<<

UNDERSTANDING THE EFFECTS OF ON

Jordi Galí Javier Vallés CREI and Universitat Pompeu Fabra Economic Bureau of Spanish Prime Minister J. David López-Salido Federal Reserve Board

Abstract Recent evidence suggests that consumption rises in response to an increase in government spending. That finding cannot be easily reconciled with existing optimizing models. Weextend the standard new Keynesian model to allow for the presence of rule-of-thumb consumers. We show how the interaction of the latter with sticky prices and deficit financing can account for the existing evidence on the effects of government spending. (JEL: E32, E62)

1. Introduction

What are the effects of changes in government purchases on aggregate economic activity? How are those effects transmitted? Even though such questions are central to and its ability to inform , there is no widespread agreement on their answer. In particular, though most macroeconomic models predict that a rise in government purchases will have an expansion- ary effect on , those models often differ regarding the implied effects on consumption. Because the latter variable is the largest component of aggregate

Acknowledgments: We wish to thank Alberto Alesina, Javier Andrés, Florin Bilbiie, Günter Coenen, Gabriel Fagan, Eric Leeper, Ilian Mihov, Valery Ramey, Michael Reiter, Jaume Ventura, Lutz Weinke, co-editor Roberto Perotti, two anonymous referees, and seminar participants at the Bank of , Bank of England, CREI-UPF, IGIER-Bocconi, INSEAD, York, Salamanca, NBER Summer Institute 2002, the 1st Workshop on Dynamic Macroeconomics at Hydra, the EEA Meetings in Stockholm, and the 2nd International Research Forum on for useful comments and suggestions. Galí acknowledges the financial support and hospitality of the Banco de España, and CREA-Barcelona and MCyT (grant SEJ 2005-01124) for research support. Anton Nakov provided excellent research assistance. This paper was written while the last two authors worked at the Research Department of the Banco de España. The opinions and analyses are the responsibility of the authors and, therefore, do not necessarily coincide with those of the Banco de España, the Eurosystem, the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, or any other person associated with the Federal Reserve System. E-mail addresses: Galí: [email protected]; López-Salido: [email protected]; and Vallés: [email protected]

Journal of the European Economic Association March 2007 5(1):227–270 © 2007 by the European Economic Association

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 227 — #1 228 Journal of the European Economic Association , its response is a key determinant of the size of the government spending multiplier. The standard RBC and the textbook IS-LM models provide a stark example of such differential qualitative predictions. The standard RBC model generally predicts a decline in consumption in response to a rise in government purchases of and services (henceforth, government spending, for ). In contrast, the IS-LM model predicts that consumption should rise, hence amplifying the effects of the expansion in government spending on output. Of course, the rea- son for the differential impact across those two models lies in how consumers are assumed to behave in each case. The RBC model features infinitely-lived Ricardian households, whose consumption decisions at any point in time are based on an intertemporal budget constraint. Ceteris paribus, an increase in gov- ernment spending lowers the present value of after- income, thus generating a negative wealth effect that induces a cut in consumption.1 By way of contrast, in the IS-LM model consumers behave in a non-Ricardian fashion, with their consumption being a function of their current disposable income and not of their lifetime resources. Accordingly, the implied effect of an increase in government spending will depend critically on how the latter is financed, with the multiplier increasing with the extent of deficit financing.2 What does the existing empirical evidence have to say regarding the con- sumption effects of changes in government spending? Can it help discriminate between the two paradigms, on the grounds of the observed response of consump- tion? A number of recent empirical papers shed some light on those questions. They all apply multivariate time series methods in order to estimate the responses of consumption and a number of other variables to an exogenous increase in government spending. They differ, however, on the assumptions made in order to identify the exogenous component of that variable. In Section 2 we describe in some detail the findings from that literature that are most relevant to our pur- poses, and provide some additional empirical results of our own. In particular,

1. The mechanisms underlying those effects are described in detail in Aiyagari, Christiano, and Eichenbaum (1990), Baxter and King (1993), Christiano and Eichenbaum (1992), and Fatás and Mihov (2001), among others. In a nutshell, an increase in (non-productive) government purchases, financed by current or future lump-sum , has a negative wealth effect which is reflected in lower consumption. It also induces a rise in the quantity of labor supplied at any given wage. The latter effect leads, in equilibrium, to a lower real wage, higher and higher output. The increase in employment leads, if sufficiently persistent, to a rise in the expected return to , and may trigger a rise in . In the latter case the size of the multiplier is greater or less than one, depending on parameter values. 2. See, for example, Blanchard (2003). The total effect on output will also depend on the investment response. Under the assumption of a constant , generally maintained in textbook versions of that model, the rise in consumption is accompanied by an investment decline (resulting from a higher ). If instead the holds the interest rate steady in the face of the increase in government spending, the implied effect on investment is nil. However, any “intermediate” response of the central bank (i.e., one that does not imply full accommodation of the higher money demand induced by the rise in output) will also induce a fall in investment in the IS-LM model.

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 228 — #2 Galí et al. Effects of Government Spending on Consumption 229 and like several other authors that preceded us, we find that a positive government spending leads to a significant increase in consumption, while investment either falls or does not respond significantly. Thus, our evidence seems to be con- sistent with the predictions of models with non-Ricardian consumers and hard to reconcile with those of the neoclassical paradigm. After reviewing the evidence, we turn to our paper’s main contribution: The development of a simple dynamic general equilibrium model that can potentially account for that evidence. Our framework shares many ingredients with recent dynamic optimizing sticky price models, though we modify the latter by allow- ing for the presence of rule-of-thumb behavior by some households.3 Following Campbell and Mankiw (1989), we assume that rule-of-thumb consumers do not borrow or save; instead, they are assumed to consume their current income fully. In our model, rule-of-thumb consumers coexist with conventional infinite-horizon Ricardian consumers. The introduction of rule-of-thumb consumers in our model is motivated by an extensive empirical literature pointing to substantial deviations from the perma- nent income hypothesis. Much of that literature provides evidence of “excessive” dependence of consumption on current income. That evidence is based on the analysis of aggregate time series,4 as well as natural experiments using micro data (e.g., response to anticipated tax refunds).5 That evidence also seems consis- tent with the observation that a significant fraction of households have near-zero net worth.6 On the basis of that evidence, Mankiw (2000) calls for the systematic incorporation of non-Ricardian households in macroeconomic models, and for an examination of the policy implications of their presence. As further explained below, the existence of non-Ricardian households cannot in itself generate a positive response of consumption to a rise in government spending. To see this, consider the following equilibrium condition

mpnt = µt + ct + ϕnt , where mpnt , ct , and nt represent the (logs) of the marginal product of labor, con- sumption, and hours worked, respectively. The term ct + ϕnt represents the (log) marginal rate of substitution, with parameter ϕ>0 measuring the curvature of the marginal disutility of labor. Variable µt is thus the wedge between the marginal rate of substitution and the marginal product of labor, and can be interpreted as the sum of both the (log) wage and price markups, as discussed in Galí, Gertler, and López-Salido (2007).

3. See, for example, Rotemberg and Woodford (1999), Clarida, Galí, and Gertler (1999), or Woodford (2003) for a description of the standard new Keynesian model. 4. See, for example, Campbell and Mankiw (1989) and Deaton (1992) and references therein. 5. See, for example, Souleles (1999) and Johnson, Parker, and Souleles (2004). 6. See, for example, Wolff (1998).

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 229 — #3 230 Journal of the European Economic Association

Consider first an economy with a constant wedge, µt = µ for all t. Notice that the particular case of µ = 0 corresponds to the perfectly competitive case often assumed in the RBC literature. According to both theory and evidence, an increase in government purchases raises hours and, under standard assumptions, lowers the marginal product of labor. Thus, it follows that consumption must drop if the previous condition is to be satisfied. Hence, a necessary condition for consumption to rise in response to a fiscal expansion is the existence of a simulta- neous decline in the wedge µt . This motivates the introduction in our framework of the assumption of sticky prices in goods markets and, at least in one version of our model, of imperfectly competitive labor markets. Those complementary assumptions interact with the presence of non-Ricardian consumers in a way that makes it possible to reverse the sign of the response of consumption to changes in government spending. As described subsequently, our model predicts responses of aggregate consumption and other variables that are in line with the existing evidence, given plausible calibrations of the fraction of rule-of-thumb consumers, the degree of price stickiness, and the extent of deficit financing. Beyond the narrower focus of the present paper, a simple lesson emerges from our analysis: Allowing for deviations from the strict Ricardian behavior assumed in the majority of existing macro models may be required in order to capture important aspects of the economy’s workings.7 Our proposed framework, based on the simple model of rule-of-thumb consumers of Campbell and Mankiw (1989), although admittedly ad-hoc, provides in our view a good starting point. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the existing empirical literature and provides some new evidence. Section 3 lays out the model and its different blocks. Section 4 contains an analysis of the model’s equilibrium dynamics. Section 5 examines the equilibrium response to a government spending shock under alternative calibrations, focusing on the response of consumption and its consistency with the existing evidence. Section 6 summarizes the main findings of the paper and points to potential extensions and directions for further research.

2. An Overview of the Evidence

In the present section we start by summarizing the existing evidence on the response of consumption (and some other variables) to an exogenous increase in government spending, and providing some new evidence of our own. Most of the existing evidence relies on structural vector autoregressive models, with different papers using alternative identification schemes. Unfortunately, the data does not seem to speak with a single voice on this issue: Although some papers

7. In a companion paper (Galí, López-Salido, and Vallés 2004), we study the implications of rule-of-thumb consumers for the stability properties of Taylor-type rules.

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 230 — #4 Galí et al. Effects of Government Spending on Consumption 231 uncover a large, positive, and significant response of consumption, others find that such a response is small and often insignificant. As far as we know, however, there is no evidence in the literature pointing to the large and significant nega- tive consumption response that would be consistent with the predictions of the neoclassical model. Blanchard and Perotti (2002) and Fatás and Mihov (2001) identify exogenous shocks to government spending by assuming that the latter variable is predeter- mined relative to the other variables included in the VAR. Their most relevant findings for our purposes can be summarized as follows. First, a positive shock to government spending leads to a persistent rise in that variable. Second, the implied fiscal expansion generates a positive response in output, with the asso- ciated multiplier being greater than one in Fatás and Mihov, but close to one in Blanchard and Perotti. Third, in both papers the fiscal expansion leads to large (and significant) increases in consumption. Fourth, the response of investment to the spending shock is found to be insignificant in Fatás and Mihov, but negative (and significant) in Blanchard and Perotti. Here we provide some complementary evidence using an identification strat- egy similar to the above mentioned papers. Using U.S. quarterly data, we estimate the responses of several macroeconomic variables to a government spending shock. The latter is identified by assuming that government purchases are not affected contemporaneously (i.e., within the quarter) by the innovations in the other variables contained in a vector autoregression (VAR).8 Our VAR includes a measure of government spending, GDP, hours worked, consumption of non- durables and services, private nonresidential investment, the real wage, the budget deficit, and personal disposable income. In a way consistent with the model devel- oped herein, both government spending and the budget deficit enter the VAR as a ratio to trend GDP, where the latter is proxied by (lagged) potential output. The remaining variables are specified in logs, following convention.9

8. Qualitatively, the results herein are robust to the use of military spending (instead of total government purchases) as a predetermined variable in the VAR, as in Rotemberg and Woodford (1992). 9. We use quarterly U.S. data over the period 1954:I–2003:IV. The series were drawn from Estima’s USECON database (acronyms reported in brackets below). These include government (Federal + State + Local) consumption and gross investment expenditures (GH), (GDPH), a measure of aggregate hours obtained by multiplying total civilian employment (LE) by weekly average hours in manufacturing (LRMANUA), nonfarm business hours (LXNFH), the real compensation per hour in the nonfarm business sector (LXNFR), consumption of nondurable and services (CNH + CSH), non-residential investment (FNH), and the CBO estimate of potential GDP (GDPPOTHQ). All quantity variables are in log levels, and normalized by the size of the civil- ian population over 16 years old (LNN). We included four lags of each variable in the VAR. Our deficit measure corresponds to gross government investment (GFDI + GFNI + GSI) minus gross government savings (obtained from the FRED-II database). The resulting variable, expressed in nominal terms, was normalized by the lagged trend nominal GDP (GDPPOTQ). Finally, disposable income corresponds to real personal disposable income, also drawn from the FRED-II.

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 231 — #5 232 Journal of the European Economic Association

Figure 1. The dynamic effects of a government spending shock. Note: Estimated impulse responses to a government spending shock in the large VAR. Sample Period 1954:I–2003:IV. The horizontal axis represents quarters after the shock. Confidence intervals correspond ±1 standard deviations of empir- ical distributions, based on 1,000 Monte Carlo replications. The right bottom panel plots the point estimates of both consumption (solid line) and disposable income (dashed line).

Figure 1 displays the estimated impulse responses. Total government spend- ing rises significantly and persistently, with a half-life of about four years. Output rises persistently in response to that shock, as predicted by the theory. Most inter- estingly, however, consumption is also shown to rise on impact and to remain persistently above zero. A similar pattern is displayed by disposable income; in fact, as shown in the bottom right graph, the response of consumption tracks, almost one-for-one, that of disposable income. With respect to the labor variables, our point estimates imply that both hours and the real wage rise persistently in response to the fiscal shock, although with some delay relative to government spending itself.10 By contrast, investment falls slightly in the short run, though the response is not significant. Finally, the deficit rises significantly on impact, remaining positive for about two years. Our point estimates in Figure 1 imply a government spending multiplier on output, dYt+k/dGt ,of0.78 on impact (k = 0), and of 1.74 at the end of the second year (k = 8). Such estimated multipliers are of a magnitude similar to the ones reported by Blanchard and Perotti (2002). They are also roughly consistent with the range of estimated short-run expenditure multipliers generated by a variety of

10. Fatás and Mihov (2001) also uncover a significant rise in the real wage in response to a spending shock, using compensation per hour in the non-farm business sector as a measure of the real wage. The positive comovement between hours and the real wage in response to a shock in military spending was originally emphasized by Rotemberg and Woodford (1992). See also Rotemberg and Woodford (1995).

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 232 — #6 Galí et al. Effects of Government Spending on Consumption 233

Table 1. Estimated effects of government spending shocks.

Estimated Fiscal Multipliers Implied Output Consumption Fiscal Parameters

1stQ 4thQ 8thQ 1stQ 4thQ 8thQ ρg φg φb 1948:I–2003:IV Baseline spending Small VAR 0.51 0.31 0.28 0.04 0.09 0.19 0.85 0.10 0.10 Larger VAR 0.41 0.31 0.68 0.07 0.11 0.49 0.80 0.06 0.06 Excluding military Small VAR 0.15 -0.12 0.34 -0.11 0.24 0.32 0.95 0.005 0.60 Larger VAR 0.36 0.62 1.53 0.03 0.51 0.68 0.94 0.005 0.60

1954:I–2003:IV Baseline spending Small VAR 0.74 0.75 1.22 0.14 0.46 0.73 0.95 0.13 0.20 Larger VAR 0.68 0.70 1.74 0.17 0.29 0.95 0.95 0.10 0.30 Excluding military Small VAR 0.63 1.95 2.60 0.25 1.41 1.12 0.95 0.05 0.50 Larger VAR 0.74 2.37 3.50 0.37 1.39 1.76 0.95 0.01 0.50

1960:I–2003:IV Baseline spending Small VAR 0.91 1.05 1.32 0.19 0.59 0.84 0.95 0.13 0.20 Larger VAR 0.81 0.44 0.76 0.20 0.25 0.45 0.95 0.08 0.20 Excluding military Small VAR 0.72 1.14 1.19 0.17 0.78 0.68 0.94 0.03 0.50 Larger VAR 1.13 1.89 2.08 0.40 1.14 1.07 0.98 0.01 0.55 Note: Large VAR corresponds to the 8-variable VAR described in the text; Small VAR estimates are based on a 4-variable VAR including government spending, output, consumption, and the deficit. Government spending excluding military was obtained as GFNEH + GSEH + GFNIH + GSIH. For each specification ρg is the AR(1) coefficient that matches the half-life of the estimated government spending response. Parameter φg is obtained as the difference of the VAR-estimated impact effects of government spending and deficit, respectively. Finally, given ρg and φg , we calibrate the parameter φb such that the dynamics of government spending (21) and (37) are consistent with the horizon at which the deficit is back to steady state, matching our empirical VAR responses of the fiscal deficit. macroeconometric models.11 Most important for our purposes is the observation that the multiplier on consumption is always positive, going from 0.17 on impact to 0.95 at the end of the second year. Table 1 illustrates the robustness of these findings to alternative specifications of the VAR, including number of variables (4 vs. 8 variables), sample period (full postwar, post–Korean war, and post-1960), and definition of government spending (excluding and including military spending).12 panel of the table reports the size of the multipliers on output and consumption at different horizons (on impact, one-year, and two-year horizons, respectively).13 Although the exact

11. See Hemming, Kell, and Mahfouz (2002) and the survey of the evidence provided in IMF (2004, Chap. 2). 12. See Table 1 for details. 13. The right panel is used herein for the purposes of model calibration.

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 233 — #7 234 Journal of the European Economic Association size of the estimated multipliers varies somewhat across specifications, the central finding of a positive response of consumption holds for the vast majority of cases.14 As previously mentioned, some papers in the literature call into question (or at least qualify) the previous evidence. Perotti (2004) applies the methodology of Blanchard and Perotti (2002) to several OECD countries. He emphasizes the evidence of subsample instability in the effects of government spending shocks, with the responses in the 1980s and 1990s being more muted than in the earlier period. Nevertheless, the sign and magnitude of the response of private con- sumption in Perotti’s estimates largely mimics that of GDP, both across countries and across sample periods. Hence, his findings support a positive comovement between consumption and income, conditional on government spending shocks, in a way consistent with the model developed herein (though at odds with the neoclassical model).15 Mountford and Uhlig (2004) apply the agnostic identification procedure orig- inally proposed in Uhlig (2005) to identify and estimate the effects of a “” and a “deficit spending” shock.16 They find that government spending shocks crowd out both residential and non-residential investment, but they hardly change consumption (the response of the latter is small and insignificant). Ramey and Shapiro (1998) use a narrative approach to identify shocks that raise military spending, and which they codify by means of a dummy variable (widely known as the “Ramey-Shapiro dummy”). They find that nondurable con- sumption displays a slight, though hardly significant decline, whereas durables consumption falls persistently, but only after a brief but quantitatively large rise on impact. They also find that the product wage decreases, even though the real wage remains pretty much unchanged.17 Several other papers have used subsequently the identification scheme pro- posed by Ramey and Shapiro in order to study the effects of exogenous changes in government spending on different variables. Thus, Edelberg, Eichenbaum, and Fisher (1999) show that a Ramey-Shapiro episode triggers a fall in real wages, an increase in non-residential investment, and a mild and delayed fall in the con- sumption of nondurables and services, though durables consumption increases on impact. More recent work by Burnside, Eichenbaum, and Fisher (2003) using

14. The only exception corresponds to the small VAR specification over the full sample period and excluding military spending. Yet the underlying impulse responses (not shown) indicate that the slightly negative impact effect on consumption is quickly reversed in that case. 15. The response of private investment to the same shock tends to be negative, especially in the second sample period. 16. This method is based on sign and near-zero restrictions on impulse responses. 17. Ramey and Shapiro (1998) provide a potential explanation of the comovements of consumption and real wages in response to a change in military spending, based on a two-sector model with costly capital reallocation across sectors, and in which military expenditures are concentrated in one of the two sectors (manufacturing).

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 234 — #8 Galí et al. Effects of Government Spending on Consumption 235 a similar approach reports a flat response of aggregate consumption in the short run, followed by a small (and insignificant) rise in that variable several quarters after the Ramey-Shapiro episode is triggered. Another branch of the literature, exemplified by the work of Giavazzi and Pagano (1990), has uncovered the presence of “non-Keynesian effects” (i.e., neg- ative spending multipliers) during large fiscal consolidations, with output rising significantly despite large cuts in government spending. In particular, Perotti (1999) finds evidence of a negative comovement of consumption and govern- ment spending during such episodes of fiscal consolidation (and hence large spending cuts), but only in circumstances of “fiscal stress” (defined by unusually high debt/GDP ratios). In “normal” times, however, the estimated effects have the opposite sign, that is, they imply a positive response of consumption to a rise in government purchases. Nevertheless, as shown in Alesina and Ardagna (1998), the evidence of non-Keynesian effects during fiscal consolidations can hardly be interpreted as favorable to the neoclassical model because, on average, cuts in government spending raise both output and consumption during those episodes.18 Overall, we view the evidence discussed as tending to favor the predictions of the traditional Keynesian model over those of the neoclassical model. In particular, none of the evidence appears to support the kind of strong negative comovement between output and consumption predicted by the neoclassical model in response to changes in government spending. Furthermore, in trying to understand some of the empirical discrepancies discussed above it is worth emphasizing that the bulk of the papers focusing on the response to changes in government spending in “ordinary” times tend to support the traditional Keynesian hypothesis, in contrast with those that focus on “extraordinary” fiscal episodes (associated with wars or with large fiscal consolidations triggered by explosive debt dynamics). In light of those considerations, we view the model developed herein as an attempt to account for the effects of government spending shocks in “normal” times, as opposed to extraordinary episodes. Accordingly, we explore the condi- tions under which a dynamic general equilibrium model with nominal rigidities and rule-of-thumb consumers can account for the positive comovement of con- sumption and government purchases that arises in response to small exogenous variations in the latter variable.

3. A New Keynesian Model with Rule-of-Thumb Consumers

The economy consists of two types of households, a continuum of firms producing differentiated intermediate goods, a perfectly competitive firm producing a final good, a central bank in charge of monetary policy, and a fiscal authority. Next

18. See Table 6 in Alesina and Ardagna (1998).

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 235 — #9 236 Journal of the European Economic Association we describe the objectives and constraints of the different agents. Except for the presence of rule-of-thumb consumers, our framework consists of a standard dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model with staggered price setting à la Calvo.19

3.1. Households

We assume a continuum of infinitely lived households, indexed by i ∈[0, 1]. A fraction 1 − λ of households have access to capital markets where they can trade a full set of contingent securities, and buy and sell physical capital (which they accumulate and rent out to firms). We use the term optimizing or Ricardian to refer to that subset of households. The remaining fraction λ of households do not own any assets nor have any liabilities, and just consume their current labor income. We refer to them as rule-of-thumb households. Different inter- pretations for that behavior include myopia, lack of access to capital markets, fear of saving, ignorance of intertemporal trading opportunities, and so forth. Our assumptions imply an admittedly extreme form of non-Ricardian behavior among rule-of-thumb households, but one that captures in a simple and parsimonious way some of the existing evidence, without invoking a specific explanation. Campbell and Mankiw (1989) provide some aggregate evidence, based on estimates of a modified Euler equation, of the quantitative importance of such rule-of-thumb consumers in the U.S. and other industrialized economies.20

o o Optimizing households. Let Ct , and Lt represent consumption and leisure for optimizing households. Preferences are defined by the discount factor β ∈ (0, 1) o o and the period utility U(Ct ,Lt ). A typical household of this type seeks to maximize ∞ t o o E0 β U(Ct ,Nt ), (1) t=0 subject to the sequence of budget constraints

o + o + −1 o = o + k o + o + o − o Pt (Ct It ) Rt Bt+1 Wt Pt Nt Rt Pt Kt Bt Dt Pt Tt (2)

19. Most of the recent monetary models with nominal rigidities abstract from capital accumulation. A list of exceptions includes King and Watson (1996), Yun (1996), Dotsey (1999), Kim (2000) and Dupor (2002). In our framework, the existence of a mechanism to smooth consumption over time is important in order for the distinction between Ricardian and non-Ricardian consumers to be meaningful, thus justifying the need for introducing capital accumulation explicitly. 20. Mankiw (2000) reviews more recent microeconomic evidence consistent with that view.

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 236 — #10 Galí et al. Effects of Government Spending on Consumption 237 and the capital accumulation equation o o = − o + It o Kt+1 (1 δ)Kt φ o Kt . (3) Kt

o At the beginning of the period the consumer receives labor income Wt Pt Nt , o where Wt is the real wage, Pt is the price level, and Nt denotes hours of work. o He also receives income from renting his capital holdings Kt to firms at the (real) k o rental cost Rt . Bt is the quantity of nominally riskless one-period bonds carried over from period t −1, and paying one unit of the numéraire in period t. Rt denotes o the gross nominal return on bonds purchased in period t. Dt are dividends from o ownership of firms, Tt denotes lump-sum taxes (or transfers, if negative) paid by o o these consumers. Ct and It denote, respectively, consumption and investment expenditures, in real terms. Pt is the price of the final good. Capital adjustment o o o costs are introduced through the term φ(It /Kt )Kt , which determines the change o  in the capital stock induced by investment spending It . We assume φ > 0, and φ ≤ 0, with φ(δ) = 1, and φ(δ) = δ. In what follows we specialize the period utility—common to all households—to take the form

N 1+ϕ U(C,L) ≡ log C − , 1 + ϕ where ϕ ≥ 0. The first order conditions for the optimizing consumer’s problem can be written as Pt 1 = Rt Et t,t+1 , (4) P + t 1 I o = k + − + − t+1  Qt Et t,t+1 Rt+1 Qt+1 (1 δ) φt+1 o φt+1 , (5) Kt+1 = 1 Qt o , (6)  It φ o Kt where t,t+k is the stochastic discount factor for real k-period ahead payoffs given by

− Co 1 ≡ k t+k t,t+k β o (7) Ct

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 237 — #11 238 Journal of the European Economic Association and where Qt is the (real) shadow value of capital in place, namely, Tobin’s Q. Notice that, under our assumption on φ, the elasticity of the investment-capital ratio with respect to Q is given by −1/φ(δ)δ ≡ η.21 We consider two alternative labor market structures. First we assume a competitive labor market, with each household choosing the quantity of hours supplied given the market wage. In that case the optimality conditions must be supplemented with the first-order condition = o o ϕ Wt Ct (Nt ) . (8) Under our second labor market structure wages are set in a centralized manner by an economy-wide union. In that case hours are assumed to be determined by firms (instead of being chosen optimally by households), given the wage set by the union. Households are willing to meet the demand from firms, under the assumption that wages always remain above all households’ marginal rate of substitution. In that case condition (8) no longer applies. We refer the reader to Section 3.6 and Appendix A for a detailed description of the labor market under this alternative assumption.

Rule-of-thumb households. Rule-of-thumb households are assumed to behave in a “hand-to-mouth” fashion, fully consuming their current labor income. They do not smooth their consumption path in the face of fluctuations in labor income, nor do they intertemporally substitute in response to changes in interest rates. As noted we do not take a stand on the sources of that behavior, though one may possibly attribute it to a combination of myopia, lack of access to financial markets, or (continuously) binding borrowing constraints. Their period utility is given by

r r U(Ct ,Lt ), (9) and they are subject to the budget constraint r = r − r Pt Ct Wt Pt Nt Pt Tt . (10) Accordingly, the level of consumption will equate labor income net of taxes: r = r − r Ct Wt Nt Tt . (11)

r Notice that we allow taxes paid by rule-of-thumb households (Tt ) to dif- o fer from those of the optimizing households (Tt ). Under the assumption of a

21. See Basu and Kimball (2003) for a critical assessment of the predictions of new Keynesian models with endogenous capital accumulation and a proposal for reconciling those predictions with some of the evidence, based on the notion of costly investment planning.

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 238 — #12 Galí et al. Effects of Government Spending on Consumption 239 competitive labor market, the labor supply of rule-of-thumb households must satisfy = r r ϕ Wt Ct (Nt ) . (12) Alternatively, when the wage is set by a union, hours are determined by firms’ labor demand, and (8) does not apply. Again we refer the reader to the subsequent discussion.

Aggregation. Aggregate consumption and hours are given by a weighted average of the corresponding variables for each consumer type. Formally, ≡ r + − o Ct λCt (1 λ)Ct (13) and ≡ r + − o Nt λNt (1 λ)Nt . (14) Similarly, aggregate investment and the capital stock are given by ≡ − o It (1 λ)It and ≡ − o Kt (1 λ)Kt .

3.2. Firms

We assume a continuum of monopolistically competitive firms producing dif- ferentiated intermediate goods. The latter are used as inputs by a (perfectly competitive) firm producing a single final good.

Final goods firm. The final good is produced by a representative, perfectly competitive firm with a constant returns technology:

εp − 1 εp−1 εp 1 ε Yt = Xt (j) p dj , 0 where Xt (j) is the quantity of intermediate good j used as an input and εp > 1. Profit maximization, taking as given the final goods price Pt and the prices for the intermediate goods Pt (j), all j ∈[0, 1], yields the set of demand schedules −εp Pt (j) Xt (j) = Yt , Pt

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 239 — #13 240 Journal of the European Economic Association as well as the zero-profit condition

1 1 1−εp 1−εp Pt = Pt (j) dj . 0

Intermediate goods firm. The production function for a typical intermediate goods firm (say, the one producing good j)isgivenby

α 1−α Yt (j) = Kt (j) Nt (j) , (15)

22 where Kt (j) and Nt (j) represent the capital and labor services hired by firm j. Cost minimization, taking the wage and the rental cost of capital as given, implies K (j) α W t = t . − k Nt (j) 1 α Rt Real marginal cost is common to all firms and given by = k α 1−α MCt (Rt ) (Wt ) , where ≡ α−α(1 − α)−(1−α).

Price setting. Intermediate firms are assumed to set nominal prices in a stag- gered fashion, according to the stochastic time dependent rule proposed by Calvo (1983). Each firm resets its price with probability 1−θ each period, independently of the time elapsed since the last adjustment. Thus, each period a measure 1 − θ of producers reset their prices, while a fraction θ keep their prices unchanged. A firm resetting its price in period t will seek to solve ∞ k ∗ − max Et θ Et t,t+kYt+k(j) (Pt /Pt+k) MCt+k , P ∗ t k=0 subject to the sequence of demand constraints ∗ − = = εp Yt+k(j) Xt+k(j) (Pt /Pt+k) Yt+k, ∗ and where Pt represents the price chosen by firms resetting prices at time t. The first-order condition for this problem is ∞ k ∗ − p = θ Et t,t+kYt+k(j) (Pt /Pt+k) µ MCt+k 0, (16) k=0

22. Without loss of generality we normalize total factor productivity to unity.

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 240 — #14 Galí et al. Effects of Government Spending on Consumption 241

p where µ ≡ εp/(εp − 1) is the gross “frictionless” price markup, and the one prevailing in a zero inflation steady state. Finally, the equation describing the dynamics for the aggregate price level is given by

1 1−ε ∗ − 1−ε = p + − 1 εp p Pt θPt−1 (1 θ)(Pt ) . (17)

3.3. Monetary Policy

In our baseline model the central bank is assumed to set the nominal interest rate rt ≡ Rt − 1 every period according to a simple linear interest rate rule:

rt = r + φπ πt , (18) where φπ ≥ 0 and r is the steady state nominal interest rate. An interest rate rule of the form (18) is the simplest specification in which the conditions for indeterminacy and their connection to the Taylor principle can be analyzed. Notice that it is a particular case of the celebrated Taylor rule (1993), corresponding to a zero coefficient on the output gap, and a zero inflation target. Rule (18) is said to satisfy the Taylor principle if and only if φπ > 1. As is well known, in the absence of rule-of-thumb consumers, that condition is necessary and sufficient to guarantee the uniqueness of equilibrium.23

3.4.

The government budget constraint is + −1 = + Pt Tt Rt Bt+1 Bt Pt Gt , (19) ≡ r + − o ≡ − ≡ − where Tt λTt (1 λ) Tt . Letting gt (Gt G)/Y , tt (Tt T)/Y, and bt ≡ ((Bt /Pt−1) − (B/P ))/Y , we henceforth assume a fiscal policy rule of the form

tt = φbbt + φggt , (20) where φb and φg are positive constants. Finally, government purchases (in deviations from steady state, and normal- ized by steady state output) are assumed to evolve exogenously according to a first order autoregressive process

gt = ρggt−1 + εt , (21)

23. The “Taylor principle” refers to a property of interest rate rules for which an increase in inflation eventually leads to a more than one-for-one rise in the nominal interest rate (see Woodford 2003).

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 241 — #15 242 Journal of the European Economic Association where 0 <ρg < 1, and εt represents an i.i.d. government spending shock with 2 constant variance σε .

3.5. Market Clearing

The clearing of factor and good markets requires that the following conditions are satisfied for all t: 1 Nt = Nt (j) dj, Yt (j) = Xt (j) for all j, 0 1 Kt = Kt (j) dj, Yt = Ct + It + Gt . (22) 0

3.6. Linearized Equilibrium Conditions

In the present section we derive the log-linear versions of the key optimality and market-clearing conditions that will be used in our analysis of the model’s equilib- rium dynamics. Some of these conditions hold exactly, whereas others represent first-order approximations around a zero-inflation steady state. Henceforth, and unless otherwise noted, lower-case letters denote log-deviations with respect to the corresponding steady state values (i.e., xt ≡ log Xt /X).

Households. Next we list the log-linearized versions of the defined households’ optimality conditions, expressed in terms of the aggregate variables. The log- linear equations describing the dynamics of Tobin’s Q and its relationship with investment are given respectively by

= { }+[ − − ] { k }− − { } qt βEt qt+1 1 β(1 δ) Et rt+1 (rt Et πt+1 ) (23) and

it − kt = ηqt . (24)

The log-linearized capital accumulation equation is

kt+1 = δit + (1 − δ)kt . (25)

The log-linearized Euler equation for optimizing households is given by

o = { o }− − { } ct Et ct+1 (rt Et πt+1 ) . (26)

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 242 — #16 Galí et al. Effects of Government Spending on Consumption 243

Consumption for rule-of-thumb households is given, to a first order approx- imation, by WNr Y cr = (w + nr ) − tr , (27) t Cr t t Cr t r ≡ r − r where tt (Tt T )/Y . As shown in the Appendix B, the analysis is simplified by assuming that steady state consumption is the same across household types, that is, Cr = Co = C, an outcome that can always be guaranteed by an appropriate choice of T r and T o. Because the focus of our paper is on the differential responses to shocks, as opposed to steady state differences across households, we view that assumption as being largely innocuous, while simplifying the algebra considerably.24 In par- ticular, under the above assumption, the log-linearized expressions for aggregate consumption and hours take the following simple form: = r + − o ct λct (1 λ)ct , (28) = r + − o nt λnt (1 λ)nt . (29) Under perfectly competitive labor markets, we can log-linearize expressions (8) and (12) and combine them with (28) and (29) to obtain

wt = ct + ϕnt . (30) Under the assumption of imperfectly competitive labor markets, one can also interpret equation (30) as a log-linear approximation to a generalized wage schedule of the form Wt = H(Ct ,Nt ). In that case, and under the assumption that each firm decides how much labor to hire (given the wage), firms will allocate labor demand uniformly across households, independently of their type. Accordingly, r = o 25 we will have Nt Nt for all t. In Appendix A we show how a wage schedule of that form arises in an economy in which wages are set by unions in order to maximize a weighted average of the utility of both types of households. Independently of the assumed labor market structure we can derive an intertemporal equilibrium condition for aggregate consumption of the form = { }− − { } − { }+ { r } ct Et ct+1 σ (rt Et πt+1 ) nEt nt+1 τ Et tt+1 . (31)

24. Notice that under perfectly competitive labor markets marginal rates of substitution are equal- ized across households. The assumption of equal consumption levels in the steady state thus implies that N r = N o = N as well. As discussed below, under our alternative labor market structure equal- ity of hours across household types holds independently of their relative level of consumption. See Appendix A for details. 25. We implicitly assume that the resulting wage markup is sufficiently high (and fluctuations j ϕ = sufficiently small) that the inequalities H(Ct ,Nt )>Ct Nt for j r, o are satisfied at all times. Both conditions guarantee that both type of households will be willing to meet firms’ labor demand at the prevaling wage. Notice also that consistency with balanced-growth requires that H can be written as Ct h(Nt ) (which happens to be consistent with [30]).

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 243 — #17 244 Journal of the European Economic Association

In the case of perfectly competitive labor markets, the previous equa- tion results from combining equations (8), (12), (26), (27), (28), and (29), the associated coefficients are given by

p σ ≡ (1 − λ)[µ ϕγc + (1 − α)],

n ≡ λ(1 − α)(1 + ϕ)ϕ, p t ≡ λµ ϕ,

p −1 where  ≡ (µ ϕγc +(1−α)(1−λ(1+ϕ))) , and γc ≡ C/Y is the steady state consumption-output ratio (which, does not depend on λ, as shown in Appendix B). See Appendix C for details of the derivation. By contrast, under the assumption of an imperfectly competitive labor market, (31) can be derived from combining equations (30), (26), (27), (28), (29), as well r = o = as the assumption nt nt nt . In that case the expressions for the coefficients in (31) are given by

p σ ≡ (1 − λ)γcµ ,

n ≡ λ(1 − α)(1 + ϕ), p t ≡ λµ ,

p −1 where  ≡ (γcµ − λ(1 − α)) . Notice that independently of the labor market structure assumed we have limλ→0 σ = 1, limλ→0 n = 0, and limλ→0 τ = 0—that is, as the fraction of rule-of-thumb consumers becomes negligible, the aggregate Euler equation approaches its standard form given our utility specification.

Discussion. A number of features of these equilibrium conditions are worth stressing. First, notice that the Euler equation (31) is the only log-linear equilib- rium condition involving aggregate variables which displays a dependence on λ, the fraction of rule-of-thumb households. Second, the presence of rule-of-thumb households generates a direct effect of employment on the level of consumption (and, thus, on ), beyond the effect of the -term interest rate. This can be seen by “integrating” (31) to obtain the following expression in levels: ∞ = − r − { − } ct nnt τ tt σ Et rt+k πt+k+1 . k=0 Thus, for any given path of real interest rates and taxes, an expansion in government purchases has the potential to raise aggregate consumption through its induced expansion in employment and the consequent rise in the real wage,

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 244 — #18 Galí et al. Effects of Government Spending on Consumption 245 labor income and, as a result, consumption of rule-of-thumb households. In turn, the resulting increase in consumption would raise aggregate demand, output, and employment even further, thus triggering a multiplier effect analogous to the one found in traditional Keynesian models. Third, the ultimate effect of government purchases on aggregate consumption depends on the response of taxes (accruing to rule-of-thumb households) and the expected long-term real rate. Those responses will, in turn, be determined by the fiscal and monetary policy rules in place. Nevertheless, it is clear from the previous equation that in order for aggregate consumption to increase in response to a rise in government spending, the response of taxes and interest rates should be sufficiently muted. We return to this point below, when analyzing the sensitivity of our results to alternative calibrations of those policies.

Firms. Log-linearization of (16) and (17) around the zero inflation steady state yields the familiar equation describing the dynamics of inflation as a function of the log deviations of the average markup from its steady-state level

= { }− ˆ p πt βEt πt+1 λpµt , (32)

−1 where λp = (1 − βθ)(1 − θ)θ and, ignoring constant terms, ˆ p = − − µt (yt nt ) wt , (33) or, equivalently,

ˆ p = − − k µt (yt kt ) rt . (34)

Furthermore, as shown in Woodford (2003), the following “aggregate production function” holds, up to a first-order approximation:

yt = (1 − α)nt + αkt . (35)

Market clearing. Log-linearization of the market-clearing condition of the final good around the steady state yields

yt = γcct + γiit + gt , (36) where γi ≡ I/Y represents the share of investment on output in the steady state.

Fiscal policy. Linearization of the government budget constraint (19) around a steady state with zero debt and a balanced primary budget yields

bt+1 = (1 + ρ)(bt + gt − tt ),

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 245 — #19 246 Journal of the European Economic Association where ρ ≡ β−1 − 1 pins down the steady state interest rate. Plugging in the fiscal policy rule previously assumed, we obtain

bt+1 = (1 + ρ)(1 − φb)bt + (1 + ρ)(1 − φg)gt . (37)

Hence, under our assumptions, a necessary and sufficient condition for non- explosive debt dynamics is given by (1 + ρ)(1 − φb)<1, or equivalently ρ φb > . 1 + ρ

4. Analysis of Equilibrium Dynamics

Combining all the equilibrium conditions and doing some straightforward, though tedious, substitutions we can obtain a system of stochastic difference equations describing the log-linearized equilibrium dynamics of the form

AEt {xt+1}=Bxt + εt , (38)  where xt ≡ (nt ,ct ,πt ,kt ,bt ,gt−1) . The elements of matrices A and B are all functions of the underlying structural parameters, as shown in Appendix C. We start by describing the calibration that we use as a benchmark. Each period is assumed to correspond to a quarter. We set the discount factor β equal to 0.99. We assume a steady state price markup µp equal to 0.2. The rate of depreciation δ is set to 0.025. The elasticity of output with respect to capital, α, is assumed to be 1/3, a value roughly consistent with observed income shares, given the assumed steady state price markup. All the previous parameter values remain unchanged in the analysis below. Next we turn to the parameters for which we conduct some sensitivity analysis, distinguishing between the non-policy and the policy parameters. Our baseline setting for the weight of rule-of-thumb households λ is 1/2. This is within the range of estimated values in the literature of the weight of the rule-of-thumb behavior (see Mankiw 2000). The fraction of firms that keep their prices unchanged, θ, is given a baseline value of 0.75, which corresponds to an average price duration of one year. We set the baseline value for the elasticity of wages with respect to hours (ϕ) equal to 0.2. This is consistent with Rotemberg and Woodford’s (1997, 1999) calibration of the elasticity of wages with respect to output of 0.3 combined with an elasticity of output with respect to hours of 2/3. Finally, we follow King and Watson (1996), and set η (the elasticity of investment with respect to q) equal to 1.0 in our baseline calibration. The baseline policy parameters are chosen as follows. We set the size of the response of the to inflation, φπ ,to1.5, a value commonly used in empirical Taylor rules (and one that satisfies the so-called Taylor principle).

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 246 — #20 Galí et al. Effects of Government Spending on Consumption 247

In order to calibrate the parameters describing the fiscal policy rule (20) and the government spending shock (21) (i.e., φg, φb, and ρg) we use the VAR- based estimates of the dynamic responses of government spending and deficit (see Table 1 for details). In particular, we set the baseline value of the parameter ρg = 0.9 that matches the half-life of the responses of government spending. The latter value reflects the highly persistent response of government spending to its own shock. We obtain the values of the parameter φg from the difference between the estimated impact responses of government spending and deficit, respectively. As can be seen from Table 1, our (average) estimates suggest a value for that parameter equal to 0.10. Interestingly, the estimates in Table IV of Blanchard and Perotti (2002) imply a corresponding estimate of 0.13, very much in line with our estimates and baseline calibration. Given ρg and φg, we calibrate parameter φb such that the dynamics of government spending (21) and debt (37) are consistent with the horizon at which the deficit is back to zero in our estimates. Hence, in our baseline calibration we set φb = 0.33, in line with the estimated averages for different subsamples, as described in Table 1. Finally, we set γg = 0.2, which roughly corresponds to the average share of government purchases in GDP in postwar U.S. data. Much of the sensitivity analysis below focuses on the share of rule-of-thumb households (λ) and its interaction with parameters ρg, θ, η, ϕ, and φπ .Given the importance of the fiscal rule parameters in the determination of aggregate consumption (and, indirectly, of other variables) we will also analyze the effect of alternative values for the policy parameters φb and φg.

4.1. Rule-of-Thumb Consumers, Indeterminacy, and the Taylor Principle

Next we provide a brief analysis of the conditions that guarantee the uniqueness of equilibrium. A more detailed analysis of those conditions for an economy similar to the one considered here (albeit without a fiscal block) can be found in Galí, López-Salido, and Vallés (2004). In that paper we show how the presence of rule-of-thumb consumers can alter dramatically the equilibrium properties of an otherwise standard dynamic sticky price model. In particular, under certain parameter configurations the economy’s equilibrium may be indeterminate (and thus may display stationary sunspot fluctuations) even when the interest rate rule is one that satisfies the Taylor principle (which corresponds to φπ > 1inour model). Figure 2 illustrates that phenomenon for the model developed in the previous section. In particular the figure displays the regions in (λ, θ)space associated with either a unique equilibrium or indeterminacy, when the remaining parameters are kept at their baseline values. We see that indeterminacy arises whenever a high degree of price stickiness coexists with a sufficiently large weight of rule-of-thumb

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 247 — #21 248 Journal of the European Economic Association

Figure 2. Determinacy analysis. Note: Based on the model with competitive labor markets, remaining parameters at their baseline values. The dark area corresponds to the indeterminacy region.

households. Both frictions are thus seen to be necessary in order for indeterminacy to emerge as a property of the equilibrium dynamics. The figure also makes clear that the equilibrium is unique under our baseline calibration (λ = 1/2, θ = 0.75). We refer the reader to Galí, López-Salido, and Vallés (2004) for a discussion of the intuition underlying that violation of the Taylor principle.26

26. See also Bilbiie (2005) for a subsequent analysis in a model without capital accumulation, and for a re-assessment of the evolution of Fed policies over the postwar period, in light of that analysis.

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 248 — #22 Galí et al. Effects of Government Spending on Consumption 249

5. The Effects of Government Spending Shocks

In the present section we analyze the effects of shocks to government spending in the model economy described above. In particular, we focus on the condi- tions under which an exogenous increase in government spending has a positive effect on consumption, as found in much of the existing evidence. Throughout we restrict ourselves to configurations of parameter values for which the equilibrium is unique. Figure 3 shows the contemporaneous response of output, consumption, and investment (all normalized by steady state output) to a positive government spend- ing shock, as a function of λ, the fraction of rule-of-thumb consumers. The size of the shock is normalized to a 1% of steady state output. Given our normalizations, the plotted values can be interpreted as impact multipliers. We restrict the range of λ values considered to those consistent with a unique equilibrium. The remaining parameters are kept at their baseline values. Figure 3(A) corresponds to the econ- omy with competitive labor markets, Figure 3(B) to its imperfectly competitive counterpart. In the former case, consumption declines for most values of λ con- sidered, except for implausible large ones. The (absolute) size of the decline is, however, decreasing in λ, reflecting the offsetting role of rule-of-thumb behav- ior on the conventional negative wealth and intertemporal substitution effects triggered by the fiscal expansion. When imperfect labor markets are assumed, the possibility of crowding-in of consumption emerges for values of λ above a threshold value of roughly 1/4, a more plausible value. Notice also that the government spending multiplier on inflation and output rises rapidly when λ increases, attaining values roughly in line with the empirical evidence reviewed in Section 2. Figure 4 displays the dynamic responses of some key variables in our model to a positive government spending shock under the baseline calibration, and com- pares them to those generated by a neoclassical economy. The latter corresponds to a particular calibration of our model, with no price rigidities and no rule-of- thumb consumers (θ = λ = 0). Again we consider two alternative labor market structures, competitive and non-competitive. In each case the top-left graph dis- plays the pattern of the three fiscal variables (spending, taxes, and the deficit) in response to the shock considered. Notice that the pattern of both variables is close to the one estimated in the data (see Figure 1), consistently with our calibration of the fiscal policy rule. The figure illustrates the amplifying effects of the introduc- tion of rule-of-thumb consumers and sticky prices: The response of output and consumption is systematically above that generated by the neoclassical model.27

27. That monotonicity contrasts with some of the patterns observed in the data; we conjecture this is unrelated to the issue at hand and could be fixed by the introduction of habit formation and other mechanisms that generate inertia in aggregate demand.

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 249 — #23 250 Journal of the European Economic Association

Figure 3. Impact multipliers: sensitivity to λ. Note: Baseline calibration for remaining parameters.

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 250 — #24 Galí et al. Effects of Government Spending on Consumption 251

Figure 4. The dynamic effects of a government spending shock: baseline vs. neoclassical models. Note: Baseline calibration (continuous), neoclassical calibration (dashed).

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 251 — #25 252 Journal of the European Economic Association

Figure 5. Impact multipliers: sensitivity to ρg, alternative calibrations. (Non-competitive labor market).

Furthermore, in the baseline model, and in contrast with the neoclassical model, the increase in aggregate hours coexists with an increase in real wages. Overall we view the model’s predictions under the assumption of imperfectly competitive labor markets as matching the empirical responses, at least qualitatively. Figure 5 shows the government spending (impact) multipliers on output, consumption, and investment, as a function of ρg, the parameter measuring the persistence of the spending process. In order to avoid excessive dispersion, we henceforth report findings only for the non-competitive labor market specifi- cation, which the analysis above pointed to as the most promising one given our objectives. Each of the four graphs in the figure corresponds to a differ- ent parameter configuration. The top-left graph is associated with our baseline calibration. Notice that that in that case the crowding-in effect on consumption

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 252 — #26 Galí et al. Effects of Government Spending on Consumption 253

(and the consequent enhancement of the output multiplier) is decreasing in ρg. The intuition for that result is straightforward: Higher values of that parameter are associated with stronger (negative) wealth effects lowering the consumption of Ricardian households. Yet we see that even for values of ρg as high as 0.9 a positive (though relatively small) effect on aggregate consumption emerges. Notice also that the response of investment to the same shock is negative over the admissible range of ρg. For values of the latter parameter close to unity (i.e., near-random walk processes for government spending) that response becomes negligible.28 The other graphs in Figure 5 report analogous information for three alternative “extreme” calibrations. Each calibration assumes a limiting value for one (or two) parameters, while keeping the rest at their baseline values. Thus, the flexible price scenario assumes θ = 0, the no rule-of-thumb economy assumes λ = 0, and the neoclassical calibration combines both flexible prices and lack of rule-of- thumb consumers (θ = λ = 0). Notice that when prices are fully flexible, or when all consumers are Ricardian (or when both features coexist, as under the neoclassical calibration) consumption is always crowded out in response to a rise in government spending, independently of the degree of persistence of the latter. This illustrates the difficulty of reconciling the evidence with standard dynamic general equilibrium models, as well as the role played by both sticky prices and rule-of-thumb consumers to match that evidence. The graphs in Figure 6 summarize the sensitivity of the impact multipliers to variations in three non-policy parameters to the government spending shock. The first graph explores the sensitivity of the impact multipliers to the degree of price stickiness, as indexed by parameter θ. Notice that the size of the response of output is increasing in the degree of price rigidities, largely as a result of a stronger multiplier effect on consumption. Given baseline values for the remaining parameters, we see that values of θ slightly higher than 0.5 are consistent with a positive response of aggregate consumption. That range for θ includes the values generally viewed as consistent with the micro evidence and, hence, used in most calibrations. The two middle and bottom graphs show the impact multipliers when the degree of capital adjustment costs, η, and the wage elasticity parameter, ϕ change. High capital adjustment costs (i.e., low η) tend to dampen the fall in investment but enhance the positive response of consumption and output. Finally, we notice that the impact multipliers are relatively insensitive to changes in ϕ. Figure 7 illustrates the sensitivity of the model’s predictions to the three policy parameters (φπ ,φg, φb), each considered in turn. The top graph shows an inverse relationship between the size of the impact multipliers and the strength

28. As shown subsequently, the response of investment depend crucially upon the specification of capital adjustment costs. Lower capital adjustment costs tend to increase the (negative) response of investment (see middle panel of Figure 6).

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 253 — #27 254 Journal of the European Economic Association

Figure 6. Impact multipliers: sensitivity to non-policy parameters (θ,ϕ,η).

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 254 — #28 Galí et al. Effects of Government Spending on Consumption 255 of the central bank’s response to inflation (φπ ). Intuitively, a large φπ leads to a larger increase in the real rate in response to the higher inflation induced by the fiscal expansion; as a result consumption of Ricardian households declines further, dampening the total effect on aggregate consumption. That finding should not be surprising once we realize that in staggered price setting models like ours the central bank can approximate arbitrarily well the flexible price equilibrium allocation by following an interest rate rule that responds with sufficient strength to changes in inflation. Hence, an increase in φπ affects the output and consumption multipliers in a way qualitatively similar to an increase in price flexibility (i.e., a decline in θ), as described previously. Finally, the second and third graphs show the sensitivity of the multiplier to variations in the two parameters of the fiscal rule. In particular, and of most interest given our objectives, we see how a positive comovement of consumption and output in response to government spending shocks requires a sufficiently high response of taxes to debt (a high φb), and a sufficiently low response of taxes to current government spending (i.e., a low φg). Such a configuration of fiscal parameters will tend to imply a large but not-too-persistent deficit in response to an increase in government spending, a pattern largely consistent with the empirical evidence described in Section 2.

6. Rule-of-Thumb Consumers vs. Non-Separable Preferences

In this section we discuss an alternative potential explanation for our evidence of a positive response of consumption to a rise in government spending: The presence of non-separable preferences in utility an leisure. In particular, Basu and Kimball (2002) bring up that possibility as an explanation for the significance of anticipated disposable income in the consumption Euler equation estimated by Campbell and Mankiw (1989). We point to an aspect of the model with rule-of- thumb consumers which allows us to differentiate it, at least in principle, from one with non-separable preferences. To see this formally consider the following specification of period utility:

χ 1− 1 (Ct (1 − Nt ) ) σ U(Ct ,Nt ) = , (39) 1 − σ −1 where parameter σ>0 represents the elasticity of intertemporal substitution for consumption and χ ≥ 0. Under the previous utility specification the log-linear approximation to the consumption Euler equation of a Ricardian household can be shown to take the form (see, e.g., Basu and Kimball 2002)

ct = Et {ct+1}−σ (rt − Et {πt+1}) − (1 − σ) Et {nt+1}, (40)

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 255 — #29 256 Journal of the European Economic Association

Figure 7. Impact multipliers: sensitivity to policy parameters (φπ ,φg,φb).

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 256 — #30 Galí et al. Effects of Government Spending on Consumption 257 where ≡ χN(1 − N)−1 > 0. When σ = 1, preferences are separable and hours drop out of (41). Otherwise, anticipated movements in hours should have predictive power for consumption growth. The previous optimality equation can be rewritten as

ct+1 = σ (rt − Et {πt+1}) + (1 − σ) Et {nt+1}+ξt+1, (41) where ξt+1 ≡ ct − Et {ct+1} is the unpredictable component of consumption. Notice that (41) can be estimated using an IV estimator, by replacing Et {πt+1} and Et {nt+1} with their realized counterparts, πt+1 and nt+1, and using lagged variables as instruments. Notice also that (41) has a structure similar to

ct+1 = σ (rt − Et {πt+1}) + λEt {ydt+1}+ξt+1, (42) where ydt denotes (log) disposable income. Campbell and Mankiw (1989) used a version of (42) to test the permanent income hypothesis (PIH), and interpreted coefficient λ as the fraction of aggregate consumption corresponding to rule-of- thumb consumers. Their finding of a large and significant λ (with a point estimate close to 0.5), led them to reject the PIH in favor of a model with borrowing constraints or myopic behavior. As stressed by Basu and Kimball (2002), however, Campbell and Mankiw’s interpretation of their results hinges on the assumption of a utility that is sepa- rable in consumption. If preferences are instead given by (39) (with σ = 1), a common interpretation of their results as suggesting that a substantial fraction of U.S. consumers behave in a non-Ricardian fashion may not be warranted. The reason is simple: Given the high positive correlation between changes in (log) disposable income and changes in (log) hours, it is clear that a researcher esti- mating (42) would easily conclude that anticipated changes in disposable income have predictive power for consumption growth (i.e., a significant λ), even if all consumers were fully Ricardian (as long as utility was non-separable). Further- more, the positive estimate for λ obtained by Campbell and Mankiw would be consistent with a low intertemporal elasticity of substitution (σ<1). The problem of near-observational equivalence between the two hypotheses, and the likely multicollinearity that the joint use of changes in hours and dispos- able income would imply, led Basu and Kimball (2002) to estimate a restricted version of (41). In particular, and using the fact that the household’s intratemporal optimality condition implies that ≡ χN(1 − N)−1 = WN/P C, a ratio which is in principle observable, they rewrite (41) as

(ct+1 − 0.8Et {nt+1}) = σ (rt − Et {πt+1}−0.8Et {nt+1})

+ λEt {ydt+1}+ξt+1, (43)

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 257 — #31 258 Journal of the European Economic Association where the choice of 0.8 as a setting for corresponds the average ratio of labor income to consumption expenditures in the postwar U.S. Under the joint null of fully Ricardian consumers and non-separable preferences we have λ = 0, a hypothesis that they cannot reject using aggregate postwar data, thus calling into question the interpretation that Campbell and Mankiw gave to their findings. Clearly, optimality condition (40) has some similarities with equation (31), reproduced here for convenience, which results in our model from combining the Euler equation of Ricardian households (endowed with separable preferences) with the budget constraint of rule-of-thumb households: = { }− − { } − { }+ { r } ct Et ct+1 σ (rt Et πt+1 ) nEt nt+1 τ Et tt+1 , where n and τ , defined earlier in the text, are positive as long as there is some mass of rule-of-thumb consumers (and zero otherwise). Notice however, one important difference between the two equations: In the model with rule-of-thumb consumers anticipated changes in taxes (minus transfers) accruing to those consumers should have predictive power for con- sumption growth, once we control for the influence of the interest rate and hours growth. That feature, on the other hand, is absent from the Euler equation in the Basu-Kimball model with Ricardian households and non-separable preferences. We interpret the existing evidence on the response of consumption to antic- ipated changes in taxes as bearing directly on this issue. Thus, using household level data, Parker (1999) finds evidence of a large response of consumption to variations in after-tax income resulting from anticipated changes in Social Secu- rity taxes, with the estimated elasticity being close to one half. Similarly, Souleles (1999) finds evidence of excess sensitivity of households’ consumption to pre- dictable income tax refunds, with the implied marginal propensity to consume the tax refunds between 0.35 and 0.60. Similar results are uncovered by Johnson et al. (2004), focusing on the income tax rebate of 2001. None of those anticipated changes in taxes should have effect on consumption in a fully Ricardian model, independently of whether preferences are separable in consumption and labor or not. Here we complement the evidence based on household data just discussed with our own evidence, using quarterly aggregate U.S. time series. To set the stage, we first re-estimate the Campbell-Mankiw Euler equation (42) using an updated data set, running from 1954:I to 2004:IV. We use as instruments second and third lags of the interest rate, changes in (log) consumption, and changes in (log) hours. A detailed description of the data and sources can be found in the footnote to Table 2. Our estimates of the Campbell-Mankiw model, shown in the top panel of Table 2, confirm the earlier findings of those authors. Most importantly, (antici- pated) change in (log) disposable income are shown to have predictive power for consumption changes, with the point estimate of λ being close to 0.5 and, hence,

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 258 — #32 Galí et al. Effects of Government Spending on Consumption 259

Table 2. Estimates of the consumption Euler equation. Regressors − d Specification rt−1 πt nt yt taxt Campbell-Mankiw .076 – .477* – (.073) (0.103)

Basu-Kimball (1) .314* .549* – – (.066) (.053) (2) .317* .546* −.176 – (.076) (.061) (.209) (3) .201* .639* – −.061* (.051) (.086) (.023) Note: Standard errors in brackets. The instruments include the real interest rate, (per capita) consumption growth and (per capita) hours worked growth at t − 2 and t − 3, and in the last two columns the rate of growth of disposable income or taxes between t − 2 and t − 3, respectively. Consumption growth is defined as non-durable plus services (CNH + CSH), the real interest rate (r − π) is constructed using the 3-month TBill rate (FTB3) minus the rate of growth of personal consumption deflator—defined as the ratio between nominal and real consumption ((CN + CS)/(CNH + CSH)). Per capita hours (n) correspond the Non-Farm Business Sector (LXNFH). The real personal disposable income (yd ) is from the FRED II, and from the BEA we define the variable tax as the difference between Government Current Tax Receipts (GRCRT) and Government Current Transfer Payments (GETFP) divided by potential output (GDPPOTQ) at t − 1. *Significant at 5% level. of the same order of magnitude as the original Campbell-Mankiw estimates. In addition, the estimates uncover no evidence of any intertemporal substitution effects, as reflected in the insignificant estimate of the interest rate coefficient. The second panel of Table 2 reports the IV estimates of alternative versions of the Basu-Kimball Euler equation (43), imposing the steady state restrictions implied by the theory. Row (1) shows the estimates of (43), excluding changes in disposable income (λ = 0). In contrast with the findings based on the Campbell- Mankiw equation, the estimate of the intertemporal elasticity of substitution (the coefficient on interest rate) is now significantly different from zero, with a point estimate close 0.3. In addition, as shown in row (2) once changes in hours are properly controlled for, (anticipated) changes in disposable income lose their explanatory power for consumption changes, thus replicating the main finding in Basu and Kimball (2002). In row (3) we introduce changes in taxes as an explanatory variable in the same IV equation, substituting disposable income, and motivated by the predictions of the model with rule-of-thumb consumers. Because we have no way to isolate taxes paid by non-Ricardian households, we use instead a measure of overall net taxes given by the difference between government current tax receipts (GRCRT) and government current transfer payments (GETFP), divided by (lagged) poten- tial output (GDPPOTQ).29 Under the null implied by the Ricardian model with

29. See Table 2 for details on the definition of the variables. Tax data were drawn from the BEA Web page (http://www.bea.gov).

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 259 — #33 260 Journal of the European Economic Association non-separable utility, no variable other than the (hours-adjusted) real interest rate should have predictive power for (hours-adjusted) consumption changes, as implied by (43) with λ = 0. Yet, as shown in Table 2, anticipated changes in (net) taxes enter the Euler equation significantly (and with the expected sign). The estimated elasticity of intertemporal substitution remains significant, though its point estimate has been reduced to 0.2. We interpret the evidence of the predictive power of tax changes on consumption as a rejection of a fully Ricardian model with non-separable preferences, and one that is at least suggestive of the presence of non-Ricardian households, in accordance with the micro evidence reviewed earlier.

7. Concluding Comments and Further Research

The analysis herein has shown how the interaction between rule-of-thumb behav- ior by some households (for which consumption equals labor income) and sticky prices (modeled as in the recent new Keynesian literature) make it possible to gen- erate an increase in consumption in response to a rise in government spending, in a way consistent with much of the recent evidence. Rule-of-thumb consumers partly insulate aggregate demand from the negative wealth effects generated by the higher levels of (current and future) taxes needed to finance the fiscal expan- sion, while making it more sensitive to current disposable income. Sticky prices make it possible for real wages to increase (or, at least, to decline by a smaller amount) even in the face of a drop in the marginal product of labor, as the price markup may adjust sufficiently downward to absorb the resulting gap. The com- bined effect of a higher real wage and higher employment raises current labor income and hence stimulates the consumption of rule-of-thumb households. The possible presence of countercyclical wage markups (as in the version of the model with non-competitive labor markets developed above) provides additional room for a simultaneous increase in consumption and hours and, hence, in the marginal rate of substitution, without requiring a proportional increase in the real wage. Perhaps most importantly, our framework generates a positive comovement of consumption and government spending under configurations of parameter val- ues that are empirically plausible (and conventionally assumed in the business cycle literature). Thus, we view our results as providing a potential solution to the seeming conflict between empirical evidence and the predictions of existing DSGE models regarding the effects of government spending shocks. In the present paper we kept both the model and its analysis as simple as possible, and focused on a single issue. As a result, we left out many possible extensions and avenues for further exploration. Thus, for instance, our theoretical analysis assumes that government spending is financed by means of lump-sum taxes (current or future). If only distortionary income taxes were available to the

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 260 — #34 Galí et al. Effects of Government Spending on Consumption 261 government, the response of the different macroeconomic variables to a govern- ment spending shock will generally differ from the one obtained in the economy with lump-sum taxes analyzed above, and will generally depend on the compo- sition and timing of taxation.30 Allowing for staggered nominal wage setting or some form of real wage rigidity constitutes another potentially useful extension of our framework, one that is likely to have a significant effect on the response of real wages and, hence, of labor income and consumption to any fiscal shock. Another avenue worth pursuing is the introduction of rule-of-thumb con- sumers in medium-scale DSGE models of the sort developed by Smets and Wouters (2003) and Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans (2005). Those models incorporate many of the features that have been shown to be useful in account- ing for different aspects of economic fluctuations, and which have been assumed away in the model developed above. Such a richer version of our model could be taken to the data, and generate estimates of the quantitative importance of rule- of-thumb consumers and their role in shaping historical economic fluctuations. Early examples of efforts in that direction can already be found in the work of Coenen and Straub (2005), Erceg, Guerrieri, and Gust (2005), Forni, Monteforte, and Sessa (2006), and López-Salido and Rabanal (2006). A number of papers have documented a stronger interest rate response to changes in inflation during the past two decades, relative to the pre-Volcker era.31 There is also substantial evidence pointing to a rise in asset market participation over the postwar period, which in the context of our model could be interpreted as a decline in the fraction of rule-of-thumb consumers. The model developed herein predicts a reduction in the government spending multiplier on consumption and output, in response to both developments. In that spirit, Bilbiie, Maier, and Müller (2005) explore the implications of those changes in the context of a model similar to ours, and suggest that those developments may explain part of the observed decline in fiscal multipliers uncovered by Perotti (2004) and others. Finally, one would want to consider some of the normative implications of our framework: In a model with the two types of consumers considered herein, the monetary and fiscal policy responses to shocks of different nature can be expected to have distributional effects, which should be taken into account in the design of those policies. Exploring the implications of the present model for optimal monetary policy design constitutes an additional interesting avenue for future research.32

30. An example of work in that direction is given by Bilbiie and Straub (2005), who study the interaction of distortionary taxes and rule-of-thumb households, albeit in a model without capital accumulation. 31. See, for example, Clarida, Galí, and Gertler (2000). 32. This is the road taken by Amato and Laubach (2003), albeit in the context of an alternative model of rule-of-thumb behavior.

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 261 — #35 262 Journal of the European Economic Association

Appendix A: Alternative Labor Market Structures

In the present appendix we describe two alternative models of wage determination that generate a log-linear aggregate equilibrium condition corresponding to (30) in the text.

A.1. Perfectly Competitive Labor Markets

When households choose optimally their labor supply taking wages as given, the intratemporal optimality condition takes the form

= j j ϕ Wt Ct (Nt ) , or, in logs,

= j + j wt ct ϕnt , (A.1) for j = r, o. Notice that under our assumption of equality of steady state consumption across household types, steady state hours will also be equated. Hence we can write = r + − o nt λnt (1 λ)nt , which, together with equations (28) and (A.1), allows us to obtain the aggregate equilibrium condition

wt = ct + ϕnt .

A.2. Wage-Setting by Unions

Consider a model with a continuum of unions, each of which represents workers of a certain type. Effective labor input hired by firm j is a CES function of the quantities of the different labor types employed,

εw 1 εw−1 εw−1 Nt (j) = Nt (j, i) εw di , 0 where εw is the elasticity of substitution across different types of households. The fraction of rule-of-thumb and Ricardian consumers is uniformly distributed across worker types (and hence across unions). Each period, a typical union (say,

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 262 — #36 Galí et al. Effects of Government Spending on Consumption 263 representing worker of type z) sets the wage for its workers in order to maximize the objective function

+ + 1 N 1 ϕ(z) 1 N 1 ϕ(z) λ W (z)N (z) − t + (1 − λ) W (z)N (z) − t , r t t + o t t + Ct (z) 1 ϕ Ct (z) 1 ϕ subject to a labor demand schedule −εw Wt (z) Nt (z) = Nt . Wt Because consumption will generally differ between the two types of con- sumers, the union weighs labor income with their respective marginal utility of r o consumption (i.e., 1/Ct and 1/Ct ). Notice that, in writing down the problem, we have assumed that the union takes into account the fact that firms allocate labor demand uniformly across different workers of type z, independently of their r = o = household type. It follows that, in the aggregate, we will have Nt Nt Nt for all t. The first order condition of this problem can be written as follows (after invoking symmetry, and thus dropping the z index) − λ + 1 λ = w r o Wt µ , (A.2) MRSt MRSt where MRSr ≡ Cr N ϕ, MRSo ≡ Co N ϕ, and µw ≡ εw . t t t t t t εw−1 Log-linearizing expression (A.2) and ignoring constant terms yields the wage schedule

= r + o =˜ + + wt χr mrst χomrst ct ϕ(χr χo)nt , ≡ r w ≡ − o w ˜ ≡ r + o where χr λW/MRS µ , χo (1 λ)W/MRS µ , and ct χr ct χoct . Notice that, to the extent that equates steady state consumption across household types (i.e., Cr = Co) we will have MRSr = MRSo and, hence, χr = λ and χo = 1 − λ. We can then rewrite the previous equilibrium condition as

wt ≡ ct + ϕnt , which corresponds to the equation (30) in the text. Under the present scenario we assume that the wage markup µw is sufficiently j = large (and the shocks sufficiently small) so that the conditions Wt > MRSt for j r, o are satisfied for all t. Both conditions guarantee that both type of households will be willing to meet firms’ labor demand at the prevailing wage.

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 263 — #37 264 Journal of the European Economic Association

Appendix B: Steady State Analysis

In this short appendix we show that the steady state ratio of aggregate consumption to total output does not depend upon the fraction of rule-of-thumb consumers. In doing so, we just notice that the market clearing condition for final goods implies

I G δα δα γ = 1 − − = 1 − − γ = (1 − γ ) − , c Y Y Y g g (ρ + δ) µp α K where the last equality follows from the fact that in the steady state Rk = αY/µpK (implied by the constant marginal cost) and Rk = (ρ + δ) (implied by a constant Q). Notice that this share of consumption on total output it is independent of the share of rule-of-thumb consumers and our assumption on the labor market structure.

Appendix C: Derivation of the Reduced Dynamical System

The equilibrium conditions describing the model dynamics are given by expres- sions (30)–(37). Now we reduce those conditions to the five variable system (38) in terms of hours, consumption, inflation, capital, and government spending. The first equation in the system (38) corresponds to the linearized capital accu- mulation equation (25), with it substituted out using market-clearing condition (36) and replacing yt subsequently using the production function (35): δα δ(1 − α) δγc δ kt+1 = 1 − δ + kt + nt − ct − gt , (C.1) 1 −˜γc 1 −˜γc 1 −˜γc 1 −˜γc where γ˜c = γc + γg. In order to derive the second equation in (38) we start by rewriting the inflation equation (32) in terms of variables contained in xt . Using (33) and (30) we obtain an expression for the marginal cost as a function of the consumption output ratio and aggregate hours:

µt = yt − ct − (1 + ϕ)nt . (C.2)

Substituting the previous expression (C.2) into (32), and making use of (35), yields the second equation in (38):

πt = βEt {πt+1}+λp [ct − yt + (1 + ϕ)nt ]

= βEt {πt+1}+λpct − αλpkt + (α + ϕ)λpnt . (C.3)

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 264 — #38 Galí et al. Effects of Government Spending on Consumption 265

C.1. Aggregate Euler Equation: Perfectly Competitive Labor Markets

As noted, under the assumption of perfectly competitive labor markets, we can log-linearize expressions (8) and (12) and combine them with (28) and (29) to expression (30). From log-linearizing expression (12) we obtain an expression for the evolution of the hours worked by the rule-of-thumb consumers: r = −1 − r nt ϕ wt ct .

We now substitute the previous expression as well as (30) into expression (27). r After rearranging terms this yields ct as a function only of aggregate variables: [ p + − ] r µ γcϕ (1 α) ct = − + + − + − p r (1 α)(1 ϕ)ct (1 α)(1 ϕ)ϕnt µ ϕtt . (C.4)

As noted before, we also apply the operator (1 − L−1) to expression (28), which yields

− { }= [ r − { r }] + − [ o − { o }] ct Et ct+1 λ ct Et ct+1 (1 λ) ct Et ct+1 .

Finally, we substitute expressions (C.4) and (26) into the previous one, which after rearranging terms, yields the Euler equation for aggregate consumption presented in the main text:

1 r c = E {c + }− (r − E {π + }) −  E {n + }+ E {t + }, t t t 1 σ˜ t t t 1 n t t 1 τ t t 1 where

p 1/σ˜ ≡ (1 − λ)[µ ϕγc + (1 − α)],n ≡ λ(1 − α)(1 + ϕ)ϕ, p −1 p  ≡ γcµ ϕ + (1 − α)(1 − λ(1 + ϕ)) ,t ≡ λµ ϕ.

C.2. Aggregate Euler Equation: Imperfectly Competitive Labor Markets

We first substitute expression (30) into expression (27), yielding WN Y cr = [c + (1 + ϕ)n ]− tr t C t t C t − − + = (1 α) + (1 α)(1 ϕ) − 1 r p ct p nt tt . µ γc µ γc γc

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 265 — #39 266 Journal of the European Economic Association

We proceed to use the operator (1−L−1) in the previous expression, yielding − r r (1 α) − { }= [ − { + }] ct Et ct+1 p ct Et ct 1 γcµ − + (1 α)(1 ϕ) 1 r r + [ − { + }] − [ − { }] p nt Et nt 1 tt Et tt+1 . γcµ γc (C.5)

We also apply the operator (1 − L−1) to expression (28), which yields

− { }= [ r − { r }] + − [ o − { o }] ct Et ct+1 λ ct Et ct+1 (1 λ) ct Et ct+1 .

Finally, we substitute expressions (C.5) and (26) into the previous one, which after rearranging terms yields an Euler-like equation for aggregate consumption:

p γcµ (1 − λ) = { + }− − { + } ct Et ct 1 p (rt Et πt 1 ) γcµ − λ(1 − α) + − p λ(1 ϕ)(1 α) λµ r − { + }+ { } p Et nt 1 p Et tt+1 , γcµ − λ(1 − α) γcµ − λ(1 − α) or, more compactly,

1 r c = E {c + }− (r − E {π + }) −  E {n + }+ E {t + }, t t t 1 σ˜ t t t 1 n t t 1 t t t 1 where

p 1/σ˜ ≡ γc(1 − λ)µ ,n ≡ λ(1 − α)(1 + ϕ), p −1 p  ≡ γcµ − λ(1 − α) ,t ≡ λµ , which are the coefficients of this expression in the text. Plugging into the Euler equation the interest rate rule (18), the fiscal rule (20), and using the fact the government spending follows a first order autoregressive process (21) we obtain the third equation in (38):

φπ 1 c −  n + π = E {c + }+ E {π + }− E {n + } (C.6) t n t σ˜ t t t 1 σ˜ t t 1 n t t 1 + t φbbt+1 + t φg(ρg − 1)gt .

In order to derive the fourth equation, we first combine (C.2) and (34) to k = − + + obtain rt ct kt (1 ϕ)nt . The latter expression and the interest rate

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 266 — #40 Galí et al. Effects of Government Spending on Consumption 267 rule (18), allows us to rewrite the equations describing the dynamics of Tobin’s q and investment as follows:

it − kt = βEt {(it+1 − kt+1)} + η[1 − β(1 − δ)] Et {ct+1}−kt+1 + (1 + ϕ)Et {nt+1}

− ηφπ πt + ηEt {πt+1}.

Finally, substituting the relationship 1 it − kt = (1 − α)nt − γcct − gt − (1 −˜γc − α)kt 1 −˜γc

(which can be derived by combining the goods market-clearing condition with the production function) into the previous equation and rearranging terms we obtain the fourth equation of our dynamical system:

(1 − α)nt − γcct − (1 −˜γc − α)kt + (1 −˜γc)ηφπ πt

= [ω(1 + ϕ) + β(1 − α)] Et {nt+1}+(ω − βγc) dEt {ct+1}

−[ω + β(1 −˜γc − α)]kt+1 + (1 −˜γc)ηEt {πt+1}+(1 − βρg)gt , (C.7) where ω ≡ η[1 − β(1 − δ)](1 −˜γc)>0. The last two equations of the system correspond to expression (37) describ- ing the debt accumulation and the autoregressive process for government spending (21). Hence the system of equations (C.1), (C.3), (C.6), (C.7), (37), and (21) can be written in a matrix form as follows:

AEt {xt+1}=Bxt + εt ,

 where xt ≡[nt ,ct ,πt ,kt ,bt ,gt−1] , and ⎡ ⎤ δ 0001 0−˜ ⎢ 1 γc ⎥ ⎢ ⎥ ⎢ 00β 000⎥ ⎢ 1 ⎥ ⎢ −n 1 0 t φb t (ρg− 1)φg⎥ A ≡⎢ σ˜ ⎥, ⎢ + + + − −˜ −[ + −˜ − ] − ⎥ ⎢ω(1 ϕ) β(1 α) ω βγc (1 γc)η ω β(1 γc α) 0 (1 βρg) ⎥ ⎣ ⎦ 0000 1−(1 + ρ)(1 − φg) 0000 01

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 267 — #41 268 Journal of the European Economic Association ⎡ ⎤ δ(1−α) δγc δα −˜ − −˜ 01− δ + −˜ 00 ⎢ 1 γc 1 γc 1 γc ⎥ ⎢− + − ⎥ ⎢ (α ϕ)λp λp 1 αλp 00⎥ ⎢ ⎥ ⎢ − 1 φπ 0  φ 0 ⎥ B ≡⎢ n σ˜ t b ⎥. ⎢ − − −˜ ˜ + − ⎥ ⎢ 1 α γc (1 γc)ηφπ γc α 100⎥ ⎣ ⎦ 000 0(1 + ρ)(1 − φb) 0 000 0 0ρg

References

Aiyagari, Rao, Lawrence Christiano, and Martin Eichenbaum (1990). “Output, Employment and Interest Rate Effects of Government Consumption.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 30, 73–86. Alesina, Alberto, and Silvia Ardagna (1998). “Tales of .” Economic Policy, 27, 489–545. Amato, Jeffery D., and Thomas Laubach (2003). “Rule-of-Thumb Behavior and Monetary Policy.” European Economic Review, 47, 791–831. Basu, Susanto, and Miles Kimball (2002). “Long-run Labor Supply and the Elasticity of Intertemporal Substitution for Consumption.” Working paper, University of Michigan. Basu, Susanto, and Miles Kimball (2003). “Investment Planning Costs and the Effects of Monetary and Fiscal Policy.” Working paper, University of Michigan. Baxter, Marianne, and Robert King (1993). “Fiscal Policy in General Equilibrium.” American Economic Review, 83, 315–334. Bilbiie, Florin O. (2005). “Limited Asset Market Participation, Monetary Policy, and Inverted Keynesian Logic.” Working paper, Nuffield College, Oxford University. Bilbiie, Florin O., André Maier, and Gernot J. Müller (2005). “Asset Market Participation, Monetary Policy, and the Effects of U.S. Government Spending: What Accounts for the Declining ?” Working paper, Goethe University at Frankfurt. Bilbiie, Florin O., and Roland Straub (2005). “Fiscal Policy, Business Cycles and Labor Market Fluctuations.” Working paper, Nuffield College, Oxford University. Blanchard, Olivier (2003). Macroeconomics, 3rd ed. Prentice Hall. Blanchard, Olivier, and Roberto Perotti (2002). “An Empirical Characterization of the Dynamic Effects of Changes in Government Spending and Taxes on Output.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 1329–1368. Bohn, Henning (1998). “The Behavior of Public Debt and Deficits.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113, 949–964. Burnside, Craig, Martin Eichenbaum, and Jonas Fisher (2003). “Fiscal Shocks and their Consequences.” NBER Working Paper No. 9772. Campbell, John Y., and N. Gregory Mankiw (1989). “Consumption, Income, and Interest Rates: Reinterpreting the Time Series Evidence.” In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1989, edited by O. J. Blanchard and S. Fischer. MIT Press, pp. 185–216. Calvo, Guillermo (1983). “Staggered Prices in a Utility Maximizing Framework.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 12, 383–398. Christiano, Lawrence, and Martin Eichenbaum (1992). “Current Real Business Cycles Theories and Aggregate Labor Market Fluctuations.” American Economic Review, 82, 430–450. Christiano, Lawrence, Martin Eichenbaum, and Charles Evans (2005). “Nominal Rigidities and the Dynamic Effects of a Shock to Monetary Policy.” Journal of , 113(1), 1–45.

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 268 — #42 Galí et al. Effects of Government Spending on Consumption 269

Clarida, Richard, Jordi Galí, and Mark Gertler (1999). “The Science of Monetary Policy: A New Keynesian Perspective.” Journal of Economic Literature, 37, 1661–1707. Clarida, Richard, Jordi Galí, and Mark Gertler (2000). “Monetary Policy Rules and Macroe- conomic Stability: Evidence and Some Theory.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115, 147–180. Coenen, G. and R. Straub (2005). “Does Government Spending Crowd In Private Con- sumption: Theory and Empirical Evidence for the Euro Area.” International Finance,8, 435–470. Deaton, A. (1992). Understanding Consumption, Clarendon Lectures in Economics. Clarendon Press. Dotsey, Michael (1999). “Structure from Shocks.” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Working Paper 99–6. Dupor, Bill (2002). “Interest Rate Policy and Investment with Adjustment Costs.” Working paper, Ohio State University. Edelberg, Wendy, Martin Eichenbaum, and Jonas Fisher (1999). “Understanding the Effects of Shocks to Government Purchases.” Review of Economic Dynamics, 2, 166–206. Erceg, C. J., L. Guerrieri, and C. J. Gust, (2005). “SIGMA A New Open Economy Model for Policy Analysis.” Federal Reserve Board, International Finance Discussion Papers, No. 835. Fatás, Antonio, and Ilian Mihov (2001). “The Effects of Fiscal Policy on Consumption and Employment: Theory and Evidence.” Working paper, INSEAD. Forni, Lorenzo, Libero Monteforte, and Luca Sessa (2006). “The Estimated General Equi- librium Effects of Fiscal Policy: the Case of the Euro Area.” Working paper, Banca d’Italia. Galí, Jordi, M. Gertler, and J. David López-Salido (2007). “Markups, Gaps, and the Welfare Costs of Business Fluctuations.” Review of Economics and Statistics, 89(1), 44–59. Galí, Jordi, J. David López-Salido, and Javier Vallés (2004). “Rule-of- Thumb Consumers and the Design of Interest Rate Rules.” Journal of Money, and Banking, 36, 739–764. Giavazzi, Francesco, and Marco Pagano (1990). “Can Severe Fiscal Contractions be Expan- sionary? Tales of Two Small European Countries.” In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1990, edited by O. J. Blanchard and S. Fischer. MIT Press, pp. 75–110. Hemming, Richard, Michael Kell, and Selma Mahfouz (2002). “The Effectiveness of Fiscal Policy in Stimulating Economic Activity-A Review of the Literature.” IMF Working Paper 02/208. IMF (2004). World Economic Outlook 2004. IMF. Johnson, David S., Jonathan A. Parker, and Nicholas S. Souleles (2004). “Household Expenditure and the Income Tax Rebates of 2001.” NBER Working Paper 1078. Kim, Jinill (2000). “Constructing and Estimating a Realistic Optimizing Model of Monetary Policy.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 45, 329–359. King, Robert, and Mark Watson (1996). “Money, Prices, Interest Rates and the Business Cycle.” Review of Economics and Statistics, 78, 35–53. Lopez-Salido, J. David, and Pau Rabanal (2006). “Government Spending and Consumption- Hours Preferences.” Working paper, Federal Reserve Board. Mankiw, N. Gregory (2000). “The Savers-Spenders Theory of Fiscal Policy.” American Economic Review, 90, 120–125. Mountford, Andrew, and Harald Uhlig (2004). “What are the Effects of Fiscal Policy Shocks?” Working paper, Humboldt University Berlin. Parker, Jonathan (1999). “The Reaction of Household Consumption to Predictable Changes in Social Security Taxes.” American Economic Review, 89, 959–973. Perotti, Roberto (1999). “Fiscal Policy in Good Times and Bad.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 1399–1436.

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 269 — #43 270 Journal of the European Economic Association

Perotti, Roberto (2004). “Estimating the Effects of Fiscal Policy in OECD Countries.” Working paper, IGIER at Milan. Ramey, Valerie, and Matthew Shapiro (1998). “Costly Capital Reallocation and the Effect of Government Spending.” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on , 48, 145–194. Rotemberg, Julio, and Michael Woodford (1992). “Oligopolistic Pricing and the Effects of Aggregate Demand on Economic Activity.” Journal of Political Economy, 100, 1153–1297. Rotemberg, Julio, and Michael Woodford (1995). “Dynamic General Equilibrium Models with Imperfectly Competitive Products Markets.” In Frontiers in Business Cycle Research, edited by Thomas F. Cooley. Princeton University Press, pp. 297–346. Rotemberg, Julio, and Michael Woodford (1997). “An Optimization Econometric Framework for the Evaluation of Monetary Policy” In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1997, edited by O. J. Blanchard and S. Fischer. MIT Press, pp. 297–346. Rotemberg, Julio, and Michael Woodford (1999). “Interest Rate Rules in an Estimated Sticky Price Model.” In Monetary Policy Rules, edited by J.B. Taylor, University of Chicago Press and NBER. Smets, Frank, and Raf Wouters(2003). “An Estimated Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model of the Euro Area.” Journal of the European Economic Association, 1(5), 1123–1175. Souleles, Nicholas S. (1999). “The Response of Household Consumption to Income Tax Refunds.” American Economic Review, 89, 947–958. Taylor, John B. (1993). “Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice.” Carnegie Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 39, 195–214. Uhlig, H. (2005). “What Are the Effects of Monetary Policy? Results from an Agnostic Identification Procedure.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 52(2), 381–419. Wolff, Edward (1998). “Recent Trends in the Size Distribution of Household Wealth.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 12, 131–150. Woodford, Michael (2003). Interest and Prices, chap. 4, Princeton University Press. Yun, Tack (1996). “Nominal Price Rigidity, Endogeneity, and Business Cycles.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 37, 345–370.

“zwu001070405” — 2007/1/24 — page 270 — #44