Chaebol and Catastrophe: a New View of the Korean Business Groups and Their Role in the Financial Crisis*
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
Chaebol and Catastrophe Chaebol and Catastrophe: A New View of the Korean Business Groups and Their Role in the Financial Crisis* Robert C. Feenstra Abstract Department of Economics We present a model of industrial organization that has multiple One Shields Avenue University of California stable equilibria and argue that the high-concentration equilibrium Davis, CA 95616 describes Korea’s economy and the low-concentration equilib- [email protected] rium describes Taiwan’s economy. Past industrial policy of the Gary G. Hamilton state may have put Korea’s economy in the high-concentration Department of Sociology equilibrium, but discontinuation of the policy did not cause the in- Box 353340 University of Washington dustrial organization to change because this is an economically vi- Seattle, WA 98195 able equilibrium. [email protected] Eun Mie Lim The high-concentration equilibrium produces a narrower range of Department of Sociology final goods than the low-concentration equilibrium, which explains Box 353340 University of Washington why the 1996 collapse in semiconductor prices caused the less di- Seattle, WA 98195 versified Korean economy to contract more than the more diver- [email protected] sified Taiwanese economy. More importantly, this collapse in de- mand caused Korea’s economy to move to a new equilibrium that has a smaller number of business groups, as evidenced by the col- lapse of the second-tier chaebol and their absorption into the first-tier chaebol. This wave of bankruptcies, combined with the fi- nancially precarious state of the merchant banks, created an inves- tor panic that precipitated the crisis, which began with the 17 No- vember 1997 devaluation of the won. This is why economic fundamentals could explain the chaebol bankruptcies before that date and not those after that date. The logic of our model sug- gests that public policy should focus on reducing the vertical link- ages within business groups and not on reducing their horizontal linkages as the current “Big Deal” program of the government is doing. * This paper was prepared for the Asian Economic Panel confer- ence, Seoul, Korea, 25–26 October 2001. It draws upon the forth- coming book Emergent Economics, Divergent Paths: Business Groups and Economic Organization in South Korea and Taiwan, by Robert Feenstra and Gary Hamilton, Cambridge University Press, as well as the dissertation research of Eun Mie Lim. Asian Economic Papers 1:2 © 2002 the Center for International Development at Harvard University and the Massachusetts Institute of Technology Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/15353510260187373 by guest on 26 September 2021 Chaebol and Catastrophe 1. Introduction In the aftermath of the Asian ªnancial crisis, many economists in the United States have criticized the actions taken by the IMF, and in particular, its insistence that countries in crisis undertake contractionary monetary and ªscal policies as a condi- tion for receiving loans. Scholars such as Jeffrey Sachs (1998), Martin Feldstein (1998), and Joseph Stiglitz (2000) argue that imposition of this condition turned an initial liquidity crisis into a full-blown banking and ªnancial crisis. We have no disagreement with these criticisms of the IMF and with a re-thinking of its appropriate role; focusing on the IMF, however, distracts attention from the ques- tion of what happened in South Korea and other countries of Asia, and why. The IMF did not enter Korea until December 1997, and by that time the ªnancial crisis was fully under way. To understand the origins of the crisis we need to go at least some months earlier, before the exchange rate devaluation of 17 November 1997, and even before the exchange rate crises elsewhere in Asia. Let us start at least at the beginning of 1997. On 23 January 1997, the Hanbo Steel group in Korea declared bankruptcy. It was unprecedented that any chaebol in Korea would be permitted to go bankrupt, and this was followed in the subsequent months by the bankruptcies of well-known groups such as Sammi, Jinro, Hanshin, and then Kia in July, which was the eighth largest chaebol. Two years later, Daewoo became the ªrst instance of a top ªve chaebol that was permitted to go bankrupt. Including Daewoo, some 25 chaebol went bankrupt during 1997 and 1998, and fully 40 percent, or 10 out of 25, went bankrupt before the exchange rate crisis of 17 No- vember. Why did so many chaebol go bankrupt even before the exchange rate crisis, and what role did this play in the ªnancial crisis? It seems to us that these are the central questions that should be addressed and that need to be answered before Ko- rea pursues any reforms. It is impossible to answer these questions, however, with- out ªrst having a conceptual framework for thinking about the chaebol and their place in the economy. Perhaps the most common framework for thinking about business groups, or the in- tegration of ªrms more generally, is the transactions cost approach. Initiated by Ron- ald Coase and greatly extended by Oliver Williamson (1975, 1985), transactions cost research was designed to explain why some industries are vertically integrated and others are not. The transactions cost approach typically relies on different industry characteristics (such as asset speciªcity of investments) to explain the extent of verti- cal integration across industries. When these ideas are applied to the business groups in Asia, as some authors have done (e.g., Chang and Choi 1988; Levy 1991), 2 Asian Economic Papers Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/15353510260187373 by guest on 26 September 2021 Chaebol and Catastrophe problems in the approach become apparent. In the ªrst place, the same industry is often organized quite differently across different countries (such as Korea and Tai- wan), so transactions costs are clearly not speciªc to industries. Furthermore, some of the other factors that might inºuence the level of transactions costs, such as the reliance or nonreliance on formal contracts, are actually quite similar across Korea and Taiwan. So we are hard-pressed to identify the contribution of transactions costs to the differing structure of business groups across these countries. Government policies are another explanation for business groups, and the growth of the chaebol in South Korea is often attributed to the cheap credit that they received during the 1960s and 1970s. One drawback to this explanation, however, is that even when such policies are removed, the structure of business groups can remain intact for a considerable time, as happened in Korea. This is consistent with a policy-based explanation only if there is path dependence at work, that is, if past policies con- tinue to affect current structure. Path dependence, in turn, suggests the possibility of multiple equilibria in the structure of business groups, and this will be our focus in this paper. We shall rely on an alternative reason for the formation of groups, suggested by Ghemawat and Khanna (1998) and Khanna (2001), and that is the market power ex- planation: by horizontally integrating, groups achieve the beneªts of setting prices across multiple markets (Bernheim and Whinston 1990), and by vertically integrat- ing, upstream producers can offer preferential prices to those downstream, thereby increasing their joint proªts [as originally noted by Spengler (1950)]. We shall exam- ine the incentives for integration in a monopolistic competition model with multiple upstream and downstream producers. A business group is deªned as a set of produ- cers that jointly maximize proªts. Allowing for free entry of business groups and unafªliated ªrms, we demonstrate the presence of multiple equilibria in the economy that have varying degrees of verti- cal and horizontal integration. Thus, at given parameter values, we often ªnd a sta- ble high-concentration equilibrium, with a small number of strongly integrated busi- ness groups, and also a stable low-concentration equilibrium, with a larger number of less-integrated groups. The difference between these is that a small number of strongly integrated groups charge higher prices for external sales of the intermediate inputs, thereby inhibiting the entry of other business groups. The ªnding of multiple equilibria offers a new perspective on the business groups in Korea. The chaebol should not be viewed as responses to transactions costs, nor as simply the result of industrial policies in Korea. Instead, they should be thought of 3 Asian Economic Papers Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/15353510260187373 by guest on 26 September 2021 Chaebol and Catastrophe as one of a small number of organizational forms consistent with proªt maximiza- tion and free entry. That other countries have different group structures reºects the prevailing historical conditions that have shaped the direction of each economy. The policy choices in Korea can be thought of as establishing initial conditions of the economy, but the fact that the chaebol have grown as large as they have reºects the fact that these groups are a stable form of economic organization. Even signiªcant policy changes, such as the end of industrial policies favoring the chaebol, should not be expected to break up this type of organization. What about the effects of large shocks to the Korean economy, such as the Asian ªnancial crisis? As discussed in section 5, Korea experienced an abrupt fall in the growth and price of exports at the end of 1996. We view this as the proximate cause of the string of bankruptcies in 1997. In mathematical language, this is an example of a “catastrophe,” whereby a continuous change in some underlying variable (ex- ports) leads to a discontinuous change in a resulting variable (Woodcock and Davis 1978). Our hypothesis in this paper is that this notion of catastrophe may explain the string of bankruptcies in Korea during 1997, even before the exchange rate devalua- tion and ªnancial crisis.