Competition Law and Sports

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Competition Law and Sports VOLUME 2 ISSUE 3 MARCH 2019 ISSN: 2456-9666 COMPETITION LAW AND SPORTS - TEJASWINI1 & UTTAKARSH MATTIKOP2 ABSTRACT Sports right from ancient times has not been the same as it was before. In ancient times sports was played pleasure, then slowly it became a part of culture of a country and now in the present day it has become a business. Sports today is one of the biggest money-making industries with lots of money being spent. Cricket today has become a world-wide business, especially in a country like India cricket is not just a game but also a religion. Competition laws are framed so that unfair trade practices are prevented. Not only unfair trade practices but also prevent monopolistic trade activities, cartelization and other anti-competitive agreements. With Competition Act, 2002 substituting MRTP Act, the scope has now widened. With sports being now an industry there is now a need to include sports in the ambit of competition law. With BCCI misusing its position has given invitation to Competition Commission of India (CCI) to keep a check in the sports industry so that fair trade practice is followed. INTRODUCTION In India, sports is having its own 8000 years old history since early civilization, Atharvaveda also holds the traditional Olympic oath. And in this modern era, cricket, hockey, tennis etc. growing immensely and also the players have been recognised and appreciated internationally. But as we can see that, the government is neglecting the sports sector, as there are institutions like Ministry Of Youth Affairs And Sports that is, the apex body which provides planning and a good infrastructure to it3. The government made or passed many rules regarding sports, and also made rules regarding competition between the institutions. Sports is expanding remarkably that 1 Student, B.B.A LL.B 4th Year, New Law College Bhartiya Vidyapeeth Deemed University 2 Student, B.B.A LL.B 4th Year ,New Law College bhartiya Vidyapeeth Deemed University 3 Dr. Vijay Kumar Singh, a primer on „sports and competition law interface‟ in India https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2973042 JUSIMPERATOR www.jusimperator.org Page 1 VOLUME 2 ISSUE 3 MARCH 2019 ISSN: 2456-9666 some people make sports their business and making multi-millions from the billons of fans of sports and also enjoying the dominant position in the market as well. The scope of competition law in India is getting wider day by day, to remove the wrongful activities done by the huge organisation, like abuse of dominant position, unfair trade practices, restrictive trade practices, monopolistic trades, because nowadays sports is also falling into the same category of abuse of dominance in the market because there are various sports organisations who all are into this business. Sport‟s is becoming a global business and yet there are multiple ways for the sports organisations to significantly getting different from the other organisations and also maintaining competitive balance between the organisation. APPLICABILITY OF COMPETITION LAW INTO SPORTS In India cricket is on the peak level and other sports like football, basketball, tennis are also gaining popularity with the large corporate who all are interested in investing in it and also in the sponsorship of it as well, which is attracting huge young audience towards it. Basically for every sport there is a body which lays down the rules, regulations, criteria, eligibility of that sport. International federation with various national sports federations, which governs all the regulatory aspect of it. A sport basically follows the pyramid structures of it because of the multiple federations of sports have been recognized internationally. The European commission‟s Helsinki report was about the integrity, uniformity and control over the non-discriminatory rules applied to the sports globally and also encourage the immense growth of it worldwide. The International federation of sports is having their own set of regulations for restricting rival tournaments, but in country like India where sports is unique because it follows the pyramid structure of sports that ensures monopoly to maintain the unity and integrity in sports but there are many industrial thrives as well who just want to earn by unfair use of it. And for these kind of industries there is anti-competitive agreements to stop their dominance in the market by unfair means, therefore the competitive environment in the market of sports gave birth to competition law for sports industries as well. That is the reason why European Court created an exception, JUSIMPERATOR www.jusimperator.org Page 2 VOLUME 2 ISSUE 3 MARCH 2019 ISSN: 2456-9666 and that is divided into two parts, that is first being pure sporting function and second being activities having a substantial economic impact. COMPETITION ISSUES IN SPORTS SECTOR: The following five basic competition questions were identified during a Roundtable on sports organized by OECD24 in which various countries participated: (i) The nature of sports federations (should they be considered as normal commercial enterprises subject to competition law or as private non-profit making bodies which merely regulate the sports?) (ii) The relationship between sports federations or leagues and the constituent clubs (should the federations or leagues be viewed as cartels of clubs or as bodies independent of the clubs?) (iii) The nature of the product or service provided by the professional sports (should the matches be viewed as separate events or is there a positive externality in that a championship is more than a set of matches?) (iv) The nature of the relevant market (are different sports substitutable for one another or within the same sport are different competitions substitutable, particularly from the broadcasting perspective?)4 In India, there are cases of All India Chess federation and of BCCI and of Indian hockey Federation are some examples of it. These three cases decided by Competition Commission of India (CCI) are the important source of Competition law to be in the market of sports in India. Surrender Singh Barmi v BCCI (CCI, 61/2010) In this case, the competition commission of India passed an order under section 27 of the competition act, 2002 that the Board of control for cricket in India was found in contravention of the provision of section 4 of the Competition act, 2002. In this case the commission found that the BCCI at the dominant position in the market. It was given that 4 Dr. Vijay Kumar Singh, a primer on „sports and competition law interface‟ in India, https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2973042 JUSIMPERATOR www.jusimperator.org Page 3 VOLUME 2 ISSUE 3 MARCH 2019 ISSN: 2456-9666 the BCCI made an agreement with the broadcasters of the Indian Premier League (IPL) that they are not allowed to make this kind of agreement with any company in the market that is using the dominant position which is found to be in contravention of section 4(2)(c) of the Competition act, 2002. Afterwards CCI directed the Director General to carry out the investigation of 60 days, and it was found that it is the prima facia case of abuse of dominance under section 4 of the act5. The CCI imposed a penalty of Rs. 52.24 crores, being 6% of the average annual revenue of BCCI for the past three years6. Dhanraj pillay vs. M/s Hockey India (CCI, 73/2011) In this case, the competition commission of India charged Hockey India into anti- competitive practices and abuse of dominance in the market under section 3 and 4 of the act. It was found in the case that Indian Hockey federation (IHF) and Nimbus Sports with International Hockey Federation (FIH), and in that regulation it was notified related with to the events sanctioned and unsanctioned and also the same was communicated to all the National Associations, but afterwards the change in Code of Conduct agreement that participation in the unsanctioned events is against the disciplinary clause. After considering all the aspects of the case it was held that there is no contravention of section 3 and 4 of the Competition act 2002. Because there is no other competitor of Hockey India and they are having the economic power in their hands to regulate it accordingly7. Hemant sharma & others vs. All India Chess Federation (CCI, 79/2011) In this case, the complaint was filed against the All India chess federation, with the direction of Delhi High court in 2011 the writ petition was filed and in this petition it was asked that to direct All India Chess Federation and Ministry of Youth affairs and Sports 5 Competition Commission Of India, https://www.cci.gov.in/sites/default/files/61%20of%202010.pdf 6 SHRI Surinder Singh Barmi v. Board of Control of Cricket in India (BCCI) (case No. 61/2010), LEXOLOGY, February 28 2013 https://www.lexology.com/library/detail.aspx?g=ce867123-0993-4908-8cf0-1afc943f0ff2 7 Dollbonline, Dhanraj pillay v. M/s. Hockey India 2013 comp LR 543 (CCI), August 29, 2017 https://nujssitc.wordpress.com/2017/06/15/an-equal-ground-regulation-of-sports-governing-bodies-analysis- through-competition-law/amp/#referrer=https%3A%2F%2Fwww.google.com&amp_tf=From%20%251%24s JUSIMPERATOR www.jusimperator.org Page 4 VOLUME 2 ISSUE 3 MARCH 2019 ISSN: 2456-9666 not to ban certain players for the life time, who had associated with rival body. The All India chess federation also written to International governing body of chess to not to remove the players for the unauthorised participation. In the order of 2018, CCI concluded with that the AICF code of conduct is very harsh against the players, so there should not be the provision of ban from the game for life time.
Recommended publications
  • The Sotheby's/Christine's Antitrust Scandal and Proposed Changes to Illinois Art Auction Law
    DePaul Journal of Art, Technology & Intellectual Property Law Volume 12 Issue 2 Fall 2002 Article 2 Fix and Tell: The Sotheby's/Christine's Antitrust Scandal and Proposed Changes to Illinois Art Auction Law Donald R. Simon Follow this and additional works at: https://via.library.depaul.edu/jatip Recommended Citation Donald R. Simon, Fix and Tell: The Sotheby's/Christine's Antitrust Scandal and Proposed Changes to Illinois Art Auction Law, 12 DePaul J. Art, Tech. & Intell. Prop. L. 269 (2002) Available at: https://via.library.depaul.edu/jatip/vol12/iss2/2 This Lead Article is brought to you for free and open access by the College of Law at Via Sapientiae. It has been accepted for inclusion in DePaul Journal of Art, Technology & Intellectual Property Law by an authorized editor of Via Sapientiae. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Simon: Fix and Tell: The Sotheby's/Christine's Antitrust Scandal and Pro LEAD ARTICLE FIX AND TELL: THE SOTHEBY'S/CHRISTINE'S ANTITRUST SCANDAL AND PROPOSED CHANGES TO ILLINOIS ART AUCTION LAW Donald R. Simon* I. INTRODUCTION For nearly 200 years, auction houses like Sotheby's and Christie's have been the public's gauge for measuring the value of artwork.' These houses act as agents and guides, offering advice to sellers and collectors while making money by taking commissions.- 2 Auctions are the most popular methods of buying and selling art.' Today, some form of auction comprise nearly fifty percent of transactions involving art.4 Internationally, the auction industry takes in nearly $4 billion dollars annually.' Of that amount, Sotheby's and Christie's, the largest and most influential auction houses,6 control more than ninety percent of the world's auction business.' Although there are many other auction * Director, Business and Legal Affairs, Questar, Inc., Chicago, Illinois.
    [Show full text]
  • Fighting Bid Rigging in Public Procurement: Report on Implementing the OECD Recommendation 2016
    Fighting bid rigging in public procurement Report on implementing the OECD Recommendation 2016 Fighting bid rigging in public procurement Report on implementing the OECD Recommendation 2016 This work is published on the responsibility of the Secretary-General of the OECD. The opinions expressed and arguments employed herein do not necessarily reflect the official views of the OECD or of the governments of its member countries or those of the European Union. This document and any map included herein are without prejudice to the status or sovereignty over any territory, to the delimitation of international frontiers and boundaries and to the name of any territory, city, or area. Please cite this publication as: OECD (2016), Fighting bid rigging in public procurement: Report on implementing the OECD Recommendation © OECD 2016 1 Foreword The 2012 Recommendation of the Council on Fighting Bid Rigging in Public Procurement recommends to governments to strive for public procurement procedures that are designed to promote competition and reduce the risk of bid rigging. Bid rigging, i.e. agreements between bidders to eliminate competition in the procurement process, thereby raising prices, lowering quality and/or restricting supply, is a major risk to the effectiveness and integrity of public procurement and deprives the public sector of genuine opportunities to achieve value for money. For this reason, the fight against bid rigging has become one of the enforcement priorities of competition authorities around the world. The OECD, through its Competition Committee, developed the Recommendation to consolidate OECD good practices and recommend specific steps to render public procurement processes competitive and free from collusion.
    [Show full text]
  • Single Bidders and Tacit Collusion in Highway Procurement Auctions
    University of Kentucky Gatton College of Business and Economics Institute for the Study of Free Enterprise Single Bidders and Tacit Collusion in Highway Procurement Auctions • Collusion in auctions can take different forms, one of which is refraining from bidding • . Certain aspects of highway procurement auctions facilitate collusive outcomes • We analyze both the bid participation decision and the pricing decision • We include variables that affect firm’s’ costs as well as variables that capture competitive and strategic effects • Most importantly, we determine the potential service area of each asphalt plant and use that information to determine the potential bidders for each paving project • We find that, in geographic markets with only a few feasible suppliers, county boundaries serve as a coordinating mechanism for softening competition, significantly influencing firms’ decisions whether and how much to bid Understanding firms’ attempts to collude drives much of economists’ study of oligopoly. Detection and deterrence of collusion are perhaps the primary challenges of antitrust policy.4 In auction markets, collusion has attracted less attention than a general focus on design mechanisms and other factors affecting the competitiveness of such markets.5 Much of the attention paid to collusion in auction markets has been motivated by price fixing and bid-rigging conspiracies in public procurement auctions Bid-rigging schemes can take a variety of forms. Sometimes all participants in an auction are part of an overt conspiracy, and then the challenge becomes determining which conspirator will win the auction and how other conspirators will be compensated. Things change somewhat if non-conspirators participate in the auction. Accommodating behavior by co-conspirators often takes the form of submitting complementary bids above (in a procurement auction) the predetermined winner’s bid.
    [Show full text]
  • Competition Law in India
    MUMBAI SILICON VALLEY BANGALORE SINGAPORE MUMBAI BKC NEW DELHI MUNICH NEW YORK Research MUMBAI SILICON VALLEY BANGALORE 93 B, Mittal Court, Nariman Point 220 S California Ave., Suite 201 Prestige Loka, G01, 7/1 Brunton Rd Competition Law Mumbai 400 021, India Palo Alto, California 94306, USA Bangalore 560 025, India Tel +91 22 6669 5000 Tel +1 650 325 7100 Tel +91 80 6693 5000 Fax +91 22 6669 5001 Fax +1 650 325 7300 Fax +91 80 6693 5001 in India SINGAPORE MUMBAI BKC NEW DELHI Level 30, Six Battery Road 3, North Avenue, Maker Maxity C–5, Defence Colony Singapore 049 909 Bandra–Kurla Complex New Delhi 110 024, India Mumbai 400 051, India Tel +65 6550 9856 Tel +91 11 4906 5000 December 2020 Tel +91 22 6159 5000 Fax +91 11 4906 5001 Fax +91 22 6159 5001 MUNICH NEW YORK Maximilianstraße 13 375 Park Ave Suite 2607 80539 Munich, Germany New York, NY 10152 Tel +49 89 203 006 268 Tel +1 212 763 0080 Fax +49 89 203 006 450 Competition Law in India © Nishith Desai Associates 2020 [email protected] © Nishith Desai Associates 2020 www.nishithdesai.com Competition Law in India December 2020 [email protected] DMS Code: WORKSITE!570106.1 © Nishith Desai Associates 2020 Competition Law in India About NDA We are an India Centric Global law firm (www.nishithdesai.com) with four offices in India and the only law firm with license to practice Indian law from our Munich, Singapore, Palo Alto and New York offices. We are a firm of specialists and the go-to firm for companies that want to conduct business in India, navigate its complex business regulations and grow.
    [Show full text]
  • Global Cartel Enforcement Report
    Global cartel enforcement report February 2020 allenovery.com 2 Global cartel enforcement report | February 2020 Foreword Antitrust authorities around the world continued to focus on tackling national and international cartels in 2019, with many jurisdictions showing an appreciable upturn in the level of fines compared to those imposed in 2018. The European Commission (EC) once again topped the global leader board, with fines totalling USD1.6 billion (up by 74% from 2018). The U.S., Japan, Germany, Italy and France also saw significant increases in the level of fines imposed in 2018, while a number of authorities with a reputation for aggressive enforcement, including South Korea and Brazil, saw a marked drop in their fine totals. But behind the numbers sit several major questions, the answers to which may impact international cartel enforcement in the future: • Will the ever-increasing spread of private damages actions, including a wave of claimant actions in Europe following on from the EC’s Trucks and Forex decisions, ultimately make leniency an unattractive proposition? To date, leniency remains the key enforcement tool in many jurisdictions. 100% of decisions in the EU, UK and Japan included an immunity/leniency applicant, as did the majority of decisions in Brazil, Spain and Hungary. But notably, immunity/leniency applicants featured in only 13% of decisions in China and 8% of decisions in the U.S. • Does the broad use of settlement agreements, and the lower fines they deliver, reduce the need for an ex ante leniency strategy? In the EU, Germany, the UK and the U.S., all decisions in 2019 involved settlement, with the EC’s approach on the Forex cartel signalling a willingness to continue to pursue ‘hybrid’ settlement decisions in the wake of the ICAP and Pometon judgments.
    [Show full text]
  • Bid Rigging an Analysis of Corruption in Auctions
    BID RIGGING AN ANALYSIS OF CORRUPTION IN AUCTIONS YVAN LENGWILER ELMAR WOLFSTETTER CESIFO WORKING PAPER NO. 1488 CATEGORY 9: INDUSTRIAL ORGANISATION JUNE 2005 An electronic version of the paper may be downloaded • from the SSRN website: www.SSRN.com • from the CESifo website: www.CESifo.de CESifo Working Paper No. 1488 BID RIGGING AN ANALYSIS OF CORRUPTION IN AUCTIONS Abstract In many auctions, the auctioneer is an agent of the seller. This invites corruption. We propose a model of corruption in which the auctioneer orchestrates bid rigging by inviting a bidder to either lower or raise his bid, whichever is more profitable. We characterize equilibrium bidding in first- and second-price auctions, show how corruption distorts the allocation, and why both the auctioneer and bidders may have a vested interest in maintaining corruption. Bid rigging is initiated by the auctioneer after bids have been submitted in order to minimize illegal contact and to realize the maximum gain from corruption. JEL Code: D44. Keywords: auctions, procurement, corruption, right of first refusal, numerical methods. Yvan Lengwiler Elmar Wolfstetter University of Basel Humboldt University Berlin Department of Economics (WWZ) Institute of Economic Theory I Petersgraben 51 Spandauer Str. 1 4003 Basel 10099 Berlin Switzerland Germany [email protected] [email protected] This article succeeds our earlier working paper entitled “Auctions and Corruption,” which circulated in various versions since the year 2000. We wish to thank Dirk Engelmann and Nicolas Sahuguet for their comments, and seminar participants at the Universities of Zürich, Bern, Bergen, Melbourne, Queensland, the Stockholm School of Economics, the University of Korea, the SAET meeting 2001, and the FEEM meeting on “Auctions and Market Design” 2002 for interesting discussions.
    [Show full text]
  • Bid Rigging : an Analysis of Corruption in Auctions
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Lengwiler, Yvan; Wolfstetter, Elmar Working Paper Bid rigging : an analysis of corruption in auctions CESifo Working Paper, No. 1488 Provided in Cooperation with: Ifo Institute – Leibniz Institute for Economic Research at the University of Munich Suggested Citation: Lengwiler, Yvan; Wolfstetter, Elmar (2005) : Bid rigging : an analysis of corruption in auctions, CESifo Working Paper, No. 1488, Center for Economic Studies and ifo Institute (CESifo), Munich This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/18952 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu BID RIGGING AN ANALYSIS OF CORRUPTION IN AUCTIONS YVAN LENGWILER ELMAR WOLFSTETTER CESIFO WORKING PAPER NO. 1488 CATEGORY 9: INDUSTRIAL ORGANISATION JUNE 2005 An electronic version of the paper may be downloaded • from the SSRN website: www.SSRN.com • from the CESifo website: www.CESifo.de CESifo Working Paper No.
    [Show full text]
  • Competition in Bidding Markets 2006
    Competition in Bidding Markets 2006 The OECD Competition Committee debated competition in bidding markets in October 2006. This document includes an executive summary and the documents from the meeting: an analytical note by Ms. Sally Van Siclen for the OECD and written submissions: Czech Republic, the European Commission, Germany, Hungary, Indonesia, Japan, Korea, Mexico, Netherlands, New Zealand, Romania, South Africa, Switzerland, Turkey, the United Kingdom, the United States as well as papers from BIAC and Professor Paul Klemperer. An aide-memoire of the discussion is also included. Competition authorities become interested in auctions by a number of routes. In competition advocacy, they may advise other parts of government on how to design auctions in order to improve their efficiency—the degree of competition. They may evaluate mergers and agreements between firms that operate in auction markets. And they may be concerned with collusion and abuse of a dominant position in auctions. Because their formal rules reduce “noise” and make communication among rivals easier, auctions can promote collusion, compared with ordinary “posted-price” markets. But an auction can be designed to reduce collusion or concerted practices or to promote participation. Thus, the design of an auction can be the object of lobbying pressure. Auctioneers can also behave strategically, choosing auction formats or practices that favour competition. Two fundamental prescriptions for effective auction design follow from the theoretical literature: Induce bidders
    [Show full text]
  • Competition News Bulletin
    Competition News Bulletin Delhi • Mumbai • Bengaluru January, 2018 Celebrating over 45 years of professional excellence Inside... I. CARTELS AND ANTI COMPETITIVE AGREEMENTS II. ABUSE OF DOMINANT POSITION / MARKET POWER III. COMBINATIONS IV. MISCELLANEOUS For Private Circulation - Educational & Information purpose only Vaish Associates Advocates …Distinct. By Experience. Competition News Bulletin I. CARTELS AND ANTI-COMPETITIVE AGREEMENTS INDIA Competition Commission of India finds Grasim Industries and others indulging in anti-competitive practices The Competition Commission of India ("CCI") vide its order dated 05.10.2017 has found Aditya Birla Chemicals (India) Limited (ABCIL), Grasim Industries Limited (GIL) and Gujarat Alkalis and Chemicals Limited (GACL) (collectively called as "opposite parties') guilty of bid rigging/ collusive bidding in terms of provisions contained in Section 3(3)(d) of the Competition Act, 2002 ("The Act") and has imposed penalty totaling INR 6.27 Crores. The brief facts are as under. For production of potable water three chemicals, namely, Poly Aluminum Chloride (PAC), Alum (coagulant) and Liquid Chlorine (LC) (disinfectant) are widely used, but PAC is mostly used as it is easy to handle. Delhi Jal Board (the Informant) has been procuring PAC and LC from the Opposite Parties for purification of water through tendering process. The Informant alleged that in case of negotiations over the bid price of PAC/LC, the Opposite Parties used to negotiate/ decrease the prices, to an equal extent. The Informant has further alleged that in negotiation over the bid price all the Opposite Parties used to decide as to how much amount is to be decreased or negotiated from bid/ quoted price.
    [Show full text]
  • BID RIGGING – a Long Time and Persistent Threat to Municipalities
    BID RIGGING – A Long Time and Persistent Threat to Municipalities By: James A. Donahue, III1 Executive Deputy Attorney General Pennsylvania Office of Attorney General Tracy W. Wertz Chief Deputy Attorney General Pennsylvania Office of Attorney General 1 James A. Donahue, III is the Executive Deputy Attorney General for the Public Protection Division and Tracy W. Wertz is the Chief Deputy Attorney General for the Antitrust Section of the Pennsylvania Office of Attorney General. The views expressed in this article are their own and not those of the Office of Attorney General. On December 28, 1894, the Addyston Pipe & Steel Company, of Cincinnati, Ohio; Dennis Long & Company, of Louisville, Kentucky; the Howard-Harrison Iron Company, of Bessemer, Alabama; the Anniston Pipe & Foundry Company, of Anniston, Alabama; The South Pittsburg Pipe Works, of South Pittsburg, Tennessee; and The Chattanooga Foundry & Pipe Works, of Chattanooga, Tennessee met to allocate pipe production among themselves covering all pipe sales in 36 of the 44 United States at the time. The agreement awarded specific tonnage of pipe to be produced by each of the companies. The companies’ production and sales were audited to insure that no one cheated on the agreement. The agreement further provided that: ‘Third. The Addyston Pipe & Steel Company shall handle the business of the gas and water companies of Cincinnati, Ohio, Covington and Newport, Ky., and pay the bonus hereafter mentioned, and the balance of the parties to this agreement shall bid on such work such reasonable prices as they shall dictate. ‘Fourth. Dennis Long & Company, of Louisville, Ky., shall handle Louisville, Ky., Jeffersonville, Ind., and New Albany, Ind., furnishing all the pipe for gas and water works in above-named cities.
    [Show full text]
  • Pilot Auction Facility for Methane and Climate Change Mitigation: Relevant Environmental Auctions
    PILOT AUCTION FACILITY FOR METHANE AND CLIMATE CHANGE MITIGATION: RELEVANT ENVIRONMENTAL AUCTIONS Lawrence M. Ausubel, Peter Cramton, Christina Aperjis and Daniel N. Hauser 14 July 2014 Pilot Auction Facility for Methane and Climate Change Mitigation Contents 1. Introduction ............................................................................................................................. 1 2. Carbon Auctions ...................................................................................................................... 2 2.1 UK Emission Trading Scheme Auction ............................................................................ 2 2.2 Carbon Markets .............................................................................................................. 2 2.3 Auction Format ............................................................................................................... 4 2.4 Experimental Work ......................................................................................................... 4 2.5 Auction Results ............................................................................................................... 5 2.6 Carbon Trading ................................................................................................................ 7 2.7 Lessons Learned .............................................................................................................. 7 3. Other Auctions ........................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Simple Statistical Screens to Detect Bid Rigging
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by RERO DOC Digital Library WORKING PAPERS SES Simple Statistical Screens to Detect Bid Rigging David Imhof N. 484 VII.2017 Faculté des sciences économiques et sociales Wirtschafts- und sozialwissenschaftliche Fakultät Simple Statistical Screens to Detect Bid Rigging David Imhof July 9, 2017 Abstract The paper applies simple statistical screens to a bid-rigging cartel in Switzerland, and shows how well the screens detect it by capturing the impact of collusion on the discrete distribution of the bids. In case of bid rigging, the support for the distribution of the bids decreases involving a lower variance, illustrated by the coefficient of variance and the kurtosis statistic. Furthermore, when firms rig bids without side-payment, the di↵erence between the first and the second lowest bids increases whereas the di↵erence between the losing bids decreases, involving a negatively skewed distribution of the bids, highlighted by the relative distance and the skewness statistic. Finally, the collusive interaction screen shows that the behaviour of firms changed radically between the cartel and post-cartel periods. Therefore, the simple statistical screens proposed in this paper purpose to screen large dataset and to detect bid- rigging cartels by using only information on bids. JEL-Classification C00, C40, D22, D40, K40, L40, L41 Keywords Bid rigging detection, screening methods, variance screen, cover bidding screen, structural and be- havioural screens. Acknowledgement The author would like to thank Christian At, Marc Blatter, Karine Brisset, Stefan Buhler,¨ Alain Egli, Yavuz Karagok,¨ Thierry Madies,` Armin Schmutzler and Markus Wyssling for support and helpful comments.
    [Show full text]