Mexico's "Second Agrarian Reform"
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
Load more
Recommended publications
-
Land Inequality and Rural Unrest: Theory and Evidence from Brazil
Land Inequality and Rural Unrest: Theory and Evidence from Brazil Michael Albertus∗ Thomas Brambor† Ricardo Ceneviva‡ Abstract What is the relationship between landholding inequality and rural unrest? And why does land reform that ostensibly addresses rural grievances sometimes exacerbate unrest? We advance the understanding of these longstanding questions by shifting the emphasis from how landholding inequality fuels rural grievances to how it captures the collective action capacity of landowners. Using municipal-level data from Brazil’s large land reform program from 1988 – 2013, we demonstrate that the relationship between landholding inequality and unrest is conditional. Isolated threats to landed elites in the form of land invasions are difficult to repel, generating a positive relationship between landholding inequality and one- off land invasions. By contrast, sustained, broader local threats triggered by nearby land reforms catalyze landowner organization to repel land invasions, leading to the reverse rela- tionship. The findings provide a novel answer for why a straightforward link between land inequality and rural unrest is elusive, and may generalize to a broad range of similar cases. Word count: 10,991 ∗Department of Political Science, University of Chicago, 5828 S. University Avenue, Pick Hall 426, Chicago, IL 60637, phone: (773) 702-8056, email: [email protected]. †Department of Political Science, Lund University, PO Box 52221 00 Lund, Sweden. Phone: +46 (0)46-2224554. Email: [email protected]. ‡Departamento de Ciˆencia Pol´ıtica, Instituto de Estudos Sociais e Pol´ıticos, Universidade do Estado do Rio de Janeiro, Rua da Matriz, 82, Botafogo, Rio de Janeiro, RJ, 22260-100, Brazil. Phone: +55 21 2266-8300. -
Ernesto 'Che' Guevara: the Existing Literature
Ernesto ‘Che’ Guevara: socialist political economy and economic management in Cuba, 1959-1965 Helen Yaffe London School of Economics and Political Science Doctor of Philosophy 1 UMI Number: U615258 All rights reserved INFORMATION TO ALL USERS The quality of this reproduction is dependent upon the quality of the copy submitted. In the unlikely event that the author did not send a complete manuscript and there are missing pages, these will be noted. Also, if material had to be removed, a note will indicate the deletion. Dissertation Publishing UMI U615258 Published by ProQuest LLC 2014. Copyright in the Dissertation held by the Author. Microform Edition © ProQuest LLC. All rights reserved. This work is protected against unauthorized copying under Title 17, United States Code. ProQuest LLC 789 East Eisenhower Parkway P.O. Box 1346 Ann Arbor, Ml 48106-1346 I, Helen Yaffe, assert that the work presented in this thesis is my own. Helen Yaffe Date: 2 Iritish Library of Political nrjPr v . # ^pc £ i ! Abstract The problem facing the Cuban Revolution after 1959 was how to increase productive capacity and labour productivity, in conditions of underdevelopment and in transition to socialism, without relying on capitalist mechanisms that would undermine the formation of new consciousness and social relations integral to communism. Locating Guevara’s economic analysis at the heart of the research, the thesis examines policies and development strategies formulated to meet this challenge, thereby refuting the mainstream view that his emphasis on consciousness was idealist. Rather, it was intrinsic and instrumental to the economic philosophy and strategy for social change advocated. -
National Legislative Framework for Water User Associations out of Sync with Traditional Institutions
National legislative framework for water user associations out of sync with traditional institutions. J. Palerm-Viquiera 1, A. Montes 2 Abstract The central question is how does the existence, change and continuity of a national legislation framework for irrigators’ institutions facilitate or block an effective self governance. The 1992 Mexican water law called for changes in water user associations that are slowly being implemented, these changes have to do with re-drawing the boundaries of the water user association (usually, but not always, smaller), with displacement of village community authority and with an institutional vacuum at river or even canal level. Field work on several case studies has shown that, in spit of the changes, irrigators seem to maintain the traditional management. From the government perspective, notwithstanding that water management is said to be a national priority, there is little interest in strengthening traditional institutions; government field operatives rather insist on the peasants’ failure to comply with the new legislation. However, in Mexico, traditional institutions seem to be capable of circumventing government directives that would impinge on effective irrigation water management. Effective institutional design (and a corresponding national legislation framework) has to start by recognizing the users’ existing institutions and their capacity to build on these institutions; as well as recognizing the costs of ignoring traditional organizations. Keywords: Irrigation District, turn-over, water user organizations, operation, distribution, equity INTRODUCTION The case study of the Tepetitlan Irrigation System is of special interest, with 9,721 irrigated hectares has built a successful non bureaucratic organization. Bryan Burns suggested a case study of new/ surprising/ successful adaptations and not a case study of failure. -
La Apropiación Territorial Del Municipio Del Uxpanapa, Veracruz
IV Congreso Chileno de Antropología. Colegio de Antropólogos de Chile A. G, Santiago de Chile, 2001. La Apropiación Territorial del Municipio del Uxpanapa, Veracruz. Micaela Rosalinda Cruz. Cita: Micaela Rosalinda Cruz. (2001). La Apropiación Territorial del Municipio del Uxpanapa, Veracruz. IV Congreso Chileno de Antropología. Colegio de Antropólogos de Chile A. G, Santiago de Chile. Dirección estable: https://www.aacademica.org/iv.congreso.chileno.de.antropologia/110 Acta Académica es un proyecto académico sin fines de lucro enmarcado en la iniciativa de acceso abierto. Acta Académica fue creado para facilitar a investigadores de todo el mundo el compartir su producción académica. Para crear un perfil gratuitamente o acceder a otros trabajos visite: https://www.aacademica.org. 3. Barahona, Rafael; Aranda, Ximena; Santana, Roberto, 5. Bengoa, José, Historia social de Ja agricultura chilena. El valle de Putaendo, estudio de estructura agraria. U. Tomo 11: "Hacienda y campesinos': Edic. Sur, 1990. de Chile, Instituto de Geografía. Santiago de Chile, 6. Domi, e K, Len ka, La vida rural en el distrito de 1961. Chacabuco: norte de la cuenca de Santiago, Santiago, 4. Bauer, Anold, La sociedad rural chilena. Desde Ja con 1959. Tesis Universidad de Chile. quista española hasta nuestros días. Edit. Andrés Be llo, 1975. La Apropiación Territorial del Municipio del Uxpanapa, Veracruz Micaela Rosalinda Cruz El propósito del presente trabajo es analizar el proceso con otros individuos, constituyeron varias sociedades de apropiación territorial del municipio del Uxpanapa, anónimas para explorar y explotar las riberas del Veracruz, a partir de los mecanismos que han permiti Coatzacoalcos. En ese entonces, el gobierno del esta do dicha apropiación. -
Land Reform in Eastern Europe
Land Reform in Eastern Europe Western CIS, Transcaucuses, Balkans, and EU Accession Countries Renee Giovarelli David Bledsoe Seattle, Washington October 2001 This paper was prepared under contract with the Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO). The positions and opinions presented are those of the author alone, and are not intended to represent the views of FAO. The Rural Development Institute (RDI), located in Seattle, Washington, USA, is a nonprofit 501(c)(3) corporation. RDI is a unique organization of lawyers devoted to problems of land reform and related issues in less developed countries and transitional economies. RDI’s goal is to assist in alleviating world poverty and instability through land reform and rural development. RDI staff have conducted field research and advised on land reform issues in 35 countries in Asia, Latin America, Eastern Europe and the Middle East. For more information about RDI, visit the RDI web site at <www.rdiland.org>. Renee Giovarelli is a staff attorney at RDI and the Director of RDI’s Kyrgyzstan and Women & Land Programs. David Bledsoe is a staff attorney and Deputy Director of Administration at RDI. This report was prepared for submission to the Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations. The authors express their appreciation for the valuable input provided by Roy Prosterman, Leonard Rolfes, and Robert Mitchell. The authors would also like to acknowledge the important contributions of the following RDI Research Assistants to the preparation of this report: Laura Gerber, Oesa Glick, Devon Shannon, Kallie Szczepanski, and Alethea Williams. i Executive Summary The former socialist countries of Eastern Europe (that is, Europe east of Germany and west of the Urals, but including all of Russia) began a transition to a market economy in the late 1980’s and early 1990’s. -
The Effects of Land Redistribution: Evidence from the French Revolution
The Effects of Land Redistribution: Evidence from the French Revolution ∗ Theresa Finley † Raphaël Franck ‡ Noel D. Johnson § Susquehanna University Hebrew University of Jerusalem George Mason University This Version: June 17, 2018 Abstract: This study exploits the confiscation and auctioning off of Church property that occurred during the French Revolution to assess the role played by transaction costs in delaying the reallocation of property rights in the aftermath of fundamental institutional reform. French districts with a greater proportion of land redistributed during the Revolution experienced higher levels of agricultural productivity in 1841 and 1852 as well as more investment in irrigation and more efficient land use. We trace these increases in productivity to an increase in land inequality associated with the Revolutionary auction process. We also show how the benefits associated with the head-start given to districts with more Church land initially, and thus greater land redistribution by auction during the Revolution, dissipated over the course of the nineteenth century as other districts gradually overcame the transaction costs associated with reallocating the property rights associated with the feudal system. Keywords: Institutions, Property Rights, French Revolution, Coase Theorem JEL Codes: N53, O43, P14, D47 ∗We are grateful for comments from Philip Hoffman, Mark Koyama, James Robinson, Jean-Laurent Rosenthal, Nic Ziebarth, and participants in the January 2017 George Mason University Workshop on Economic History and Development as well as seminar participants at Wake Forest University. We acknowledge travel and research support from the Ben Porath Fund & the Department of Economics at the Hebrew University of Jerusalem. All remaining errors are the fault of the Authors. -
Colonial Spanish Terms Compilation
COLONIAL SPANISH TERMS COMPILATION Of COLONIAL SPANISH TERMS And DOCUMENT RELATED PHRASES COMPILATION Of COLONIAL SPANISH TERMS file:///C|/...20Grant%202013/Articles%20&%20Publications/Spanish%20Colonial%20Glossary/COLONIAL%20SPANISH%20TERMS.htm[5/15/2013 6:54:54 PM] COLONIAL SPANISH TERMS And DOCUMENT RELATED PHRASES Second edition, 1998 Compiled and edited by: Ophelia Marquez and Lillian Ramos Navarro Wold Copyright, 1998 Published by: SHHAR PRESS, 1998 (Society of Hispanic Historical and Ancestral Research) P.O. Box 490 Midway City, CA 92655-0490 1-714-894-8161 Cover: Census Bookcover was provided by Ophelia Marquez . In 1791, and again in 1792, a census was ordered throughout the viceroyalty by Viceroy Conde de Revillagigedo. The actual returns came in during 1791 - 1794. PREFACE This pamphlet has been compiled in response to the need for a handy, lightweight dictionary of Colonial terms to use while reading documents. This is a supplement to the first edition with additional words and phrases included. Refer to pages 57 and 58 for the most commonly used phrases in baptismal, marriage, burial and testament documents. Acknowledgement Ophelia and Lillian want to record their gratitude to Nadine M. Vasquez for her encouraging suggestions and for sharing her expertise with us. Muy EstimadoS PrimoS, In your hands you hold the results of an exhaustive search and compilation of historical terms of Hispanic researchers. Sensing the need, Ophelia Marquez and Lillian Ramos Wold scanned hundreds of books and glossaries looking for the most correct interpretation of words, titles, and phrases which they encountered in their researching activities. Many times words had several meanings. -
Land Reform and Bounded Rationality in the Middle East
Domestic Conquest: Land Reform and Bounded Rationality in the Middle East Matthew E. Goldman A dissertation submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy University of Washington 2015 Reading Committee: Reşat Kasaba, Chair Elizabeth Kier Clark Lombardi Program Authorized to Offer Degree: Near & Middle Eastern Studies ©Copyright 2015 Matthew E. Goldman University of Washington Abstract Domestic Conquest: Land Reform and Bounded Rationality in the Middle East Matthew E. Goldman Chair of the Supervisory Committee: Professor Reşat Kasaba Henry M. Jackson School of International Studies This dissertation examines the rise and fall of projects for land reform - the redistribution of agricultural land from large landowners to those owning little or none - in the Middle East in the mid 20th century, focusing on Egypt, Iraq, Palestine/Israel, Syria, and Turkey. Following the end of World War II, local political elites and foreign advisors alike began to argue that land reform constituted a necessary first rung on the ladder of modernization, a step that would lead to political consolidation, development, industrialization, and even democratization. Unfortunately, many land reform projects resulted in grave disappointments, leading to reduced agricultural output, increased rural poverty, political conflict, and more authoritarian rather than more democratic forms of government. As many policymakers and development experts themselves came to understand, an underlying cause of these problems was their failure to adjust land reform models to account for crucial variations in local political, economic, and ecological conditions. Using a method of similarity approach, this project asks why land reform projects so often sought to apply imported models in vastly different local contexts and then failed to adequately adjust these policy models to suit local realities. -
Registro Vias Pecuarias Provincia De Almeria
COD_VP Nombre COD.TRAMO PROVINCIA MUNICIPIO ESTADO LEGAL ANCHO PRIORIDAD USO PUBLICO LONGITUD 04001001 CORDEL DE GRANADA A ALMERIA 04001001_01 ALMERIA ABLA CLASIFICADA 38 1 520 04001001 CORDEL DE GRANADA A ALMERIA 04001001_02 ALMERIA ABLA CLASIFICADA 38 1 1446 04001001 CORDEL DE GRANADA A ALMERIA 04001001_03 ALMERIA ABLA CLASIFICADA 38 1 2140 04001001 CORDEL DE GRANADA A ALMERIA 04001001_04 ALMERIA ABLA CLASIFICADA 38 2 999 04001002 CORDEL DE ESCULLAR 04001002_01 ALMERIA ABLA CLASIFICADA 38 1 11 04001002 CORDEL DE ESCULLAR 04001002_02 ALMERIA ABLA CLASIFICADA 38 0 2964 04001002 CORDEL DE ESCULLAR 04001002_03 ALMERIA ABLA CLASIFICADA 38 1 1379 04001003 VEREDA DE OHANES 04001003_01 ALMERIA ABLA CLASIFICADA 21 1 293 04001003 VEREDA DE OHANES 04001003_02 ALMERIA ABLA CLASIFICADA 21 0 1507 04001004 VEREDA DEL SERVAL 04001004_01 ALMERIA ABLA CLASIFICADA 21 1 3036 04001004 VEREDA DEL SERVAL 04001004_02 ALMERIA ABLA CLASIFICADA 21 1 103 04001005 VEREDA DEL CAMINO DE ESCULLAR 04001005_01 ALMERIA ABLA CLASIFICADA 21 1 639 04001005 VEREDA DEL CAMINO DE ESCULLAR 04001005_02 ALMERIA ABLA CLASIFICADA 21 1 11 04001005 VEREDA DEL CAMINO DE ESCULLAR 04001005_03 ALMERIA ABLA CLASIFICADA 21 1 1251 04001007 COLADA DEL MORAL 04001007_01 ALMERIA ABLA CLASIFICADA 4 1 1058 04002001 CORDEL DE ESCULLAR 04002001_01 ALMERIA ABRUCENA CLASIFICADA 38 0 621 04002001 CORDEL DE ESCULLAR 04002001_02 ALMERIA ABRUCENA CLASIFICADA 38 0 1258 04002002 CORDEL DE GRANADA A ALMERIA 04002002_01 ALMERIA ABRUCENA CLASIFICADA 38 1 933 04002002 CORDEL DE GRANADA A ALMERIA 04002002_02 -
From Land Reform to Industrial Revolution the Mexican Case
FROM LAND REFORM TO INDUSTRIAL REVOLUTION THE MEXICAN CASE EDMUNDO FLORES Among Latin American countries Mexico is the sole country self-suffi- cient in food or, Inore accurately, who exports her agricultural surpluses. The historical key to this secret, and further to the secret of her industrial growth, :nay be found in the role played by the Land Reforln. In this article the author reviews Mexico's development after the Mexican Revolu- tion and clarifies the process from Land Reform to Industrial Revolution. According to data from the Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, the present agricultural product of Latin America decreased nearly ten percent per capita, compared to the period 193~~38. Since then, agricultural imports-mostly foodstuffs-increased more than eighty percent and upset seriously the balance of payments of most Latin American coun- tries. In this depressing panorama of economic stagnation and regression, Mexico is the only exception. The combined effects of land reform, road construction, irrigation, agri- cultural credit, and the spread of many innovations through research extension and training, enabled the agricultural sector to grow at an average rate of more than 50/0 during the last thirty years and turned Mexico into the only Latin American country virtually self-suflicient in food. While growing domestic demand has been met, exports of cotton, coffee, cattle, tomatoes, fresh vegetables, and sugar-cane have increased steadily. Furthermore, until ten years ago it was customary to import corn and wheat to supplement domestic production and meet local demand. Then, quite suddenly, Mexico began to generate surpluses and became an exporter. -
Authoritarian Survival and Poverty Traps: Land Reform in Mexico
World Development Vol. 77, pp. 154–170, 2016 0305-750X/Ó 2015 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved. www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2015.08.013 Authoritarian Survival and Poverty Traps: Land Reform in Mexico MICHAEL ALBERTUS a, ALBERTO DIAZ-CAYEROS b, BEATRIZ MAGALONI b and BARRY R. WEINGAST b,* a University of Chicago, USA b Stanford University, USA Summary. — Why do governments in underdeveloped countries pursue policies that undercut long-term economic growth? Focusing on Mexico’s massive but inefficient land reform, we argue that governments do so to underpin political survival. Using a panel dataset of Mexican states from 1917 to 1992, we find that land distribution was higher during election years and where the threat of rural unrest was greater. Furthermore, PRI support eroded more slowly in states receiving more reform. The program, which carried restrictive property rights, thus served the PRI regime’s electoral interests. But while land distribution generated a loyal political clientele, it generated steep costs – lower long-term economic growth. Ó 2015 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved. Key words — economic growth, land reform, authoritarian regimes, clientelism, redistribution, Mexico 1. INTRODUCTION Mun˜oz-Pin˜a, de Janvry, & Sadoulet, 2003). The literature in political science, history, and sociology suggests that land A general conundrum of government in underdeveloped reform was either employed as an instrument of peasant con- countries is why political officials pursue policies that under- trol or regime ‘‘legitimation” (e.g., Esteva, 1980; Warman, mine long-term economic growth. Governing coalitions in 1972). these countries create monopolies and limit economic entry to We build on these works, focusing on why the governing create rents for favored constituents that distort prices and pre- Institutional Revolutionary Party (PRI) structured property vent competitive markets (North, Wallis, & Weingast, 2009); rights in an inefficient manner. -
Latin-American Land Reform: the Uses of Confiscation
Michigan Law Review Volume 63 Issue 2 1964 Latin-American Land Reform: The Uses of Confiscation Kenneth L. Karst The Ohio State University Follow this and additional works at: https://repository.law.umich.edu/mlr Part of the Comparative and Foreign Law Commons, Land Use Law Commons, Law and Economics Commons, Legal History Commons, Legal Remedies Commons, and the Torts Commons Recommended Citation Kenneth L. Karst, Latin-American Land Reform: The Uses of Confiscation, 63 MICH. L. REV. 327 (1964). Available at: https://repository.law.umich.edu/mlr/vol63/iss2/6 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Michigan Law Review at University of Michigan Law School Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Michigan Law Review by an authorized editor of University of Michigan Law School Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. LATIN-AMERICAN LAND REFORM: THE USES OF CONFISCATION Kenneth L. Karst* N Latin America, every land reform is motivated principally by I political demands for equality, for the redistribution of wealth and income. The statement is true even in those countries where the governments are hostile to the idea of redistribution. Palliatives that exploit the ambiguity of the word "reform" in such countries are aimed at appeasement of the demand for sharing the wealth. Landless peasants and landowners understand perfectly well; yet, many technicians and students of land reform continue to speak a different language, a language in which land reform means anything from agricultural rent control to the introduction of hybrid corn.1 In part, talk of this kind is the product of sophistication.