsey Dayton [email protected]) Social Justice after the Welfare State, a Workshop led by Alice Kessler-Harris and Premilla Nadasen in the Center for the Study of Social Difference (CSSD) at Columbia, hosts a daylong symposium to explore the transformation of the Welfare state and social movements in the face of neoliberal challenges. We consider the implications of this transformation for the political economy of class, gender, racism, and migration. Putting scholars in conversation With activists Who address the fallout of neoliberalism on the ground, the symposium assesses the past, present, and future of government social responsibility and pays special attention to social rights and social justice. SCHEDULE 8:30 am Arrival and registration 9 - 10 am WELCOME Alice Kessler-Harris and Premilla Nadasen KEYNOTE ADDRESS Nancy MacLean, Duke University 10 - 10:15 am Break for coffee 10:15 am - 1:15 pm GRASSROOTS ORGANIZING Chair: Frances FOx Piven, CUNY Graduate Center Asha Rosa, Black Lives Matter and Black Youth Project Katherine Acey, Barnard Center for Research on Women Carlos Pacheco, anti-globalization activist Linda Oalican, Damayan Migrant Workers Association Michelina Ferrara, Atlas: DIY Joel Feingold, CroWn Heights Tenants Union 1:15 - 2:30 pm Break for lunch 2:30 – 5:45 pm UTOPIAN VISIONS Chair: Ruth Milkman, CUNY Graduate
    [Show full text]