The Great Depression As Historical Problem Author(S): Michael A

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Great Depression As Historical Problem Author(S): Michael A The Great Depression as Historical Problem Author(s): Michael A. Bernstein Source: OAH Magazine of History, Vol. 16, No. 1, The Great Depression (Fall, 2001), pp. 3-10 Published by: Organization of American Historians Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/25163480 . Accessed: 08/05/2011 19:24 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at . http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=oah. Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. Organization of American Historians is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to OAH Magazine of History. http://www.jstor.org From the Editor/Historiography The Great Depression as Historical Problem Michael A. Bernstein now over a It is well half-century since the Great Depression of rates of the fifties and sixties obscured the prewar debates and most severe moment a return the 1930s, the and protracted economic crisis in dissolved for the any fears of to hard times. American history. To this day, there exists no general agree Yet far from being resolved, the concerns and misgivings of the ment to some consensus war about its causes, although there tends be depression and years simply faded from view. It has by now at regarding its consequences. Those who the time argued that the long been fashionable to claim that "Keynes is dead," and few was a to an depression symptomatic of profound weakness in the mecha economists choose engage with the ideas of older generation were to events a nisms of capitalism only briefly heard. After World War II, who struggled understand devastating at time when their views appeared hysterical and exaggerated, as the industri orthodox theories and remedies no longer sufficed. Indeed, the alized nations sustained dramatic rates of growth and as the vast majority of contemporary economists have grown decidedly economics profession became increasingly preoccupied with the hostile to arguments concerning the Great Depression that do not a on run development of Keynesian theory. As result, the economic focus the short or on policy failure. In this respect, they came as slump of the interwar period to be viewed a policy problem have avoided the structural, institutional, and long-run perspec rather than the outgrowth of fundamental tendencies of capital tives more characteristic of the work of their forebears who sought was never a ism. The presumption that the Great Depression could to situate the Great Depression within historical framework that to or more. so an be repeated owing the increasing sophistication of economic spanned several decades By doing, they have lost not some causes analysis and policy formulation. Indeed, the belief became com appreciation simply of possible of the Great monplace that the business cycle was "tamed" and "obsolete." Depression itself, but also of the subsequent development and The erratic performance of the American economy during the performance of the American economy since mid-century. It is for more reason a 1970s and 1980s and recent challenges associated with this that I seek, through reassessment of these older analytical to globalization have made this notion itself obsolete. Entirely new approaches, persuade you of the insight afforded by an understand varieties of economic thinking have emerged, asserting that the ing of "The Great Depression as Historical Problem." government cannot alter levels of real output except under exceptional circumstances. Indeed, confidence in the "Keynesian Trends in the Literature Revolution" has been shaken, and a new "classicism" has come to The older literature concerning the Great Depression in the prominence in economic thought. United States may be broadly classified into three categories. One In this climate of economic opinion, it is important to remem set argued that the severity and length of the downturn was the ber that the postwar optimism for Keynesian economics emerged direct result of the collapse of financial markets that began in at a time of dramatic reconstruction in the world economy and 1929. Such work emphasized the causes of the 1929 crash and concomitant prosperity in the United States. Such hope had been those factors that amplified its impact. Another school of thought absent in the decade of the Great Depression, and even during the concluded that the economic calamity of the 1930s was the direct war a to years there had been apprehension that return depression result of poorly formulated and politically distorted actions under would come close on the heels of victory. But the high growth taken by the government. A third set of research took a broader OAH Magazine of History Fall 2001 3 Bernstein/From the Editor created by the Treaty of Versailles, some writers (such as Irving Fisher and Lionel Robbins) argued that the depression was the The for those inevitable consequence of the chaotic and unstable credit struc challenge ture of the twenties. The principal irritant consisted of a dangerous circle of obligations and risks, epitomized by the Dawes Plan of of us who teach about 1924, in which the United States lent funds to Great Britain, France, and Germany, at the same time the Allies depended on this economic German reparations to liquidate their American debts. By 1928 profound American banks were already quite wary of the situation, but their on to predictable response, cutting back loans European govern worse. crisis is to find ments, merely made the situation Moreover, the demise of the gold standard in international substantive in trade and demands that Germany make reparations payments in ways gold created a net gold flow into the United States that led to a veritable explosion of credit. Extremely unstable credit arrange which to link the once ments thereby emerged in the twenties, and the crash came, the collapse of the banking system was quick to follow. Thus economics of the excessive credit and speculation, coupled with a weak banking network, caused the Great Depression. Another version of the short-run approach concerned the interwar with the on consumer years immediate effects of the crash wealth and spending. The severity of the downturn, it was argued, resulted in a drastic personal and social devaluation of consumer wealth and a loss of confidence in credit. The resulting decreases in purchasing power left the economy of saddled with excess capacity and inadequate demand. were experience None of these short-run arguments completely convinc ing. Because the business confidence thesis was subjective, it was contemporaries. virtually impossible to evaluate in the light of historical evidence. There was also the objection that notions like these mistook effect for cause; the economic circumstances of the thirties may have generated pessimism and panic, rather than being caused by such feelings. Later economists frequently rejected the excessive credit and to in a on too perspective and attempted analyze the depression long-run speculation argument the grounds that it abstracted boldly context. It suggested that whatever the origins of the slump, the from real rather than monetary events in the interwar economy. reasons for its unparalleled length and severity predated and Indeed, business cycle indicators turned down before the stock transcended the events of 1929. market crashed. Indices of industrial production started to fall by the summer of 1929, and a softness in construction activity was The Stock Market Crash as Cause apparent in 1928. Such critics as John Kenneth Galbraith held All short-run analyses of the Great Depression shared a com that "cause and effect run from the economy to the stock on causes mon attribute. They focused the immediate and impacts market, never the reverse. Had the economy been fundamen of the New York Stock Market collapse of 1929, and they asserted tally sound in 1929 the effect of the great stock market crash that the resulting devaluation of wealth and disruption of the might have been small... the shock to confidence and the loss banking system explained the intensity of the crisis. The "business of spending by those who were caught in the market might soon confidence" thesis was perhaps the best example of this school of have worn off." thought. It held that regardless of the mechanisms that caused the As for the wealth and spending hypothesis, the evidence did collapse, the dramatic slide of the stock market created intensely not provide compelling proof. The dramatic decline in consump to to pessimistic expectations in the business community. The shock tion expenditures after 1929 may have been due the stock was so severe a once confidence and unexpected that dramatic panic market debacle; it may have arisen expectations had been took hold, stifling investment and thereby a full recovery. dampened by the events after 1929; or it may have been an A more comprehensive formulation of the short-run argument outgrowth of a declining trend in construction activity and in even directly confronted the question of why financial markets col farm incomes during the twenties.
Recommended publications
  • Ebook Download Lectures on Inequality, Poverty and Welfare 1St
    LECTURES ON INEQUALITY, POVERTY AND WELFARE 1ST EDITION PDF, EPUB, EBOOK Antonio Villar | 9783319455617 | | | | | Lectures on Inequality, Poverty and Welfare 1st edition PDF Book Arthur Lewis Charles L. There is little doubt that good child care can help children succeed and that one way income support can help children succeed is by enabling their parents to purchase better child care. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press. Economic theory Political economy Applied economics. Presidents of the International Economic Association. Growing evidence shows that low income can have lasting adverse effects on children and that bolstering family income can help poor children catch up in a range of areas. Figure 5. In some ways people had got used to the idea that India was spiritual and religion-oriented. Retrieved 26 April The school had many progressive features, such as distaste for examinations or competitive testing. The key approach consists in linking inequality and poverty measurement with welfare evaluation. Resources, Values, and Development. His influential monograph Collective Choice and Social Welfare , which addressed problems related to individual rights including formulation of the liberal paradox , justice and equity, majority rule, and the availability of information about individual conditions, inspired researchers to turn their attention to issues of basic welfare. In the Bengal famine, rural laborers' negative freedom to buy food was not affected. In order for citizens to have a capacity to vote, they first must have "functionings". In addition to his important work on the causes of famines, Sen's work in the field of development economics has had considerable influence in the formulation of the " Human Development Report ", [15] published by the United Nations Development Programme.
    [Show full text]
  • The Institutionalist Reaction to Keynesian Economics
    Journal of the History of Economic Thought, Volume 30, Number 1, March 2008 THE INSTITUTIONALIST REACTION TO KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS BY MALCOLM RUTHERFORD AND C. TYLER DESROCHES I. INTRODUCTION It is a common argument that one of the factors contributing to the decline of institutionalism as a movement within American economics was the arrival of Keynesian ideas and policies. In the past, this was frequently presented as a matter of Keynesian economics being ‘‘welcomed with open arms by a younger generation of American economists desperate to understand the Great Depression, an event which inherited wisdom was utterly unable to explain, and for which it was equally unable to prescribe a cure’’ (Laidler 1999, p. 211).1 As work by William Barber (1985) and David Laidler (1999) has made clear, there is something very wrong with this story. In the 1920s there was, as Laidler puts it, ‘‘a vigorous, diverse, and dis- tinctly American literature dealing with monetary economics and the business cycle,’’ a literature that had a central concern with the operation of the monetary system, gave great attention to the accelerator relationship, and contained ‘‘widespread faith in the stabilizing powers of counter-cyclical public-works expenditures’’ (Laidler 1999, pp. 211-12). Contributions by institutionalists such as Wesley C. Mitchell, J. M. Clark, and others were an important part of this literature. The experience of the Great Depression led some institutionalists to place a greater emphasis on expenditure policies. As early as 1933, Mordecai Ezekiel was estimating that about twelve million people out of the forty million previously employed in the University of Victoria and Erasmus University.
    [Show full text]
  • Efficiency Wages, Insiders and Outsiders, and the Great Depression’
    EFFICIENCY WAGES, INSIDERS AND OUTSIDERS, AND THE GREAT DEPRESSION’ Ranjit S. Dighe State University ofNew York at Oswego ABSTRACT This paper uses available quantitative and qualitative evidence from the I 930s to evaluate two prominent explanations of the wage explosion of the New Deal years of 1933—41: efficiency wages and insider-outsider models. The quantitative evidence includes various data on wage changes, hours, turn over, and strikes. Economically-based efficiency-wage models and the in sider-outsider model are found wanting as explanations of 1 930s labor mar kets. Efficiency-wage theories that emphasize worker morale fare better. This paper explains the 1930s wage burst as an interaction between New Deal policies and efforts by employers to maintain worker morale and productiv icy in a climate of growing union strength. The Great Depression, as the ultimate example of a persistent labor market disequi librium in American macroeconomic history; is inevitably seen by many as the ultimate case of sticky wages. Whatever importance one attaches to wage stickiness as a causal factor behind the mass unemployment of the 1930s, the failure ofthat unemployment to exert greater downward pressure on wages is striking. The downward rigidity ofwages in the Great Contraction of 1929—33 seems to receive the most attention from economic historians, but nearly all of the lasting increase in real wages came during the New Deal years of 1933_41.2 (See Figure.) From 1929 to June 1933, the average hourly earnings (AHE) offactory workers, measured against wholesale prices, rose just 4.5% in real product terms. (In nominal terms, they fell 23.7%, from $.590 to $.450.) From June 1933 when Congress passed the National Industrial Recovery Act (NIRA), the centerpiece of Presi dent Franklin D.
    [Show full text]
  • Lee G. Branstetter
    Lee G. Branstetter Carnegie Mellon University • H. John Heinz III College • School of Public Policy and Management 5000 Forbes Avenue Pittsburgh, PA 15213 • TEL (412) 268-4649 • [email protected] CURRENT ACADEMIC APPOINTMENTS Carnegie Mellon University Pittsburgh, PA Heinz College and Department of Social and Decision Sciences Director, Future of Work Initiative, 2016-present Professor of Economics and Public Policy, 2014-present Associate Professor of Economics and Public Policy (with tenure), 2006-2013 National Bureau of Economic Research Cambridge, MA Research Associate, 2006-present Faculty Research Fellow, 1996-2006 Affiliated with the Program on Productivity, Innovation, and Entrepreneurship and the Program on International Trade and Investment. Peterson Institute for International Economics Washington, DC Nonresident Senior Fellow, 2013-present ____________________________________________________________________________________________________ PREVIOUS APPOINTMENTS Council of Economic Advisers Washington, DC Executive Office of the President of the United States Senior Economist for International Trade and Investment, 2011-2012 Journal of International Economics Associate Editor, 2003-2011 Columbia Business School New York, NY Daniel Stanton Associate Professor of Business, 2004 – 2006 Director, International Business Program, 2002 – 2006 Associate Professor of Finance and Economics, 2001 – 2006 University of California, Davis Davis, CA Director, East Asian Studies Program, 1999 – 2001 Assistant Professor of Economics, 1996
    [Show full text]
  • The Great Depression As a Historical Problem
    Upjohn Institute Press The Great Depression as a Historical Problem Michael A. Bernstein University of California, San Diego Chapter 3 (pp. 63-94) in: The Economics of the Great Depression Mark Wheeler, ed. Kalamazoo, MI: W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research, 1998 DOI: 10.17848/9780585322049.ch3 Copyright ©1998. W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research. All rights reserved. 3 The Great Depression as a Historical Problem Michael A. Bernstein University of California, San Diego It is now over a half-century since the Great Depression of the 1930s, the most severe and protracted economic crisis in American his tory. To this day, there exists no general agreement about its causes, although there tends to be a consensus about its consequences. Those who at the time argued that the Depression was symptomatic of a pro found weakness in the mechanisms of capitalism were only briefly heard. After World War II, their views appeared hysterical and exag gerated, as the industrialized nations (the United States most prominent among them) sustained dramatic rates of growth and as the economics profession became increasingly preoccupied with the development of Keynesian theory and the management of the mixed economy. As a consequence, the economic slump of the inter-war period came to be viewed as a policy problem rather than as an outgrowth of fundamental tendencies in capitalist development. Within that new context, a debate persisted for a few years, but it too eventually subsided. The presump tion was that the Great Depression could never be repeated owing to the increasing sophistication of economic analysis and policy formula tion.
    [Show full text]
  • Alvin Hansen As a Creative Economic Theorist Author(S): Paul A
    Alvin Hansen as a Creative Economic Theorist Author(s): Paul A. Samuelson Source: The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 90, No. 1 (Feb., 1976), pp. 24-31 Published by: Oxford University Press Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1886083 Accessed: 18-07-2015 20:54 UTC Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/ info/about/policies/terms.jsp JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. Oxford University Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Quarterly Journal of Economics. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 132.72.138.1 on Sat, 18 Jul 2015 20:54:30 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ALVIN HANSEN AS A CREATIVE ECONOMIC THEORIST PAUL A. SAMUELSON Early syntheses, 27. - The scholar reborn, 29. - Conclusion, 31. Much has been written about Alvin Hansen, the teacher and scholar - by others in this symposium and by me elsewhere.' My purpose here is to describe his contributions to the corpus of eco- nomic analysis: when all personal influences decay exponentially through time as they must, there remains imperishably locked in the developed corpus of a subject the value-added contributions of a scholar. Men are mortal.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Economics 764 Gerald Friedman United States Economic History
    Economics 764 Gerald Friedman United States Economic History Spring 2016 Economics 764 provides a survey of the economic history of the United States with a focus on the impact of social conflict. My office is 926 Thompson Hall, E-Mail: [email protected]. Hours by appointment. Required readings are marked with a star *. Class discussions will focus on these readings. Students are expected to participate in class discussions and prepare at least 6 papers assessing the week’s readings; papers should be submitted (as email attachment) before 5 PM on Tuesday before class. In addition, you should prepare research proposal including a research plan and an annotated bibliography of the literature on a research question of your choice. Students will present these papers in class after Spring break. 1. Introduction: Approaches to Economic History *Paul David, “CLIO and the Economics of QWERTY,” American Economic Review 75 (1985), 332-37. *Gerald Friedman, Statemaking and Labor Movements, chapter 7. *David Gordon, Richard Edwards, Michael Reich, Segmented Work, Divided Workers (Cambridge, 1982), chs. 1-2. *Alice Kessler-Harris, “The Wages of Patriarchy: Some Thoughts about the Continuing Relevance of Class and Gender,” Labor: Studies in Working-Class History of the Americas 3 (2006), 7-21 *Karl Marx and Frederick Engels, “The Communist Manifesto, Part I” *__________________________, “Eleven Theses on Feuerbach” *Donald McCloskey, "Does the Past Have Useful Economics?," Journal of Economic Literature (1976), 434-61. *Joan Scott, “On Gender,” International Labor and Working Class History (Spring 1987), 1-13. *Joan Scott, “Gender: A Useful Category of Historical Analysis,” American Historical Review (1986), 1053-1075 *Kenneth Sokoloff and Stanley L.
    [Show full text]
  • Sendhil Mullainathan Education Fields Of
    Sendhil Mullainathan Professor of Economics Littauer Center 208 Harvard University Cambridge, MA 02138 [email protected] 617 496 2720 _____________________________________________________________________________________ Education HARVARD UNIVERSITY, CAMBRIDGE, MA, 1993-1998 PhD in Economics Dissertation Topic: Essays in Applied Microeconomics Advisors: Drew Fudenberg, Lawrence Katz, and Andrei Shleifer CORNELL UNIVERSITY, ITHACA, NY, 1990-1993 B.A. in Computer Science, Economics, and Mathematics, magna cum laude Fields of Interest Corporate Finance, Development, Economics and Psychology, and Labor Economics Professional Affiliations and Activities DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, HARVARD UNIVERSITY Professor of Economics, 2004 (September) to present. DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY Mark Hyman Jr. Career Development Associate Professor, 2002-2004 Mark Hyman Jr. Career Development Assistant Professor, 2000-2002 Assistant Professor, 1998- 2000 Courses taught: Macroeconomic Theory (required 1st year PhD course) Economics and Psychology (2nd year PhD Course) Corporate Finance (2nd year PhD Course) AFFILIATIONS Research Associate, National Bureau of Economic Research Member, Russell Sage Foundation Behavioral Economics Roundtable Founding Member, Poverty Action Lab Board Member, Bureau of Research in Economic Analysis of Development Senior Advisor on Behavioral Economics, United States Treasury and Office of Management and Budget, 2010-2011 Faculty Affiliate, Center for International Development, Kennedy School
    [Show full text]
  • The Origins of Modern Labor Economics
    Journal of Labor Research, Volume XXIV, N° 4, Fall 2003 Ideas Versus Ideology: The Origins of Modern Labor Economics LOWELL GALLAWAY and RICHARD VEDDER Ohio University, Athens, OH 45701 Starting with its early twentieth century origins, the development of Labor Economics is traced to the present. We describe an intellectual revolution in which an earlier tra- dition that focused primarily on the institution of the labor union has been replaced by a perspective that emphasizes the various roles played by labor markets in an eco- nomic system. That earlier tradition contained very significant ideological elements, whereas its successor deals much more with the world of ideas. In the course of the debate, which still continues, ideas triumphed over ideology and created modern Labor Economics. I. Introduction When and where did Labor Economics, as it has existed during the twentieth century, come into existence? More importantly, where did the very expression "Labor Eco- nomics" originate? While there may be no precise and definitive answers to these ques- tions, it does seem clear that academic interest in the separate subject, Labor Economics, existed very early in the century. In a fascinating quasi-survey, quasi-review, article written in 1926 by Professor Paul Brissenden of Columbia University, a brief biblio- graphic history of Labor Economics textbooks is provided. Parallelling Brissenden, both in time and subject matter, are a 1926 article by Sumner Slichter and a 1927 piece by Charles E. Persons. One of the striking aspects of the bibliographic references presented by Bris- senden, Persons, and Slichter is the frequent use of the term "problem(s)" in the title of the books referenced.
    [Show full text]
  • The Rise of the Natural-Rate of Unemployment Model
    The University of Notre Dame Australia ResearchOnline@ND Business Book Chapters School of Business 2000 The Rise of the Natural-Rate of Unemployment Model Robert Leeson University of Notre Dame Australia, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://researchonline.nd.edu.au/bus_chapters Recommended Citation Leeson, R. (2000). The rise of the natural-rate of unemployment model. In R. Leeson. The eclipse of Keynesianism: The political economy of the Chicago counter revolution. New York, NY: Palgrave Macmillan. This Book Chapter is brought to you by the School of Business at ResearchOnline@ND. It has been accepted for inclusion in Business Book Chapters by an authorized administrator of ResearchOnline@ND. For more information, please contact [email protected]. 0 Robert Leeson 2000. The Eclipse of Keynesianism: The Political Economy of the Chicago Counter Revolution. New York: Palgrave Macmillan. Chapter 4 The Rise of the Natural-Rate of Unemployment Model 4.1 Introduction With respect to political mythology, the Northern spring of 1968 is chiefly remembered (like its forerunner of 1848) as a 'springtime' of youthful and hirsute left-revolutionary fervour. This revolutionary wave could plausibly include a US President amongst its victims, broken by the weight of office. i In contrast to all this tragedy and melodrama, with respect to influence over economic policy and all that flows from that, the most revolutionary call to arms of that time, was Milton Friedman's American Economic Association (AEA) Presidential Address. Neither youthful nor hirsute, he was an advocate of floating exchange rates, monetary targeting, low if not zero inflation, the abandonment of fine tuning, lower taxes and less regulated markets.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 CHICAGO and INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS1 Malcolm Rutherford
    CHICAGO AND INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS1 Malcolm Rutherford University of Victoria 1. Introduction For most economists the terms “Chicago economics” and “institutionalism” denote clearly antithetical approaches to the discipline. Various members of the modern “Chicago School” have made highly dismissive remarks concerning American institutionalism. Coase has commented that American institutionalists were anti-theoretical, and that “without a theory they had nothing to pass on except a mass of descriptive material waiting for a theory, or a fire” (Coase 1984, p. 230). Some of these attitudes have their roots in the interwar period, most obviously in Frank Knight’s bitingly critical attacks on the methodology and policy positions of institutionalist and advocates of the “social control” of business (Knight 1932). Nevertheless, what this presentation seeks to reveal is a much more complex interrelation between institutional and Chicago economics. To fully understand this relationship it is necessary to begin with the early years of the Chicago Department of Economics. 2. Chicago Economics and Institutionalism 1892-1919 The Chicago Department of Political Economy was begun in 1892 with Laurence Laughlin as its head. While Laughlin was extremely conservative in his economic and political views, and very much at odds with the historicist or “new” school influence in American economics, he built a department that was extremely diverse in its interests and had significant representation of those critical of “orthodox” economics (Nef 1934). Most obviously, Laughlin brought Thorstein Veblen with him from Cornell, and shortly thereafter placed him in charge of editing the Journal of Political Economy. As Hodgson has argued (Hodgson 2004), Veblen’s years at Chicago (from 1892 to 1906) were remarkably creative ones.
    [Show full text]
  • Robert M. Solow How Did Economics Get That Way
    Robert M. Solow How did economics get that way & what way did it get? Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/daed/article-pdf/134/4/87/1829009/001152605774431518.pdf by guest on 03 October 2021 My exposure to economics as a disci- ics, and I would like to provide a few pline began in September 1940 when I then-and-now snapshots. The differ- enrolled as a freshman in the elementa- ence, however, is that with economics ry economics course at Harvard College. something more is called for; the pic- I will try in this essay to make sense of tures have to be connected. I would like the evolution of economics over a span to tell a story about how and why the ar- of more than ½fty years. chitecture of economics changed. It will An analogy that comes to mind is be a sort of Whig history but without the from The Boston Globe. The Sunday edi- smugness. tion occasionally publishes pairs of pho- tographs of urban landscapes. They are There were three textbooks that were taken from the same spot, looking in used in the 1940 economics course at the same direction, but are at least thir- Harvard. One was a standard principles ty, forty, or ½fty years apart. One shows text by Frederic Garver and Alvin Han- a corner of the city as it looked then sen. Hansen had been at Minnesota with and the other as it looks now. Some Garver but by 1940 was a professor at buildings have disappeared, some new Harvard and–although we freshmen ones have been built, and some of the had no inkling–the leading ½gure in old ones are still there but with altered bringing the ideas of John Maynard facades.
    [Show full text]