Chapter 17: Consumption 1
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
Load more
Recommended publications
-
Toward a Theory of Intertemporal Policy Choice Alan M. Jacobs
Democracy, Public Policy, and Timing: Toward a Theory of Intertemporal Policy Choice Alan M. Jacobs Department of Political Science University of British Columbia C472 – 1866 Main Mall Vancouver, B.C. V6T 1Z1 [email protected] DRAFT: DO NOT CITE Presented at the Annual Conference of the Canadian Political Science Association, June 3-5, 2004, at the University of Manitoba, Winnipeg. In the title to a 1950 book, Harold Lasswell provided what has become a classic definition of politics: “Who Gets What, When, How.”1 Lasswell’s definition is an invitation to study political life as a fundamental process of distribution, a struggle over the production and allocation of valued goods. It is striking how much of political analysis – particularly the study of what governments do – has assumed this distributive emphasis. It would be only a slight simplification to describe the fields of public policy, welfare state politics, and political economy as comprised largely of investigations of who gets or loses what, and how. Why and through what causal mechanisms, scholars have inquired, do governments take actions that benefit some groups and disadvantage others? Policy choice itself has been conceived of primarily as a decision about how to pay for, produce, and allocate socially valued outcomes. Yet, this massive and varied research agenda has almost completely ignored one part of Lasswell’s short definition. The matter of when – when the benefits and costs of policies arrive – seems somehow to have slipped the discipline’s collective mind. While we have developed subtle theoretical tools for explaining how governments impose costs and allocate goods at any given moment, we have devoted extraordinarily little attention to illuminating how they distribute benefits and burdens over time. -
ECON 302: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory (Fall 2014)
ECON 302: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory (Fall 2014) Discussion Section 2 September 19, 2014 SOME KEY CONCEPTS and REVIEW CHAPTER 3: Credit Market Intertemporal Decisions • Budget constraint for period (time) t P ct + bt = P yt + bt−1 (1 + R) Interpretation of P : note that the unit of the equation is dollar valued. The real value of one dollar is the amount of goods this one dollar can buy is 1=P that is, the real value of bond is bt=P , the real value of consumption is P ct=P = ct. Normalization: we sometimes normalize price P = 1, when there is no ination. • A side note for income yt: one may associate yt with `t since yt = f (`t) here that is, output is produced by labor. • Two-period model: assume household lives for two periods that is, there are t = 1; 2. Household is endowed with bond or debt b0 at the beginning of time t = 1. The lifetime income is given by (y1; y2). The decision variables are (c1; c2; b1; b2). Hence, we have two budget-constraint equations: P c1 + b1 = P y1 + b0 (1 + R) P c2 + b2 = P y2 + b1 (1 + R) Combining the two equations gives the intertemporal (lifetime) budget constraint: c y b (1 + R) b c + 2 = y + 2 + 0 − 2 1 1 + R 1 1 + R P P (1 + R) | {z } | {z } | {z } | {z } (a) (b) (c) (d) (a) is called real present value of lifetime consumption, (b) is real present value of lifetime income, (c) is real present value of endowment, and (d) is real present value of bequest. -
Shopping Enjoyment and Obsessive-Compulsive Buying
European Journal of Business and Management www.iiste.org ISSN 2222-1905 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2839 (Online) DOI: 10.7176/EJBM Vol.11, No.3, 2019 Young Buyers: Shopping Enjoyment and Obsessive-Compulsive Buying Ayaz Samo 1 Hamid Shaikh 2 Maqsood Bhutto 3 Fiza Rani 3 Fayaz Samo 2* Tahseen Bhutto 2 1.School of Business Administration, Shah Abdul Latif University, Khairpur, Sindh, Pakistan 2.School of Business Administration, Dongbei University of Finance and Economics, Dalian, China 3.Sukkur Institute of Business Administration, Sindh, Pakistan Abstract The purpose of this paper is to evaluate the relationship between hedonic shopping motivations and obsessive- compulsive shopping behavior from youngsters’ perspective. The study is based on the survey of 615 young Chinese buyers (mean age=24) and analyzed through Structural Equation Modelling (SEM). The findings show that adventure seeking, gratification seeking, and idea shopping have a positive effect on obsessive-compulsive buying, whereas role shopping and value shopping have a negative effect on obsessive-compulsive buying. However, social shopping is found to be insignificant to obsessive-compulsive buying. The study has a number of implications. Marketers should display more information about latest trends and fashions, as young buyers are found to shop for ideas and information. Managers should design the layouts with more exciting and impressive features, as these buyers are found to shop for adventure and gratification. Salesmen should take greater care into consideration while offering them to buy products such as gifts, souvenir etc. for their dear ones, as these buyers are less likely to enjoy buying for others. Moreover, business managers should less rely on discount promotions, as this consumer segment is found to be less likely to shop for discounts and bargains. -
The Intertemporal Keynesian Cross
The Intertemporal Keynesian Cross Adrien Auclert Matthew Rognlie Ludwig Straub February 14, 2018 PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE,PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE Abstract This paper develops a novel approach to analyzing the transmission of shocks and policies in many existing macroeconomic models with nominal rigidities. Our approach is centered around a network representation of agents’ spending patterns: nodes are goods markets at different times, and flows between nodes are agents’ marginal propensities to spend income earned in one node on another one. Since, in general equilibrium, one agent’s spending is an- other agent’s income, equilibrium demand in each node is described by a recursive equation with a special structure, which we call the intertemporal Keynesian cross (IKC). Each solution to the IKC corresponds to an equilibrium of the model, and the direction of indeterminacy is given by the network’s eigenvector centrality measure. We use results from Markov chain potential theory to tightly characterize all solutions. In particular, we derive (a) a generalized Taylor principle to ensure bounded equilibrium determinacy; (b) how most shocks do not af- fect the net present value of aggregate spending in partial equilibrium and nevertheless do so in general equilibrium; (c) when heterogeneity matters for the aggregate effect of monetary and fiscal policy. We demonstrate the power of our approach in the context of a quantitative Bewley-Huggett-Aiyagari economy for fiscal and monetary policy. 1 Introduction One of the most important questions in macroeconomics is that of how shocks are propagated and amplified in general equilibrium. Recently, shocks that have received particular attention are those that affect households in heterogeneous ways—such as tax rebates, changes in monetary policy, falls in house prices, credit crunches, or increases in economic uncertainty or income in- equality. -
What Role Does Consumer Sentiment Play in the U.S. Economy?
The economy is mired in recession. Consumer spending is weak, investment in plant and equipment is lethargic, and firms are hesitant to hire unemployed workers, given bleak forecasts of demand for final products. Monetary policy has lowered short-term interest rates and long rates have followed suit, but consumers and businesses resist borrowing. The condi- tions seem ripe for a recovery, but still the economy has not taken off as expected. What is the missing ingredient? Consumer confidence. Once the mood of consumers shifts toward the optimistic, shoppers will buy, firms will hire, and the engine of growth will rev up again. All eyes are on the widely publicized measures of consumer confidence (or consumer sentiment), waiting for the telltale uptick that will propel us into the longed-for expansion. Just as we appear to be headed for a "double-dipper," the mood swing occurs: the indexes of consumer confi- dence register 20-point increases, and the nation surges into a prolonged period of healthy growth. oes the U.S. economy really behave as this fictional account describes? Can a shift in sentiment drive the economy out of D recession and back into good health? Does a lack of consumer confidence drag the economy into recession? What causes large swings in consumer confidence? This article will try to answer these questions and to determine consumer confidence’s role in the workings of the U.S. economy. ]effre9 C. Fuhrer I. What Is Consumer Sentitnent? Senior Econotnist, Federal Reserve Consumer sentiment, or consumer confidence, is both an economic Bank of Boston. -
Intertemporal Choice and Competitive Equilibrium
Intertemporal Choice and Competitive Equilibrium Kirsten I.M. Rohde °c Kirsten I.M. Rohde, 2006 Published by Universitaire Pers Maastricht ISBN-10 90 5278 550 3 ISBN-13 978 90 5278 550 9 Printed in The Netherlands by Datawyse Maastricht Intertemporal Choice and Competitive Equilibrium PROEFSCHRIFT ter verkrijging van de graad van doctor aan de Universiteit Maastricht, op gezag van de Rector Magni¯cus, prof. mr. G.P.M.F. Mols volgens het besluit van het College van Decanen, in het openbaar te verdedigen op vrijdag 13 oktober 2006 om 14.00 uur door Kirsten Ingeborg Maria Rohde UMP UNIVERSITAIRE PERS MAASTRICHT Promotores: Prof. dr. P.J.J. Herings Prof. dr. P.P. Wakker Beoordelingscommissie: Prof. dr. H.J.M. Peters (voorzitter) Prof. dr. T. Hens (University of ZÄurich, Switzerland) Prof. dr. A.M. Riedl Contents Acknowledgments v 1 Introduction 1 1.1 Intertemporal Choice . 2 1.2 Intertemporal Behavior . 4 1.3 General Equilibrium . 5 I Intertemporal Choice 9 2 Koopmans' Constant Discounting: A Simpli¯cation and an Ex- tension to Incorporate Economic Growth 11 2.1 Introduction . 11 2.2 The Result . 13 2.3 Related Literature . 18 2.4 Conclusion . 21 2.5 Appendix A. Proofs . 21 2.6 Appendix B. Example . 25 3 The Hyperbolic Factor: a Measure of Decreasing Impatience 27 3.1 Introduction . 27 3.2 The Hyperbolic Factor De¯ned . 30 3.3 The Hyperbolic Factor and Discounted Utility . 32 3.3.1 Constant Discounting . 33 3.3.2 Generalized Hyperbolic Discounting . 33 3.3.3 Harvey Discounting . 34 i Contents 3.3.4 Proportional Discounting . -
Intertemporal Consumption-Saving Problem in Discrete and Continuous Time
Chapter 9 The intertemporal consumption-saving problem in discrete and continuous time In the next two chapters we shall discuss and apply the continuous-time version of the basic representative agent model, the Ramsey model. As a prepa- ration for this, the present chapter gives an account of the transition from discrete time to continuous time analysis and of the application of optimal control theory to set up and solve the household’s consumption/saving problem in continuous time. There are many fields in economics where a setup in continuous time is prefer- able to one in discrete time. One reason is that continuous time formulations expose the important distinction in dynamic theory between stock and flows in a much clearer way. A second reason is that continuous time opens up for appli- cation of the mathematical apparatus of differential equations; this apparatus is more powerful than the corresponding apparatus of difference equations. Simi- larly, optimal control theory is more developed and potent in its continuous time version than in its discrete time version, considered in Chapter 8. In addition, many formulas in continuous time are simpler than the corresponding ones in discrete time (cf. the growth formulas in Appendix A). As a vehicle for comparing continuous time modeling with discrete time mod- eling we consider a standard household consumption/saving problem. How does the household assess the choice between consumption today and consumption in the future? In contrast to the preceding chapters we allow for an arbitrary num- ber of periods within the time horizon of the household. The period length may thus be much shorter than in the previous models. -
AP Macroeconomics: Vocabulary 1. Aggregate Spending (GDP)
AP Macroeconomics: Vocabulary 1. Aggregate Spending (GDP): The sum of all spending from four sectors of the economy. GDP = C+I+G+Xn 2. Aggregate Income (AI) :The sum of all income earned by suppliers of resources in the economy. AI=GDP 3. Nominal GDP: the value of current production at the current prices 4. Real GDP: the value of current production, but using prices from a fixed point in time 5. Base year: the year that serves as a reference point for constructing a price index and comparing real values over time. 6. Price index: a measure of the average level of prices in a market basket for a given year, when compared to the prices in a reference (or base) year. 7. Market Basket: a collection of goods and services used to represent what is consumed in the economy 8. GDP price deflator: the price index that measures the average price level of the goods and services that make up GDP. 9. Real rate of interest: the percentage increase in purchasing power that a borrower pays a lender. 10. Expected (anticipated) inflation: the inflation expected in a future time period. This expected inflation is added to the real interest rate to compensate for lost purchasing power. 11. Nominal rate of interest: the percentage increase in money that the borrower pays the lender and is equal to the real rate plus the expected inflation. 12. Business cycle: the periodic rise and fall (in four phases) of economic activity 13. Expansion: a period where real GDP is growing. 14. Peak: the top of a business cycle where an expansion has ended. -
Consumption Growth Parallels Income Growth: Some New Evidence
This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: National Saving and Economic Performance Volume Author/Editor: B. Douglas Bernheim and John B. Shoven, editors Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBN: 0-226-04404-1 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/bern91-2 Conference Date: January 6-7, 1989 Publication Date: January 1991 Chapter Title: Consumption Growth Parallels Income Growth: Some New Evidence Chapter Author: Christopher D. Carroll, Lawrence H. Summers Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c5995 Chapter pages in book: (p. 305 - 348) 10 Consumption Growth Parallels Income Growth: Some New Evidence Christopher D. Carroll and Lawrence H. Summers 10.1 Introduction The idea that consumers allocate their consumption over time so as to max- imize a stable individualistic utility function provides the basis for almost all modem work on the determinants of consumption and saving decisions. The celebrated life-cycle and permanent income hypotheses represent not so much alternative theories of consumption as alternative empirical strategies for fleshing out the same basic idea. While tests of particular implementations of these theories sometimes lead to statistical rejections, life-cycle/permanent income theories succeed in unifying a wide range of diverse phenomena. It is probably fair to accept Franc0 Modigliani’s ( 1980) characterization that “the Life Cycle Hypothesis has proved a very fruitful hypothesis, capable of inte- grating a large variety of facts concerning individual and aggregate saving behaviour.” This paper argues, however, that both permanent income and, to an only slightly lesser extent, life-cycle theories as they have come to be implemented in recent years are inconsistent with the grossest features of cross-country and cross-section data on consumption and income and income growth. -
Behavioural Economics Mark.Hurlstone @Uwa.Edu.Au Behavioural Economics Outline
Behavioural Economics mark.hurlstone @uwa.edu.au Behavioural Economics Outline Intertemporal Choice Exponential PSYC3310: Specialist Topics In Psychology Discounting Discount Factor Utility Streams Mark Hurlstone Delta Model Univeristy of Western Australia Implications Indifference Discount Rates Limitations Seminar 7: Intertemporal Choice Hyperbolic Discounting Beta-delta model CSIRO-UWA Behavioural Present-Bias Strengths & Economics Limitations BEL Laboratory [email protected] Behavioural Economics Today Behavioural Economics • mark.hurlstone Examine preferences (4), time (2), and utility @uwa.edu.au maximisation (1) in standard model) Outline (1) (2) (3) (4) Intertemporal Choice Exponential Discounting Discount Factor Utility Streams Delta Model Implications Indifference Discount Rates • Intertemporal choice—the exponential discounting Limitations model Hyperbolic Discounting • anomalies in the standard Model Beta-delta model Present-Bias • behavioural economic alternative—quasi-hyperbolic Strengths & Limitations discounting [email protected] Behavioural Economics Today Behavioural Economics • mark.hurlstone Examine preferences (4), time (2), and utility @uwa.edu.au maximisation (1) in standard model) Outline (1) (2) (3) (4) Intertemporal Choice Exponential Discounting Discount Factor Utility Streams Delta Model Implications Indifference Discount Rates • Intertemporal choice—the exponential discounting Limitations model Hyperbolic Discounting • anomalies in the standard Model Beta-delta model Present-Bias • behavioural -
The Time Series Consumption Function Revisited
ALAN S. BLINDER Brookings Institution and Princeton University ANGUS DEATON Princeton University The Time Series Consumption Function Revisited THERELATIONSHIP between consumer spending and income is one of the oldest statistical regularitiesof macroeconomics-and one of the stur- diest. Like the aging movie star, it needs a little touching up now and again, but always seems to come bouncingback. A dozen yearsago, boththe theoreticalderivation and the econometric form of the aggregateconsumption function were considered settled. Most economists adheredto one of two ways of puttingFisher's theory of intertemporaloptimization into operation: Milton Friedman's per- manent income hypothesis (henceforth, PIH) or Franco Modigliani's life-cycle hypothesis (henceforth,LCH). ' Since each variantseemed to have sound theoretical underpinnings,and since the two had similar econometricforms that explainedthe data well and had similarimplica- tions for policy, there was not a greatdeal to quarrelabout. Perhapsthe most contentious empirical issue was the apparently large marginal This paperhas benefitedfrom the commentsand suggestionsof AlbertAndo, Whitney Newey, and members of the Brookings Panel and from seminar presentationsat the Universityof Warwick,Princeton University, and Johns Hopkins University.We thank Peter Rathjensand Lori Gruninfor researchassistance and the National Science Foun- dationfor financialsupport. 1. Milton Friedman, A Theory of the Consumption Function (Princeton University Press, 1957); Franco Modigliani and Richard Brumberg, -
Intertemporal Choices with Temporal Preferences
INTERTEMPORAL CHOICES WITH TEMPORAL PREFERENCES by Hyeon Sook Park B.A./M.A. in Economics, Seoul National University, 1992 M.A. in Economics, The University of Chicago, 1997 M.S. in Mathematics & C.S., Chicago State University, 2001 M.S. in Financial Mathematics, The University of Chicago, 2004 Submitted to the Graduate Faculty of the Kenneth P. Dietrich Arts and Sciences in partial ful…llment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy University of Pittsburgh 2012 UNIVERSITY OF PITTSBURGH DIETRICH SCHOOL OF ARTS AND SCIENCES This dissertation was presented by Hyeon Sook Park It was defended on May 24, 2012 and approved by John Du¤y, Professor of Economics, University of Pittsburgh James Feigenbaum, Associate Professor of Economics,Utah State University Marla Ripoll, Associate Professor of Economics, University of Pittsburgh David DeJong, Professor of Economics, University of Pittsburgh Dissertation Director: John Du¤y, Professor of Economics, University of Pittsburgh ii INTERTEMPORAL CHOICES WITH TEMPORAL PREFERENCES Hyeon Sook Park, PhD University of Pittsburgh, 2012 This dissertation explores the general equilibrium implications of inter-temporal decision- making from a behavioral perspective. The decision makers in my essays have psychology- driven, non-traditional preferences and they either have short term planning horizons, due to bounded rationality (Essay 1), or have present biased preferences (Essay 2) or their utilities depend not only on the periodic consumption but are also dependent upon their expectations about present and future optimal consumption (Essay 3). Finally, they get utilities from the act of caring for others through giving and volunteering (Essay 4). The decision makers who are de…ned by these preferences are re-optimizing over time if they realize that their past decisions for today are no longer optimal and this is the key mechanism that helps replicate the mean lifecycle consumption data which is known to be hump-shaped over the lifecycle.