Chaebol and Catastrophe: a New View of the Korean Business Groups and Their Role in the Financial Crisis*

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Chaebol and Catastrophe: a New View of the Korean Business Groups and Their Role in the Financial Crisis* Chaebol and Catastrophe Chaebol and Catastrophe: A New View of the Korean Business Groups and Their Role in the Financial Crisis* Robert C. Feenstra Abstract Department of Economics We present a model of industrial organization that has multiple One Shields Avenue University of California stable equilibria and argue that the high-concentration equilibrium Davis, CA 95616 describes Korea’s economy and the low-concentration equilib- [email protected] rium describes Taiwan’s economy. Past industrial policy of the Gary G. Hamilton state may have put Korea’s economy in the high-concentration Department of Sociology equilibrium, but discontinuation of the policy did not cause the in- Box 353340 University of Washington dustrial organization to change because this is an economically vi- Seattle, WA 98195 able equilibrium. [email protected] Eun Mie Lim The high-concentration equilibrium produces a narrower range of Department of Sociology final goods than the low-concentration equilibrium, which explains Box 353340 University of Washington why the 1996 collapse in semiconductor prices caused the less di- Seattle, WA 98195 versified Korean economy to contract more than the more diver- [email protected] sified Taiwanese economy. More importantly, this collapse in de- mand caused Korea’s economy to move to a new equilibrium that has a smaller number of business groups, as evidenced by the col- lapse of the second-tier chaebol and their absorption into the first-tier chaebol. This wave of bankruptcies, combined with the fi- nancially precarious state of the merchant banks, created an inves- tor panic that precipitated the crisis, which began with the 17 No- vember 1997 devaluation of the won. This is why economic fundamentals could explain the chaebol bankruptcies before that date and not those after that date. The logic of our model sug- gests that public policy should focus on reducing the vertical link- ages within business groups and not on reducing their horizontal linkages as the current “Big Deal” program of the government is doing. * This paper was prepared for the Asian Economic Panel confer- ence, Seoul, Korea, 25–26 October 2001. It draws upon the forth- coming book Emergent Economics, Divergent Paths: Business Groups and Economic Organization in South Korea and Taiwan, by Robert Feenstra and Gary Hamilton, Cambridge University Press, as well as the dissertation research of Eun Mie Lim. Asian Economic Papers 1:2 © 2002 the Center for International Development at Harvard University and the Massachusetts Institute of Technology Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/15353510260187373 by guest on 26 September 2021 Chaebol and Catastrophe 1. Introduction In the aftermath of the Asian ªnancial crisis, many economists in the United States have criticized the actions taken by the IMF, and in particular, its insistence that countries in crisis undertake contractionary monetary and ªscal policies as a condi- tion for receiving loans. Scholars such as Jeffrey Sachs (1998), Martin Feldstein (1998), and Joseph Stiglitz (2000) argue that imposition of this condition turned an initial liquidity crisis into a full-blown banking and ªnancial crisis. We have no disagreement with these criticisms of the IMF and with a re-thinking of its appropriate role; focusing on the IMF, however, distracts attention from the ques- tion of what happened in South Korea and other countries of Asia, and why. The IMF did not enter Korea until December 1997, and by that time the ªnancial crisis was fully under way. To understand the origins of the crisis we need to go at least some months earlier, before the exchange rate devaluation of 17 November 1997, and even before the exchange rate crises elsewhere in Asia. Let us start at least at the beginning of 1997. On 23 January 1997, the Hanbo Steel group in Korea declared bankruptcy. It was unprecedented that any chaebol in Korea would be permitted to go bankrupt, and this was followed in the subsequent months by the bankruptcies of well-known groups such as Sammi, Jinro, Hanshin, and then Kia in July, which was the eighth largest chaebol. Two years later, Daewoo became the ªrst instance of a top ªve chaebol that was permitted to go bankrupt. Including Daewoo, some 25 chaebol went bankrupt during 1997 and 1998, and fully 40 percent, or 10 out of 25, went bankrupt before the exchange rate crisis of 17 No- vember. Why did so many chaebol go bankrupt even before the exchange rate crisis, and what role did this play in the ªnancial crisis? It seems to us that these are the central questions that should be addressed and that need to be answered before Ko- rea pursues any reforms. It is impossible to answer these questions, however, with- out ªrst having a conceptual framework for thinking about the chaebol and their place in the economy. Perhaps the most common framework for thinking about business groups, or the in- tegration of ªrms more generally, is the transactions cost approach. Initiated by Ron- ald Coase and greatly extended by Oliver Williamson (1975, 1985), transactions cost research was designed to explain why some industries are vertically integrated and others are not. The transactions cost approach typically relies on different industry characteristics (such as asset speciªcity of investments) to explain the extent of verti- cal integration across industries. When these ideas are applied to the business groups in Asia, as some authors have done (e.g., Chang and Choi 1988; Levy 1991), 2 Asian Economic Papers Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/15353510260187373 by guest on 26 September 2021 Chaebol and Catastrophe problems in the approach become apparent. In the ªrst place, the same industry is often organized quite differently across different countries (such as Korea and Tai- wan), so transactions costs are clearly not speciªc to industries. Furthermore, some of the other factors that might inºuence the level of transactions costs, such as the reliance or nonreliance on formal contracts, are actually quite similar across Korea and Taiwan. So we are hard-pressed to identify the contribution of transactions costs to the differing structure of business groups across these countries. Government policies are another explanation for business groups, and the growth of the chaebol in South Korea is often attributed to the cheap credit that they received during the 1960s and 1970s. One drawback to this explanation, however, is that even when such policies are removed, the structure of business groups can remain intact for a considerable time, as happened in Korea. This is consistent with a policy-based explanation only if there is path dependence at work, that is, if past policies con- tinue to affect current structure. Path dependence, in turn, suggests the possibility of multiple equilibria in the structure of business groups, and this will be our focus in this paper. We shall rely on an alternative reason for the formation of groups, suggested by Ghemawat and Khanna (1998) and Khanna (2001), and that is the market power ex- planation: by horizontally integrating, groups achieve the beneªts of setting prices across multiple markets (Bernheim and Whinston 1990), and by vertically integrat- ing, upstream producers can offer preferential prices to those downstream, thereby increasing their joint proªts [as originally noted by Spengler (1950)]. We shall exam- ine the incentives for integration in a monopolistic competition model with multiple upstream and downstream producers. A business group is deªned as a set of produ- cers that jointly maximize proªts. Allowing for free entry of business groups and unafªliated ªrms, we demonstrate the presence of multiple equilibria in the economy that have varying degrees of verti- cal and horizontal integration. Thus, at given parameter values, we often ªnd a sta- ble high-concentration equilibrium, with a small number of strongly integrated busi- ness groups, and also a stable low-concentration equilibrium, with a larger number of less-integrated groups. The difference between these is that a small number of strongly integrated groups charge higher prices for external sales of the intermediate inputs, thereby inhibiting the entry of other business groups. The ªnding of multiple equilibria offers a new perspective on the business groups in Korea. The chaebol should not be viewed as responses to transactions costs, nor as simply the result of industrial policies in Korea. Instead, they should be thought of 3 Asian Economic Papers Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/15353510260187373 by guest on 26 September 2021 Chaebol and Catastrophe as one of a small number of organizational forms consistent with proªt maximiza- tion and free entry. That other countries have different group structures reºects the prevailing historical conditions that have shaped the direction of each economy. The policy choices in Korea can be thought of as establishing initial conditions of the economy, but the fact that the chaebol have grown as large as they have reºects the fact that these groups are a stable form of economic organization. Even signiªcant policy changes, such as the end of industrial policies favoring the chaebol, should not be expected to break up this type of organization. What about the effects of large shocks to the Korean economy, such as the Asian ªnancial crisis? As discussed in section 5, Korea experienced an abrupt fall in the growth and price of exports at the end of 1996. We view this as the proximate cause of the string of bankruptcies in 1997. In mathematical language, this is an example of a “catastrophe,” whereby a continuous change in some underlying variable (ex- ports) leads to a discontinuous change in a resulting variable (Woodcock and Davis 1978). Our hypothesis in this paper is that this notion of catastrophe may explain the string of bankruptcies in Korea during 1997, even before the exchange rate devalua- tion and ªnancial crisis.
Recommended publications
  • 2014 ESG Integrated Ratings of Public Companies in Korea
    2014 ESG Integrated Ratings of public companies in Korea Korea Corporate Governance Service(KCGS) annouced 2014 ESG ratings for public companies in Korea on Aug 13. With the ESG ratings, investors may figure out the level of ESG risks that companies face and use them in making investment decision. KCGS provides four ratings for each company which consist of Environmental, Social, Governance and Integrated rating. ESG ratings by KCGS are graded into seven levels: S, A+, A, B+, B, C, D. 'S' rating means that a company has all the system and practices that the code of best practices requires and there hardly exists a possibility of damaging shareholder value due to ESG risks. 'D' rating means that there is a high possibility of damaging shareholder value due to ESG risks. Company ESG Integrated Company Name Code Rating 010950 S-Oil Corporation A+ 009150 Samsung Electro-Mechanics Co., Ltd. A+ 000150 DOOSAN CORPORATION A 000210 Daelim Industrial Co., Ltd. A 000810 Samsung Fire & Marine Insurance Co., Ltd. A 001300 Cheil Industries Inc. A 001450 Hyundai Marine&Fire Insurance Co., Ltd. A 005490 POSCO. A 006360 GS Engineering & Construction Corp. A 006400 SAMSUNG SDI Co., Ltd. A 010620 Hyundai Mipo Dockyard Co., Ltd. A 011070 LG Innotek Co., Ltd. A 011170 LOTTE CHEMICAL CORPORATION A 011790 SKC Co., Ltd. A 012330 HYUNDAI MOBIS A 012450 Samsung Techwin Co., Ltd. A 023530 Lotte Shopping Co., Ltd. A 028050 Samsung Engineering Co., Ltd. (SECL) A 033780 KT&G Corporation A 034020 Doosan Heavy Industries & Construction Co., Ltd. A 034220 LG Display Co., Ltd.
    [Show full text]
  • The Korean Financial Crisis of 1997: Onset, Turnaround, and Thereafter, Which I Originally Authored in Korean in 2006
    The Korean Financial Crisis of 1997 Onset, Turnaround, and Thereafter Public Disclosure Authorized Kyu-Sung LEE Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized The Korean Financial Crisis of 1997 The Korean Financial Crisis of 1997 ONSET, TURNAROUND, AND THEREAFTER Kyu-Sung LEE © 2011 The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank and the Korea Development Institute 1818 H Street NW Washington DC 20433 Telephone: 202-473-1000 Internet: www.worldbank.org All rights reserved 1 2 3 4 14 13 12 11 The findings, interpretations, and conclusions herein are those of the author and do not reflect the views of the World Bank, its Board of Executive Directors or the governments they represent. The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The boundaries, colors, denominations, and other information shown on any map in this work do not imply any judgment on the part of The World Bank concerning the legal status of any territory or the endorse- ment or acceptance of such boundaries. Rights and Permissions The material in this publication is copyrighted. Copying and/or transmitting portions or all of this work without permission may be a violation of applicable law. The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank encourages dissemination of its work and will normally grant permission to reproduce portions of the work promptly. For permission to photocopy or reprint any part of this work, please send a request with complete information to the Copyright Clearance Center Inc., 222 Rosewood Drive, Danvers, MA 01923, USA; telephone: 978-750-8400; fax: 978-750-4470; Internet: www.copyright.com.
    [Show full text]
  • Samsung Press Information
    Company Overview History of Samsung Samsung's history dates to 1938 when "Samsung General Stores" opened in North Kyung- sang Province, Korea. The company conducted its trade business until the 1950s when it became a producer of basic commodities such as sugar and wool. In 1958, Samsung be- came involved in the insurance industry by incorporating a local fire & marine insurance company. During the 1960s, Samsung became one of the first Korean companies to actively expand its overseas trade. The group consolidated its manufacturing base by adding paper and fer- tilizer businesses. Samsung continued with expansion into the life insurance business, strengthened its retail operations and then moved into the communications sector, success- fully establishing a newspaper and a broadcasting company. The 1970s were a crucial period in shaping present-day Samsung. Its strengths in the semi- conductor, information and telecommunications industries grew from the significant in- vestments made during this period. Samsung also took a meaningful step toward heavy industries by venturing into aircraft manufacturing, shipbuilding and construction, as well as chemical industries. In the 1980s, Samsung expanded its efforts into exploring the larger markets overseas. The group began contributing to foreign economies by building facilities in the US, the UK and Portugal. Samsung also invested considerable resources into fostering Korea's rich heritage by supporting a wide range of cultural and artistic activities. The final decade of the 20th century saw the evolution of Samsung's new approach to management. Chairman Kun-Hee Lee's insightful vision and the introduction of the "New Management" in 1993 acknowledged the need to transform management philosophy in or- der to keep up with a rapidly changing global economy.
    [Show full text]
  • Chaebols and Catastrophe
    Chaebols and Catastrophe: A New View of the Korean Business Groups and Their Role in the Financial Crisis Robert C. Feenstra, University of California, Davis Gary H. Hamilton, University of Washington Eun Mie Lim, University of Washington October 2001 Prepared for the Asian Economic Policy conference, Seoul, Korea, October 25-26, 2001. This paper draws upon the forthcoming book, Emergent Economics, Divergent Paths: Business Groups and Economic Organization in South Korea and Taiwan, by Robert Feenstra and Gary Hamilton, Cambridge University Press, as well as the dissertation research of Eun Mie Lim. 1. Introduction The Asian financial crisis of 1997-98 seemed to end as quickly as it began, a grande finale to the 20th century. But as the opening years of the 21st century bring another slowdown, impacting the Asian economies as well as those worldwide, it is appropriate to ask what lessons we might learn from the crisis. What policy actions, if any, should South Korea take in relation to its industrial and financial structure, and could the type of catastrophic shock that occurred in 1997-98 be experienced again? In the aftermath of the crisis, many economists in the U.S. have criticized the actions taken by the International Monetary Fund (IMF), and in particular, their insistence that countries in crisis undertake contractionary monetary and fiscal policies as a condition of receiving loans. Scholars such as Jeffrey Sachs (1998) and Martin Feldstein (1998), along with Joseph Stiglitz (2000), argued that these conditions turned an initial liquidity crisis into a full-blown banking and financial crisis. A report commissioned by the U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • THE STRATEGIC MANAGEMENT of KOREAN and JAPANESE BIG BUSINESS GROUPS: a Comparison Study Between Korean General Trading Companies and Japanese Sogo Shoshas
    THE STRATEGIC MANAGEMENT OF KOREAN AND JAPANESE BIG BUSINESS GROUPS: A Comparison Study between Korean General Trading Companies and Japanese Sogo Shoshas by IN WOO JUN A thesis submitted to The University of Birmingham for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Management The Birmingham Business School The University of Birmingham August, 2009 University of Birmingham Research Archive e-theses repository This unpublished thesis/dissertation is copyright of the author and/or third parties. The intellectual property rights of the author or third parties in respect of this work are as defined by The Copyright Designs and Patents Act 1988 or as modified by any successor legislation. Any use made of information contained in this thesis/dissertation must be in accordance with that legislation and must be properly acknowledged. Further distribution or reproduction in any format is prohibited without the permission of the copyright holder. ABSTRACT This research is an in-depth study of Korean GTCs (General Trading Companies) and Japanese Sogo Shoshas (the Japanese version of General Trading Companies), which are unique big business conglomerates but not well-known in Western countries. It investigates and compares several of their features, such as their history, characteristics, functions, organisational structure, corporate culture, human resource management, their impact on national economic development, strategic management and decision-making process. First, it examines a wide range of literature to show the functions of Korean GTCs and Japanese Sogo Shoshas as transaction intermediaries, information gatherers, project organisers, international marketers, financial providers, etc. With these varied functions, they have played significant roles not only from the macro aspect, but also the micro aspect.
    [Show full text]
  • Korean CIO Survey 2008
    Korean CIO Survey 2008 Korean CIO Survey 2008 Innovation through IT for Business Results A comparison of Korean and global views on the role of the IT function in business innovation Innovation through IT for Business Results Table of Contents Foreword 1 Participating Companies and Organizations 2 Executive Summary 4 Innovation - A Definition 5 Business Innovation through IT for Delivering Results 6 Areas Where Innovation Delivers Results 8 Strategic IT Capabilities Beyond the IT Fundamentals 12 Building a Relationship for Business Innovation 16 Expanding the Network to Include External Partners 18 A New Start for the CIO as a Leader of Innovation 22 About the Survey 24 About Samsung SDS, OpenTide and Capgemini 25 Copyright © 2008 Samsung SDS, OpenTide and Capgemini. All rights reserved. Korean CIO Survey 2008 Foreword With the global economy changing rapidly, For that reason, this survey addresses the and uncertainty growing in the Korean role of the CIO and the IT function in market, it becomes more important, yet business innovation and proposes strategies more difficult, for organizations to make the that can put CIOs in a better position to right investment decisions. drive business innovation. Focusing on the right decisions and choices We thank all the CIOs who participated for is particularly critical during the current sharing their opinions with us. We value global economic turmoil. Because of the your effort and commitment. We hope considerable amount of investment and that this report will stimulate discussion costs involved in IT, it is more important about the role of the IT function in Korea, now than ever for CIOs to ask questions its relationship to the business and how it like: “is the IT function focused on business can add value by participating in business values and performing well against business innovation.
    [Show full text]
  • Chaebols and Firm Dynamics in Korea
    Chaebols and firm dynamics in Korea Philippe Aghion, Sergei Guriev, Kangchul Jo Abstract We study firm dynamics in Korea before and after the 1997-98 Asian crisis and pro-competitive reforms that reduced the dominance of chaebols. We find that in industries that were dominated by chaebols before the crisis, labor productivity and TFP of non-chaebol firms increased markedly after the reforms (relative to other industries). Furthermore, entry of non-chaebol firms increased significantly in all industries after the reform. Finally, after the crisis, non-chaebol firms also significantly increased their patenting activity (relative to non-chaebol firms). These results are in line with a neo-Schumpeterian view of transition from a growth model based on investment in existing technologies to an innovation-based model. Keywords: Schumpeterian growth, chaebols, Asian crisis JEL Classification Number: O43, L25 Contact details: Sergei Guriev, One Exchange Square, London EC2A 2JN, United Kingdom Phone: +44 20 7338 6805; Fax: +44 20 7338 6111; email: [email protected] Philippe Aghion, College de France and London School of Economics Phone: +33 1 44 27 17 06; email: [email protected] Kangchul Jo, London School of Economics Phone: +44 7477 006402; email: [email protected] Sergei Guriev is Chief Economist at the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, Professor of Economics at the Institut d’´etudes politiques de Paris (Sciences Po) and Research Fellow at the Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR). Philippe Aghion is a Professor of Economics at the College de France and London School of Economics. Kangchul Jo is a doctoral student at London School of Economics.
    [Show full text]
  • How Can Non‐Chaebol Companies Thrive in the Chaebol Economy? 非财阀公司如何在财阀经济中生存? ‐公司层面营销战略的分析‐
    28 N.K. Kim, S. Sengupta, D.J. Kim / Journal of Global Academy of Marketing Science 19-3 (2009) 28-36 How Can Non‐Chaebol Companies Thrive in the Chaebol Economy? 非财阀公司如何在财阀经济中生存? ‐公司层面营销战略的分析‐ Nam Kuk Kim1)*, Sanjit Sengupta2), Dong‐jae Kim3)1) Abstract perform better than Niche players. Proposition 2: Firms that have no product similarity with a While existing literature has focused extensively on the Chaebol will perform better than firms that have product strengths and weaknesses of the Chaebol and their ownership similarity. and governance, there have been few studies of Korean non‐ Proposition 2a: Partners (suppliers or complementors) will Chaebol firms. However, Lee, Lee and Pennings (2001) did perform better than Co‐existers. not specifically investigate the competitive strategies that non‐ Proposition 2b: Niche players will perform better than Chaebol firms use to survive against the Chaebol in the Competitors. domestic Korean market. The motivation of this paper is to Proposition 3: Niche players should perform better than Co‐ document, through four exploratory case studies, the successful existers. competitive strategies of non‐Chaebol Korean companies against Proposition 4: Performance can be rank‐ordered in descending the Chaebol and then offer some propositions that may be order as Partners, Niche Players, Co‐existers, Competitors. useful to other entrepreneurial firms as well as public policy A team of experts was constituted to categorize each of makers. these 216 non‐Chaebol companies into one of the 4 cells in Competition and cooperation as conceptualized by product our typology. Simple Analysis of Variance (ANOVA) in SPSS similarity and cooperative inter‐firm relationship respectively, statistical software was used to test our propositions.
    [Show full text]
  • Samsung Electronics and Apple, Inc.: a Study in Contrast
    International Journal of Engineering and Advance Technology Studies Vol. 3, No.1, pp.16-26, March 2015 Published by European Centre for Research Training and Development UK (www.eajournals.org) SAMSUNG ELECTRONICS AND APPLE, INC.: A STUDY IN CONTRAST IN COMPETITIVE ANALYSIS IN 21ST CENTURY Rawal Rasheed, Raheel Nawaz, Yasir Abbas 1-The Islamia University of Bahawalpur Pakistan. 2- The Islamia University of Bahawalpur Pakistan. 3- The Islamia University of Bahawalpur Pakistan. ABSTRACT: Samsung Electronic devices are one of the biggest technological innovation company currently, provides a new paradigm on how top to bottom incorporated companies nowadays function. Technologies have been modifying how value stores and markets work, so much so that how side to side, top to bottom incorporated components are considered nowadays are modifying, too. While the Samsung controls much of their value stores, they, too, delegate some of the stores to another. This business design allows them to develop on their proficiencies and, at the same time, to reduce deal costs, which allows them to fulfill the requirements of a very powerful technological innovation market. This study contains the financial analysis of the Samsung and its competitor Apple as well as the industry in which Samsung is performing, and it also contains the unique issues that Samsung is facing in these days. This study is beneficial to the academic readers and for a lot of firms, by this study, these firms can understand the issues that are impacting financial performance and position of different firms. This study provided help in commerce field, IT field, Business field and as well as professionals and the readers attaining the benefit to understand the market trends and the current performance of the multinational leader in electronics and mobile phone industry.
    [Show full text]
  • Modern Korean Economy: 1948–2008 Written by Yongjin Park
    UNDERSTANDING KOREA SERIES No. 1 Hangeul Written by Lee Ji-young Understanding Korea No. 8 No. 2 Early Printings in Korea outh Korea is known for its rapid and continuous economic ECONOMY ECONOMY KOREAN MODERN Written by Ok Young Jung Sgrowth in the latter half of the 20th century. After liberation from Japanese colonial rule in 1945 and the Korean War About the series No. 3 Korean Confucianism: Tradition and Modernity (1950‒53), Korea has seen its per capita GDP shooting up from Written by Edward Y. J. Chung just US$290 in 1960 to an amazing US$28,384 in 2010. The Understanding Korea Series aims to share a variety MODERN KOREAN of original and fascinating aspects of Korea with those This book looks at the country’s modern economic overseas who are engaged in education or are deeply No. 4 Seoul development starting from the end of the Korean War, the Written by Park Moon-ho interested in Korean culture. economic problems Korea faced after the conflict, efforts to solve ECONOMY No. 5 A Cultural History of the Korean House these problems, and the results produced. It will also describe 1948–2008 Written by Jeon BongHee changes in economic policy objectives from liberation from Japanese colonial rule in 1945 through today in detail. No. 6 Korea’s Religious Places Written by Mark Peterson Yongjin Park No. 7 Geography of Korea Written by Kwon Sangcheol, Kim Jonghyuk, Lee Eui-Han, Jung Chi-Young No. 8 Modern Korean Economy: 1948–2008 Written by Yongjin Park ISBN 979-11-5866-427-5 Not for sale Cover Photo The night view of Seoul © gettyimages Korea Cover Design Jung Hyun-young, Cynthia Fernandez Modern Korean Economy Understanding Korea No.
    [Show full text]
  • Chaebols, the Engine of the Korean Economy: a Case Study of the Samsung Group
    Department of Business and Management Chair of Corporate Strategies Chaebols, the engine of the Korean economy: a case study of the Samsung Group SUPERVISOR Prof.ssa Federica Brunetta CANDIDATE Immacolata Andolfo Id. No 687771 CO-SUPERVISOR Prof.ssa Karynne Turner ACADEMIC YEAR 2017/2018 A mamma e papà, la mia forza, la mia ancora ed il mio sostegno più grande. Summary Introduction .............................................................................................................. 3 Chapter 1: Inside Korean Chaebol ..........................................................................6 1.1 History of Chaebols ........................................................................................... 6 1.2 Corporate Governance ..................................................................................... 11 1.3 Chaebols’ Institution Based-View ................................................................... 18 1.4 Strengths and Weaknesses ............................................................................... 21 1.4.1 Weaknesses ............................................................................................... 21 1.4.2 Strengths ................................................................................................... 23 1.4.2.1 Do chaebols support innovation? ....................................................... 25 1.5 Multiplex Ties Between Korean Business Groups .......................................... 27 1.6 A New Era for Chaebols? ...............................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Korea Corporate Governance Service(KCGS) Annouced 2014 ESG Ratings for Public Companies in Korea on Aug 13
    2014 Governance Ratings of public companies in Korea Korea Corporate Governance Service(KCGS) annouced 2014 ESG ratings for public companies in Korea on Aug 13. With the ESG ratings, investors may figure out the level of ESG risks that companies face and use them in making investment decision. KCGS provides four ratings for each company which consist of Environmental, Social, Governance and Integrated rating. ESG ratings by KCGS are graded into seven levels: S, A+, A, B+, B, C, D. 'S' rating means that a company has all the system and practices that the code of best practices requires and there hardly exists a possibility of damaging shareholder value due to ESG risks. 'D' rating means that there is a high possibility of damaging shareholder value due to ESG risks. Company Governance Company Name Code Rating 000060 Meritz Fire & Marine Insurance Co., Ltd. A+ 002550 LIG Non-Life Insurance Co., Ltd. A+ 005490 POSCO. A+ 005830 Dongbu Insurance Co., Ltd. A+ 010950 S-Oil Corporation A+ 017670 SK Telecom Co., Ltd. A+ 019680 Daekyo Co., Ltd. A+ 030200 KT Corporation A+ 033780 KT&G Corporation A+ 053000 Woori Finance Holdings Co., Ltd. A+ 055550 Shinhan Financial Group Co., Ltd. A+ 086790 Hana Financial Group Inc. A+ 138930 BS Financial Group Inc. A+ 000150 DOOSAN CORPORATION A 000210 Daelim Industrial Co., Ltd. A 000810 Samsung Fire & Marine Insurance Co., Ltd. A 001450 Hyundai Marine&Fire Insurance Co., Ltd. A 003550 LG Corp. A 003690 Korean Reinsurance Company A 005930 Samsung Electronics Co., Ltd. A 005940 Woori Investment & Securities Co., Ltd. A 006220 THE BANK OF CHEJU A - 1 - Company Governance Company Name Code Rating 009150 Samsung Electro-Mechanics Co., Ltd.
    [Show full text]