Economics of the Crisis and the Crisis of Economics 1

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Economics of the Crisis and the Crisis of Economics 1 Arenas ekonomiska råd Rapport 2 Axel Leijonhufvud Economics of the Crisis and the Crisis of Economics Axel Leijonhufvud, professor emeritus UCLA and University of Trento Economics of the Crisis and the Crisis of Economics 2 Publicerat i oktober 2011 ©Författaren och Arena Idé Arena Idé är en del av Arenagruppen www.arenagruppen.se Arenagruppen Drottninggatan 83 111 60 Stockholm Tel (vx) 08‐789 11 60 Fax: 08‐411 42 42 Arenas ekonomiska råd är en verksamhet inom tankesmedjan Arena Idé. Syftet är att utifrån en radikal och progressiv utgångspunkt bredda den ekonomiska och politiska diskussionen i Sverige. Vi vill skapa en oberoende arena för kunskapsutveckling och förnyelse av den ekonomiska debatten. Arenas ekonomiska råd är ett samarbete mellan Arena Idé och Friedrich Ebert Stiftungs kontor i Stockholm. 3 Axel Leijonhufvud Economics of the Crisis and the Crisis of Economics1 Balance sheet troubles 5 Stability and Instability 5 Markets for produced goods 6 Financial markets 7 Leverage Dynamics: The build‐up 8 Instability and Economic Logic 9 Leverage Dynamics: Unravelling 10 Network structures and instability 11 Corridor stability and bifurcation 13 A Complex dynamical System 13 Financial bifurcation 15 Macroeconomics and Financial Economics: In Crisis? 16 ( 1 ) Unemployment in DSGE: An example 16 ( 2 ) Representative agent models, fallacies of composition and instabilities. 18 ( 3 ) Stable GE with “frictions” vs. instability. 18 ( 4 ) Violations of budget constraints and their consequences 20 ( 5 ) An external critique: Ontology 21 1 Lecture given at the Stockholm School of Economics, September 20, 2011 4 Balance sheet troubles This is not an ordinary recession. The problems unleashed by he financial crisis are far more serious and intractable than that. The United States and the Eurozone countries are in the midst of a balance sheet recession. The concept is due to Richard Koo2 who used the term to summarize his diagnosis of Japan’s economic troubles in the wake of its 1992‐93 crisis. A balance sheet recession is fundamentally different from the garden variety and the usual countercyclical policies are not adequate to cope with it. The questions I want to discuss in these lectures all pertain to the extra‐ordinary nature of balance sheet recessions in general and, of course, the present one in particular: What makes them different from ordinary cyclical recessions? How do they come about? What makes them peculiarly intractable? What policies are effective or less effective in dealing with them? Apart from these substantive questions, there is one further question worth considering, namely, what kind of economic theory helps us understand these matters better? And what kinds do not? Stability and Instability How did we end up in our present unpredicted predicament? A short answer would be: By not being alert to the symptoms of instability. Almost all bankers, regulators, policy‐ makers and (of course) economists disregarded the possibility of serious systemic instability. But the widespread assumption that a system of “free markets” is stable needs reexamination. 2 Richard C. Koo, Balance Sheet Recession: Japan’s Struggle with Unchartered Economics and Its Global Implications, Singapore: John Wiley & Sons, 2003 and idem, The Holy Grail of Macroeconomics: Lessons from Japan’s Great Recession, Rev. edn., Singapore: John Wiley & Sons, 2009. 5 Markets for produced goods The beginning student’s first introduction to economics tends to be the supply‐and‐ demand model for a produced good. Two negative feedback loops are supposed to guarantee that the equilibrium is reached (ceteris paribus). If supply exceeds demand, price will rise so as to reduce the discrepancy in quantities. If marginal cost exceeds the demand price, output will decline so as to decrease the discrepancy in values. Both feedbacks reduce the deviation from the market equilibrium which is why they are termed “negative feedbacks.” In principle, it is possible that the interaction between the two feedback controls will generate persistent fluctuations in both output and price but theoretical reasons and practical experience both tell us that this possibility can most often be disregarded. So the conclusion is that we are safe in presuming that the market for any particular produced good will home in towards its equilibrium neighborhood, which is to say, that the market is stable. This presumption has been carried over to general equilibrium systems with an arbitrarily large number of goods. This is the case even though theoretical proofs of the stability of general equilibrium exist only for some special cases of limited interest. But as far as I know – and my knowledge is limited – the economists who in the last 20 or so years have based their macroeconomics on GE constructions have shown little interest in investigating their stability properties. Stability has been taken “on faith.” This faith may have some merit as long as what is being discussed are ( 1 ) Non‐ monetary GE models lacking fractional reserve banks and in which lending and borrowing are intertemporal barter transactions; and ( 2 ) budget constraints are always binding and never violated. These conditions are assumed in Real Business Cycle theory, for example, which pretty much dominated high brow macrotheory just a few years ago. But obviously these assumptions remove us altogether from the world of our experience. 6 Suppose we take stability on faith and trust that “market forces” will always tend to make output and consumption move towards a coordinated equilibrium state. How then explain recessions? Well, there might be conditions that interfere with markets and prevent them from doing their beneficial work. The “wage rigidity” postulated in conventional Keynesian theory as an explanation of unemployment would be an example. The recently dominant DSGE (dynamic stochastic general equilibrium) theory has pursued this logic. But a single “rigidity” does not take us very far in making the models “fit” the data. So we now have large‐scale DSGE models with more than a dozen “frictions” and “market imperfections” – with more to be added, you can be sure, when the models do not fit outside the original sample. It is my belief that this stability‐with‐impediments approach is quite wrong, that it does not explain recent events, and that it fails to suggest the right policies. Financial markets For more than a hundred years the instability of fractional reserve banking was the dominant topic in what came later to be called macroeconomics. Traditional banks had (1) large liabilities in relation to own capital (high leverage) and (2) liabilities of very short maturities relative to their assets (maturity mismatch). High leverage and maturity mismatch remain the keys to financial instability today.3 The Great Depression of the 1930s provided the ultimate lesson that taught us how to control traditional banks. Deposit insurance removed the incentives for depositors to run on banks and thereby also the “contagion” that had characterized the banking panics of the past. Reserve requirements served to limit the leverage ratios of banks. 3 Many observers would add fraud to the causes of recent instability. They are not without reasons. Cf., for example, L. Randall Wray, “Lessons We Should Have Learned from the Global Financial Crisis but Didn’t,” Levy Economics Institute Working Paper, August 2011. 7 The limits on leverage meant that banks by and large were earning the same rate of return on own capital as other industries.4 Leverage Dynamics: The build‐up In the last twenty years, financial institutions have not been satisfied to earn a rate of return no higher than that of other industries. The big investment banks, in particular, have learned to set themselves rate of return targets two or three times what is earned in the “real economy” – and the markets have learned to expect that such returns are actually achieved. The only way in which such returns can be achieved is by operating at high leverage. In retrospect, the piling up of leverage not just by financial institutions but also by other firms and notably by households has been the key to American prosperity since the early 1990s. It was an oft‐repeated cliché among American economists that the American economy performed better than Europe in the 1990s because of its “flexibility.” The simpler truth is that when more or less everybody spends more than he earns this will keep the “good times rolling.” But it leaves a legacy of debt, The arithmetic of leverage is simple enough. A bank with a leverage ratio of 30, which can invest in assets earning just ½ of a percent more than its liabilities, will earn a rate of return of 15%.5 (And if the central bank supplies funds at a rate hardly different from zero, it might be able to do a lot better than that!) Such a handsome return, however, will attract competitors and competition will narrow the margin between rates earned on assets and rates paid on liabilities. To keep its rate of return up as the margin shrinks, the individual bank can pursue one or more of 4Note that this stands in dramatic contrast to recent years when large banks have aimed for – and often achieved – rates of return above 20% while returns in manufacturing, for example, have remained in the single digits. 5 A leverage ratio of 30 is quite high, of course, but in 2007 all the big American investment banks had ratios hovering around that number. Some European big banks have operated with higher ratios than that. 8 several strategies. First, it can increase its leverage further. Secondly, it can move parts of its portfolio into riskier asset‐classes where the rates earned are a bit higher. Third, it can acquire assets too risky for its own portfolio, securitize them in bundles, and sell them off to investors that know no better.
Recommended publications
  • Tribute to Axel Leijonhufvud
    A great teacher 6 Computable economics 24 Experimental Economics 30 Adaptive Economic Process 32 Behavioral Economics 36 Institutional Economics 40 Evolutionary Economic 44 Dynamics Agent-Based Computational 48 Economics Agent-Based Finance 58 Financial Instability and 62 Crisis 68 Networks and Innovation 72 Macroeconomics and Financial Crisis 78 Evolution of Social Preferences 84 Market Design 88 Modularity and Design for Innovation 92 Financial Crisis 98 Inequality and the Changing Distribution of Income 104 Macroeconomic Coordination and Externalities 110 New Thinking on the Firm 118 Macroeconomics after the crisis: looking ahead A GREAT TEACHER 6 his is the last Summer School after almost twenty years. It could be a melancholic event, but should not be so. We had Ta rare chance to reflect on the challenges for economic analysis, in the spirit of open- minded exploration that Axel instilled to the School form beginning to end. This meeting today is also an opportunity to celebrate Axel´s contributions to our craft and to express the gratitude that we (quite a few of us here) feel for having been able to learn for him, professionally, and also personally. It is on both these terms that I would like to offer my brief remarks. I first knew about Axel in Argentina through a friend who referred me to the Spanish translation of the book on Keynes. Those were grim times in the country, economically and otherwise, and we were anxious searching for ideas to understand what had been going on. The book impressed me strongly. It was full of analytical insights on crucial questions about economic coordination, and at the same time, it allowed one to glimpse useful ways to speak about actual experiences of macro instability.
    [Show full text]
  • Fortnightly Market Wrap up Spring Week Edition 31 March 2013
    March 31, 2013 WIC Market Wrap-Up Fortnightly Market Wrap Up Spring Week Edition 31 March 2013 Warwick Investment Club Research Team 1 March 31, 2013 WIC Market Wrap-Up The WIC Market Wrap-Up The WIC Market Wrap-Up is published fortnightly by the Warwick Finance Societies’ (WFS) Warwick Investment Club (WIC) Research Team. Receive the Wrap Up via email newsletter by joining the WFS, or look out for archived issues on www.wfsocieties.com. In this Week’s Issue Editorial – page 3 Italy – page 7 Quantitative Easing and the Italian Political Debacle – Balance Sheet Recession Where we stand now By Daryl Chia, Editor-in-Chief By Marco Ross, Co-Editor US Equities – page 4 Renewables – page 8 Spring in the Step of the Dow Has the Sun Set for the Solar Jones and S&P 500 Industry? By Will Caffrey, Analyst By Richard Low, Analyst The Japanese Economy – page 5 Technology – page 9 Manufacturing – Bad signs for Blackberries – Back in season? the Japanese economy By John Peter Ong, Analyst By Eleanor Gaffney, Analyst Research Team Application Essay – page 10 Cyprus – page 6 The Eurozone Crisis The Significance of the Bailout By Jonathan Denham Deal Research Team Application Essay – page 11 By Melson Chun, Analyst The 2008 Global Financial Crisis By Zak Simpson Warwick Investment Club Research Team 2 March 31, 2013 WIC Market Wrap-Up Editorial nominal line under assets and reduced liquidity-related tail risks, but have not translated to a solution that can Quantitative Easing and the bring about robust long term growth. Balance Sheet Recession Alas, the asset reflation and wealth effect of QE is meaningful only in the short term.
    [Show full text]
  • Understanding the Global Macroeconomic Challenges
    On time, stocks and flows: Understanding the global macroeconomic challenges Claudio Borio Bank for International Settlements Abstract Five years after the financial crisis, the global economy remains unbalanced and many of the advanced countries are still struggling to return to robust, sustainable growth. Taking a historical perspective, I argue that this predicament reflects a failure to adjust to profound changes in the economic landscape, which have given rise to the (re-)emergence of major financial booms and busts. The economic developments that really matter now take much longer to unfold – economic time has slowed down relative to calendar time – and yet the planning horizons of economic agents have shortened. The key problems arise from the cumulative effects of past decisions on stocks, and yet these effects are treated as short- term flow issues. The risk is that instability will become entrenched in the system. Policy needs to adjust. JEL classification: E30, E44, E50, G10, G20, G28, H30, H50. Keywords: short horizons, debt, financial cycle, banking crises, balance sheet recessions. 2 Contents Introduction ............................................................................................................................................... 1 I. The broad canvas .......................................................................................................................... 3 Stylised facts: an economic historian’s perspective ....................................................................... 3 Stylised
    [Show full text]
  • UNIVERSITY of CALIFORNIA DEPARTMENT of ECONOMICS LECTURE 25 BALANCE SHEET EFFECTS APRIL 24, 2018 A. Aggregate Demand Or Potentia
    UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA Economics 134 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Spring 2018 Professor David Romer LECTURE 25 BALANCE SHEET EFFECTS APRIL 24, 2018 I. INTRODUCTION IV. HOUSEHOLD BALANCE SHEETS AND THE GREAT RECESSION A. The housing boom II. KOO’S DIAGNOSIS OF JAPAN’S POOR MACROECONOMIC 1. Mian and Sufi’s hypotheses PERFORMANCE 2. The role of economic fundamentals in house price A. Aggregate demand or potential output? growth B. Credit supply or credit demand? 3. The direction of causation between house prices and C. A “balance sheet” recession credit growth 4. Why did rising house prices raise consumption so III. KOO’S ANALYSIS OF A BALANCE SHEET RECESSION much? A. Koo’s analysis of a balance sheet recession in an IS-MP B. The Great Recession and slow recovery framework 1. Mian and Sufi’s hypothesis B. Is monetary policy effective in Koo’s model of a balance 2. Evidence sheet recession? 3, Discussion C. Is fiscal policy effective in Koo’s model of a balance sheet recession? V. POSSIBLE IMPLICATIONS FOR POLICY D. Is the zero lower bound important in Koo’s model of a balance sheet recession? E. Koo’s evidence F. A balance sheet recession and “debt-deflation” Economics 134 David Romer Spring 2018 LECTURE 25 Balance Sheet Effects April 25, 2018 Final Exam – Basics • Mechanics: • Monday, May 7, 3–6 P.M., 2050 VLSB. • Students with DSP accommodations: You should have received an email from me today. If you did not, please let me know. • Coverage: Whole semester. But: • There will be more emphasis on the material after the midterm.
    [Show full text]
  • Lucas on the Lucasian Transformation of Macroeconomics: an Assessment M
    Lucas on the Lucasian Transformation of Macroeconomics: an Assessment M. De Vroey Discussion Paper 2010-32 LUCAS ON THE LUCASIAN TRANSFORMATION OF MACROECONOMICS: AN ASSESSMENT Michel De Vroey ◊ July 2010 Abstract Robert Lucas is rightfully credited with having changed the course of macroeconomic theory. The aim of this paper is to document his transformation from a potential contributor to Keynesian macroeconomics to the master builder of an alternative paradigm, equilibrium macroeconomics. I reconstruct Lucas’s theoretical journey as involving seven steps: (1) his pre-macroeconomic years, (2) his early work as a macroeconomist, jointly with Rapping, (3) the ‘Expectations and the Neutrality of Money’ 1972 article, (4) his inaugural equilibrium model of the business cycle, (5) his all-out attack on Keynesian macroeconomics, (6) the passing of the baton to Kydland and Prescott, and (7) his standpoint after the victory of the approach he so much contributed to launch. JEL classification: B 22; B 31; E30. Keywords: Lucas, new classical macroeconomics. ◊ IRES, University of Louvain, [email protected] A first version of this paper was presented at seminars given at the University of Toronto and the University of British Columbia. The author is grateful to the participants at these seminars for their remarks. He also acknowledges his gratitude to Robert Lucas for having authorized him to quote from the Lucas Archives held at Duke University, as well as for his comments on the paper. Kevin Hoover’s vivid comments on an earlier version were also stimulating. 1 INTRODUCTION In the late 1970s and the beginning of the 1980s, macroeconomics underwent a radical change, which resulted in the overthrow of Keynesian IS-LM macroeconomics and its replacement by dynamic stochastic general-equilibrium macroeconomics.
    [Show full text]
  • Uncertainty Shocks and Balance Sheet Recessions
    Uncertainty Shocks and Balance Sheet Recessions Sebastian Di Tella∗ MIT Job Market Paper December, 2012 Abstract This paper investigates the origin and propagation of balance sheet recessions in a continuous-time general equilibrium model with financial frictions. I first show that in standard models driven by TFP shocks, the balance sheet channel completely disap- pears when agents are allowed to write contracts on the aggregate state of the economy. Financial frictions still affect the economy, but optimal contracts sever the link between leverage and aggregate risk sharing, eliminating the excessive exposure to aggregate risk that drives balance sheet recessions. As a result, balance sheets play no role in the trans- mission and amplification of aggregate shocks. Motivated by this neutrality result, I consider alternative structural shocks. I show that uncertainty shocks can drive bal- ance sheet recessions, with depressed growth and asset prices, and trigger a “flight to quality” event, with low interest rates and high risk premia. Uncertainty shocks create an endogenous hedging motive, inducing agents to take on aggregate risk even when contracts can be written on the aggregate state of the economy. Finally, I explore the implications for financial regulation. JEL Codes: E32, E44, G1, G12 ∗I am extremely grateful to my advisors Daron Acemoglu, Guido Lorenzoni, and Ivan Werning for their invaluable guidance. I also thank George-Marios Angeletos, Vladimir Asriyan, Ricardo Caballero, Marco Di Maggio, David Gamarnik, Veronica Guerrieri, Leonid Kogan, Andrey Malenko, William Mullins, Juan Passadore, Mercedes Politi, Felipe Severino, Rob Townsend, Victoria Vanasco, Xiao Yu Wang, Juan Pablo Xandri, Luis Zermeño, and seminar participants at the MIT Macroeconomics Lunch for useful suggestions and comments.
    [Show full text]
  • Axel Leijonhufvud’S
    A Dictionary Article on Axel Leijonhufvud’s On Keynesian Economics and the Economics of Keynes: A Study in Monetary Theory by Peter Howitt Brown University January 29, 2002 Draft of an article to be translated into French and published in the Dictionnaire des grandes œuvres économiques, edited by Xavier Greffe, Jérôme Lallement and Michel deVroey, to be published by Éditions Dalloz. On Keynesian Economics and the Economics of Keynes: A Study in Monetary Theory 1. Professor Leijonhufvud’s book, which emerged from his PhD. Dissertation at Northwestern University, was published in 1968, a critical time in the development of macroeconomic theory. Keynesian Economics was at its zenith. Policymakers around the world had adopted it as their guide to conducting stabilization policy. American Keynesians, proudly pointing to the long economic expansion following the 1962 tax-cuts that they had advocated to close the deflationary gap, claimed that their “New Economics” had vanquished the business cycle. Keynesian ideas had won over all but the most willful advocates of laissez-faire, to the point where it was commonly agreed that “we are all Keynesians now.” Keynesian Economics dominated teaching and academic research as much as it did policy-making. The IS-LM model that Hicks and Hansen had extracted from Keynes’s General Theory had become the reigning paradigm of macroeconomics. Theorists had developed choice- theoretic microfoundations for its major components - the consumption function, the demand function for investment and the demand function for money - informed by a huge volume of empirical research. The apparent success of the Keynesian research program had persuaded many that the broad outlines of macroeconomic theory were now settled, that there was nothing left for theorists to do but fill in the details.
    [Show full text]
  • Old Keynesian Economics∗
    Old Keynesian Economics∗ Roger E. A. Farmer† UCLA, Dept. of Economics September 21, 2006 Abstract I provide an outline of how a modern theory of search, modelled by a two-sided matching function, can be used to form a microfoundation to Keynesian economics. This search theory of the labor market has one less equation than unknown and, when combined with the idea that investment is driven exogenously by ‘animal spirits,’ the marriage leads to a microfounded theory of business cycles. This alternative theory has very different implications from the standard interpretations of Keynes that has become enshrined in new-Keynesian economics. I call the alternative, ‘old-Keynesian economics’ and I show that it leads to a model with multiple belief driven steady states. 1 Keynes and the Keynesians In his (1966) book, On Keynesian Economics and the Economics of Keynes, Axel Leijonhufvud made the distinction between the economics of the Gen- eral Theory (Keynes 1936) and the interpretation of Keynesian economics by Hicks and Hansen that was incorporated into the IS-LM model and that forms the basis for new-Keynesian economics. In that book, he pointed out that although the new-Keynesians give a central role to the assumption of sticky prices, the sticky-price assumption is a part of the mythology of Key- nesian economics that is inessential to the main themes of the General The- ory. In this paper I will sketch an alternative microfoundation to Keynesian ∗This paper was prepared for a Conference in honor of Axel Leijonhufvud held at UCLA on August 30th - 31st 2006.
    [Show full text]
  • Inside the Economist's Mind: the History of Modern
    1 Inside the Economist’s Mind: The History of Modern Economic Thought, as Explained by Those Who Produced It Paul A. Samuelson and William A. Barnett (eds.) CONTENTS Foreword: Reflections on How Biographies of Individual Scholars Can Relate to a Science’s Biography Paul A. Samuelson Preface: An Overview of the Objectives and Contents of the Volume William A. Barnett History of Thought Introduction: Economists Talking with Economists, An Historian’s Perspective E. Roy Weintraub INTERVIEWS Chapter 1 An Interview with Wassily Leontief Interviewed by Duncan K. Foley Chapter 2 An Interview with David Cass Interviewed jointly by Steven E. Spear and Randall Wright Chapter 3 An Interview with Robert E. Lucas, Jr. Interviewed by Bennett T. McCallum Chapter 4 An Interview with Janos Kornai Interviewed by Olivier Blanchard Chapter 5 An Interview with Franco Modigliani Interviewed by William A. Barnett and Robert Solow Chapter 6 An Interview with Milton Friedman Interviewed by John B. Taylor Chapter 7 An Interview with Paul A. Samuelson Interviewed by William A. Barnett Chapter 8 An Interview with Paul A. Volcker Interviewed by Perry Mehrling 2 Chapter 9 An Interview with Martin Feldstein Interviewed by James M. Poterba Chapter 10 An Interview with Christopher A. Sims Interviewed by Lars Peter Hansen Chapter 11 An Interview with Robert J. Shiller Interviewed by John Y. Campbell Chapter 12 An Interview with Stanley Fischer Interviewed by Olivier Blanchard Chapter 13 From Uncertainty to Macroeconomics and Back: An Interview with Jacques Drèze Interviewed by Pierre Dehez and Omar Licandro Chapter 14 An Interview with Tom J. Sargent Interviewed by George W.
    [Show full text]
  • June 2014, Several Central Banks Tightened Considerably on Net: in Turkey, by 400 Basis Points, Including a 550 Basis Point Hike in One Day In
    V. Monetary policy struggles to normalise Monetary policy globally remained very accommodative over the past year as policy rates stayed low and central bank balance sheets expanded further. Central banks in the major advanced economies continued to face an unusually sluggish recovery despite prolonged extraordinary monetary easing. This suggests that monetary policy has been relatively ineffective in boosting a recovery from a balance sheet recession. Emerging market economies and small open advanced economies struggled to deal with spillovers from monetary ease in the major advanced economies. They have also kept their policy rates very low, which has contributed to the build-up of financial vulnerabilities. This dynamic suggests that monetary policy should play a greater role as a complement to macroprudential measures when dealing with financial imbalances. It also points to shortcomings in the international monetary system, as global monetary policy spillovers are not sufficiently internalised. Many central banks faced unexpected disinflationary pressures in the past year, which represent a negative surprise for those in debt and raise the spectre of deflation. However, risks of widespread deflation appear very low: central banks see inflation returning to target over time and longer-term inflation expectations remaining well anchored. Moreover, the supply side nature of the disinflation pressures has generally been consistent with the pickup in global economic activity. The monetary policy stance needs to carefully take into account the persistence and supply side nature of the disinflationary forces as well as the side effects of policy ease. The prospect is now clearer that central banks in the major advanced economies are at different distances from normalising policy and hence will exit at different times from their extraordinary accommodation.
    [Show full text]
  • 'Wigforss Connection': the Stockholm School Vs. Keynes
    This article was downloaded by: [University of Stockholm] On: 09 January 2013, At: 06:04 Publisher: Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rejh20 The ‘Wigforss Connection’: the Stockholm School vs. Keynes debate revisited Martin Kragh Version of record first published: 09 Nov 2012. To cite this article: Martin Kragh (2012): The ‘Wigforss Connection’: the Stockholm School vs. Keynes debate revisited, The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, DOI:10.1080/09672567.2012.708770 To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/09672567.2012.708770 PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE Full terms and conditions of use: http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms- and-conditions This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematic reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub- licensing, systematic supply, or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden. The publisher does not give any warranty express or implied or make any representation that the contents will be complete or accurate or up to date. The accuracy of any instructions, formulae, and drug doses should be independently verified with primary sources. The publisher shall not be liable for any loss, actions, claims, proceedings, demand, or costs or damages whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with or arising out of the use of this material.
    [Show full text]
  • Lucas, Keynes, and the Crisis
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Laidler, David Working Paper Lucas, Keynes, and the crisis Research Report, No. 2009-2 Provided in Cooperation with: Department of Economics, University of Western Ontario Suggested Citation: Laidler, David (2009) : Lucas, Keynes, and the crisis, Research Report, No. 2009-2, The University of Western Ontario, Department of Economics, London (Ontario) This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/70391 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Lucas, Keynes, and the Crisis by David Laidler Research Report # 2009-2 July 2009 Department of Economics Research Report Series Department of Economics Social Science Centre The University of Western Ontario London, Ontario, N6A 5C2 Canada This research report is available as a downloadable pdf file on our website http://economics.uwo.ca/econref/WorkingPapers/departmentresearchreports.html.
    [Show full text]