Empirical Analyses in Finance and Macroeconomics

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Empirical Analyses in Finance and Macroeconomics Empirical Analyses in Finance and Macroeconomics The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters Citable link http://nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:40050093 Terms of Use This article was downloaded from Harvard University’s DASH repository, and is made available under the terms and conditions applicable to Other Posted Material, as set forth at http:// nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:dash.current.terms-of- use#LAA Empirical Analyses in Finance and Macroeconomics A dissertation presented by Yueran Ma to The Department of Economics in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in the subject of Business Economics Harvard University Cambridge, Massachusetts April 2018 c 2018 Yueran Ma All rights reserved. Dissertation Advisors: Author: Professor Andrei Shleifer Yueran Ma Professor Edward Glaeser Empirical Analyses in Finance and Macroeconomics Abstract This thesis has three essays which are empirical studies at the intersection of finance and macroeconomics. The topics include low interest rates and financial markets, debt contracts and corporate borrowing constraints, and expectations in finance and macro. The essays hope to provide empirical evidence, using diverse approaches, to better understand the connections as well as differences between classic theories and economic activities in practice. iii Contents Abstract . iii Acknowledgments . xii Introduction 1 1 Low Interest Rates and Risk Taking: Evidence from Individual Investment Deci- sions 3 1.1 Introduction . .3 1.2 Benchmark Experiment . .8 1.2.1 Experiment Design and Sample Description . .9 1.2.2 Results . 16 1.3 Potential Mechanisms . 21 1.3.1 Conventional Portfolio Choice Theory . 21 1.3.2 Reference Dependence . 24 1.3.3 Salience and Proportional Thinking . 27 1.4 Testing Mechanisms . 29 1.4.1 Experiment T1 (Non-Linearity) . 30 1.4.2 Experiment T2 (History Dependence) . 33 1.4.3 Experiment T3 (Salience and Proportional Thinking) . 38 1.5 Suggestive Evidence from Observational Data . 41 1.6 Conclusion . 48 2 Anatomy of Corporate Borrowing Constraints 49 2.1 Introduction . 49 2.2 Corporate Borrowing in the US . 57 2.2.1 Fact 1: Prevalence of Cash Flow-Based Lending . 58 2.2.2 Fact 2: Prevalence of Earnings-Based Borrowing Constraints . 63 2.2.3 Heterogeneity in Corporate Borrowing . 70 2.2.4 Implications . 74 2.3 Cash Flows, Corporate Borrowing, and Investment . 74 2.3.1 Mechanisms . 75 iv 2.3.2 Baseline Test . 78 2.3.3 Exogenous Variations in Operating Earnings: An Accounting Natural Experiment . 90 2.3.4 Additional Discussion . 93 2.4 Property Prices, Firm Outcomes, and Financial Acceleration . 99 2.4.1 Property Value and Corporate Borrowing . 100 2.4.2 The Great Recession: Unpacking the Property Price Effect . 108 2.4.3 Property Price Declines and the Firm Collateral Channel: US and Japan111 2.4.4 Earnings Drop and Firm Outcomes in the Great Recession . 112 2.4.5 Financial Acceleration in General Equilibrium: A Simple Comparison 113 2.5 Conclusion . 115 3 New Experimental Evidence on Expectations Formation 116 3.1 Introduction . 116 3.2 Related literature . 119 3.3 Expectations: Extrapolative vs. sticky . 121 3.4 Experiment Design . 123 3.4.1 Experimental conditions . 123 3.4.2 Payments . 129 3.4.3 Descriptive Statistics . 130 3.5 Empirical Results . 131 3.5.1 Measuring rational expectations . 131 3.5.2 Main Result . 132 3.5.3 Robustness of the estimates to g and l .................. 134 3.5.4 Quantifying the results . 136 3.5.5 Heterogeneity . 139 3.5.6 Individual-level vs Consensus Forecast . 140 3.5.7 Robustness to Experimental Setting . 142 3.6 Conclusion . 151 References 152 Appendix A Appendix to Chapter 1 168 A.1 Proofs . 168 A.1.1 Proof of Proposition 1 . 168 A.1.2 Proof of Proposition 2 . 169 A.1.3 Proof of Corollary 1 . 171 A.1.4 Proof of Proposition 3 . 171 A.1.5 Influence of Gross Framing . 171 v A.2 Additional Discussions . 172 A.2.1 Dynamic Portfolio Choice . 172 A.2.2 Diminishing Sensitivity . 173 A.2.3 Reference Point in Expected Returns . 180 A.2.4 Reference Point Formation . 182 A.2.5 Additional Experiments on History Dependence . 185 A.2.6 Salience and Related Models . 187 A.2.7 Inflation . 190 A.3 Additional Tables and Figures . 195 A.3.1 Additional Experimental Results . 195 A.3.2 Dutch Replication . 203 A.3.3 Additional Results in Observational Data . 206 A.4 Data . 216 A.4.1 List of Experiments . 216 A.4.2 Sources and Variable Definitions for Observational Data . 217 Appendix B Appendix to Chapter 2 218 B.1 Asset-Based Lending and Cash Flow-Based Lending . 218 B.1.1 Aggregate Composition . 222 B.1.2 Firm-Level Composition . 224 B.2 Earnings-Based Borrowing Constraints . 229 B.2.1 Specifications of Earnings-Based Covenant . 229 B.2.2 Other Earnings-Based Constraints . 230 B.3 Classic Models of Corporate Borrowing . 230 B.4 Accounting . 234 B.4.1 EBITDA and OCF . 234 B.4.2 Earnings Management . 241 B.5 Estimates of Market Value of Firm Real Estate . 241 B.5.1 Method 1: Traditional Estimates . 241 B.5.2 Method 2: Property Information from Firm 10-K Filings . 243 B.6 Borrowing Constraints and Financial Acceleration . 245 B.6.1 Set-Up . 245 B.6.2 Collateral-Based Constraints . 248 B.6.3 Earnings-Based Constraints . 251 B.6.4 Financial Acceleration: A Comparison . 254 B.7 Proofs . 256 vi Appendix C Appendix to Chapter 3 260 C.1 Additional tests . 260 C.1.1 Formulation with lags . 260 C.1.2 An alternative model: Adaptive expectations . 261 C.1.3 Estimate robustness across Realizations of the process . 263 C.2 Appendix Figures . 264 C.3 Survey Appendix . 265 C.3.1 Sample Experiment . 265 C.3.2 Variants . 272 vii List of Tables 1.1 Demographics of Benchmark Experiment Samples . 14 1.2 Low Interest Rates and Risk Taking: Benchmark Experiment Results . 19 1.3 Allocations in Various Interest Rate Conditions . 31 1.4 Path Dependence of Investment Decisions . 35 1.5 Baseline and Gross Framing . 40 1.6 Summary Statistics of Observational Data . 44 1.7 Interest Rates and AAII Portfolio Allocations . 46 1.8 Interest Rates and Household Investment Flows . 47 2.1 Composition of Corporate Borrowing . 63 2.2 Summary Statistics of US Non-Financial Firms . 85 2.3 Debt Issuance and Investment Activities: Large Firms w/ EBCs . 86 2.4 Debt Issuance and Investment Activities: Firms w/ Low Prevalence of EBCs 87 2.5 Changes in EBITDA: Accounting Natural Experiment . 93 2.6 Debt Issuance and Investment Activities: Large vs..
Recommended publications
  • Why Has CEO Pay Increased So Much?
    Why Has CEO Pay Increased So Much? Xavier Gabaix and Augustin Landier MIT and NBER, NYU Stern February 14, 2006∗ Preliminary and incomplete — Please do not circulate Abstract This paper develops a simple competitive model of CEO pay. It appears to explain much of the rise in CEO compensation in the US economy, without assuming managerial entrenchment, mishandling of options, or theft. CEOs have observable managerial talent and are matched to assets in a competitive assignment model. The marginal impact of a CEO’s talent is assumed to increase with the value of the assets under his control. Under very general assumptions, using results from extreme value theory, the model determines the level of CEO pay across firms and over time, and the pay-sensitivity relations. We predict that the level of CEO compensation should increase one for one with the average market capitalization of large firms in the economy. Therefore, the eight-fold increase of CEO pay between 1980 and 2000 can be fully attributed to the increase in market capitalization of large US companies. The model predicts the cross-section Cobb-Douglass relation between pay and firm size and can be used to study other large changes at the top of the income distribution, and offers a benchmark for calibratable corporate finance. ∗[email protected], [email protected]. For helpful comments, we thank David Yermack and seminar participants at MIT. 1 1Introduction This paper proposes a neoclassical model of equilibrium CEO compensation. It is simple, tractable, calibratable. CEOs have observable managerial talent and are matched to firms competitively.
    [Show full text]
  • Reporter NATIONAL BUREAU of ECONOMIC RESEARCH
    NBER Reporter NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH Reporter OnLine at: www.nber.org/reporter 2012 Number 1 Program Report IN THIS ISSUE Program Report The Changing Focus of Public Public Economics 1 Economics Research, 1980–2010 Research Summaries Private Health Insurance Markets 7 Transfer of Knowledge across Countries 10 Raj Chetty and Amy Finkelstein* Inflation Forecasting 13 Wealth After Retirement 16 The NBER’s Program on Public Economics (PE) has covered a very wide range of topics since the last program report six years ago. Rather than NBER Profiles 19 attempting to summarize the entire corpus of work that has been done by Conferences 21 this program in the past few years, this report provides a bird’s eye view NBER News 25 of some of the major changes in the field from two perspectives. First, we Program and Working Group Meetings 29 quantify the main trends in public finance research at the NBER over the Bureau Books 35 last thirty years, drawing on statistics from the database of NBER Working Papers. Second, we qualitatively summarize some of the emerging themes of recent research, both in terms of topics and methods. A Statistical Perspective The Public Economics Program began as the Business Taxation and Finance Program, which held its first meeting under the direction of David Bradford in December 1977. It was renamed the Taxation Program in 1980, to reflect the broader research interests of its affiliated researchers. To recog- nize the importance of expenditure as well as tax research, the program was renamed “Public Economics” in 1991, when James Poterba succeeded David Bradford as Program Director.
    [Show full text]
  • Macroeconomic Crises Since 1870
    11302-04_Barro_rev.qxd 9/12/08 1:04 PM Page 255 ROBERT J. BARRO Harvard University JOSÉ F. URSÚA Harvard University Macroeconomic Crises since 1870 ABSTRACT We build on Angus Maddison’s data by assembling inter- national time series from before 1914 on real per capita personal consumer expenditure, C, and by improving the GDP data. We have full annual data on C for twenty-four countries and GDP for thirty-six. For samples starting at 1870, we apply a peak-to-trough method to isolate economic crises, defined as cumulative declines in C or GDP of at least 10 percent. We find 95 crises for C 1 and 152 for GDP, implying disaster probabilities of 3 ⁄2 percent a year, with 1 mean size of 21–22 percent and average duration of 3 ⁄2 years. Simulation of a Lucas-tree model with i.i.d. shocks and Epstein-Zin-Weil preferences accords with the observed average equity premium of around 7 percent on levered equity, using a coefficient of relative risk aversion of 3.5. This result is robust to several perturbations, except for limiting the sample to nonwar crises. n earlier study by Barro used Thomas Rietz’s insight on rare eco- Anomic disasters to explain the equity premium puzzle introduced by Rajnish Mehra and Edward Prescott.1 Key parameters were the probability p of disaster and the distribution of disaster sizes b. Because large macro- economic disasters are rare, pinning down p and the b distribution from historical data requires long time series for many countries, along with the assumption of rough parameter stability over time and across countries.
    [Show full text]
  • Generatiaon NEXT 25 Economists Under 45 Who Are Shaping the Way We Think About the Global Economy
    Generatiaon NEXT 25 economists under 45 who are shaping the way we think about the global economy e asked you, our readers, and assorted international economists and journal editors to tell us which economists under 45 will have the most influence in the coming decades on our under- standing of the global economy. F&D researcher Carmen Rollins gathered information from Wscores of sources to compile this—by no means exhaustive—list of economists to keep an eye on. Nicholas Bloom, 41, British, Stanford University, uses quantitative research to measure and explain management Amy Finkelstein, 40, American, practices across firms and countries. He also researches the MIT, researches the impact of pub- causes and consequences of uncertainty and studies innova- lic policy on health care systems, tion and information technology. government intervention in health insurance markets, and market failures. Raj Chetty, 35, Indian and American, Harvard University, received his Ph.D. at age 23. He Kristin Forbes, 44, American, Bank of England and MIT, combines empirical evidence has held positions in both academia and the U.S. and U.K. eco- and economic theory to research nomic policy sphere, where she applies her research to policy how to improve government pol- questions related to international macroeconomics and finance. icy decisions in areas such as tax policy, unemployment insurance, education, and equal- Roland Fryer, 37, American, Harvard, focuses on the ity of opportunity. social and political economics of race and inequality in the United States. His research investigates economic disparity through the development of new economic theory and the Melissa Dell, 31, American, Harvard, examines poverty and implementation of randomized experiments.
    [Show full text]
  • Rare Disasters and Exchange Rates
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES RARE DISASTERS AND EXCHANGE RATES Emmanuel Farhi Xavier Gabaix Working Paper 13805 http://www.nber.org/papers/w13805 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 February 2008 For helpful comments, we thank Andy Atkeson, David Backus, Robert Barro, Daniel Cohen, Alex Edmans, Christian Julliard, Pat and Tim Kehoe, Raj Mehra, Emi Nakamura, Eric van Wincoop, and seminar participants at Boston University, Dartmouth, LBS, LSE, Minneapolis Fed, NBER, New York Fed, NYU, UBC, and the University of Virginia. Gabaix thanks the NSF for support. The views expressed herein are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer- reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2008 by Emmanuel Farhi and Xavier Gabaix. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Rare Disasters and Exchange Rates Emmanuel Farhi and Xavier Gabaix NBER Working Paper No. 13805 February 2008 JEL No. E43,E44,F31,G12,G15 ABSTRACT We propose a new model of exchange rates, which yields a theory of the forward premium puzzle. Our explanation combines two ingredients: the possibility of rare economic disasters, and an asset view of the exchange rate. Our model is frictionless, has complete markets, and works for an arbitrary number of countries.
    [Show full text]
  • Emmanuel Farhi
    Emmanuel Farhi CONTACT INFORMATION: Department of Economics, Harvard University, Littauer 318 1805 Cambridge Street, Cambridge, MA 02138, USA Phone: (617) 496-1835, Email: [email protected] Web: http://ws1.ad.economics.harvard.edu/faculty/farhi CITIZENSHIP: France (U.S. Permanent Resident) ACADEMIC POSITIONS: 2010-present: Professor of Economics, Department of Economics, Harvard University 2006-2010: Assistant Professor of Economics, Department of Economics, Harvard University OTHER POSITIONS: 2014-present: Member of the Comission Economique de la Nation 2010-2012: Member of the Council of Economic Analysis to the French Prime Minister 2009: Visiting Scholar, University of Chicago 2008-present: Fellow, Toulouse School of Economics 2008-present: Research Affiliate, Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR) 2006-present: Research Fellow, National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) 2005, 2007: Short-Term Visitor, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis EDUCATION: Ph.D. in Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 2006 Fields: Macroeconomics, Public Finance, International Macroeconomics, Finance Graduate of the Corps des Mines, Government and Business Program, 2005 MSc. in Mathematics and Economics, Ecole Normale Superieure, 2001 PUBLICATIONS: [1] “Coordination and Crisis in Monetary Unions” (with Mark Aguiar, Manuel Amador, and Gita Gopinath), forthcoming, Quarterly Journal of Economics. [2] “Dilemma not Trilemma? Exchange Rates and Capital Controls with Volatile Capital Flows”, (with Ivan Werning), IMF Economic Review, Special Volume in Honor of Stanley Fischer, forthcoming. [3] “Liquid Bundles” (with Jean Tirole), Journal of Economic Theory, forthcoming. [4] “How Much Would You Pay to Resolve Long-Run Risk?”, (with Larry Epstein and Tomasz Straleezcki), American Economic Review, September 2014, vol 104 (9). [5] “Sovereign Debt Booms in Monetary Unions” (with Manuel Amador, Mark Aguiar, and Gita Gopinath), American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, May (2014), vol 104 (5).
    [Show full text]
  • Econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) (Ed.) Periodical Part NBER Reporter Online, Volume 2010 NBER Reporter Online Provided in Cooperation with: National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), Cambridge, Mass. Suggested Citation: National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) (Ed.) (2010) : NBER Reporter Online, Volume 2010, NBER Reporter Online, National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), Cambridge, MA This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/61993 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu NBER Reporter NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH Reporter OnLine at: www.nber.org/reporter 2010 Number 1 Program Report IN THIS ISSUE Program Report Economic Fluctuations and Growth Economic Fluctuations and Growth 1 Research Summaries Robert E.
    [Show full text]
  • Xavier Gabaix
    Xavier Gabaix Stern School of Business, Finance Department New York University Ph: 212-998-0257 44 West 4th Street, 9-190 Fax: 212-995-4233 New York, NY 10012, USA [email protected] http://pages.stern.nyu.edu/~xgabaix/ Education HARVARD UNIVERSITY, Cambridge, MA Ph.D. in Economics, 1995-1999. Advisors: Robert Barro, John Campbell, Donald Davis, Edward Glaeser. ECOLE NORMALE SUPÉRIEURE, Paris, France M.A. and Aggrégation of Mathematics, 1991-1995 Professional affiliations and activities NEW YORK UNIVERSITY, Stern School of Business, Finance Department, New York, NY. Associate Professor of Finance, 2007- MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY, Department of Economics, Cambridge, MA. Rudi Dornbusch Career Development Associate Professor of Economics, 2005-2007. Rudi Dornbusch Career Development Assistant Professor of Economics, 2004-2005. Assistant Professor of Economics, 1999 – 2003. Post-Doctoral Fellow, 1998 – 1999. NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH Faculty Research Fellow, 2002-present (Asset Pricing, Economic Fluctuations and Growth) VISITING POSITIONS Princeton University: July 2006-2007 New York University: June-August 2001, 2002 University of Chicago, Department of Economics: September 1999-June 2000 Awards NSF Grant, “Rare Disasters and Exchange Rates,” (with E. Farhi), 2008-2011. Glucksman Institute research prize, second place, 2008 (for “The Age of Reason: Financial Decisions Over the Lifecycle”) Young Scientist Award for Socio- and Econophysics, AKSOE, 2006. NSF Grant, “An Econophysics and Behavioral Approach to Financial Fluctuations,” co-PI, 2005-2008. National Institutes of Health Grant, “Psychological Factors in Economic Lifecycle Decisions,” co-PI, Grant # P01 AG05842, 2004-2008. 1 Morgan Stanley Microstructure Research Grant, with V. Plerou and H.E. Stanley, 2004. NSF Grant, “Understanding Large Movements in Stock Market Activity,” with H.E.
    [Show full text]
  • Behavioral Macroeconomics Via Sparse Dynamic Programming
    Behavioral Macroeconomics Via Sparse Dynamic Programming Xavier Gabaix∗ March 16, 2017 Abstract This paper proposes a tractable way to model boundedly rational dynamic programming. The agent uses an endogenously simplified, or \sparse," model of the world and the conse- quences of his actions and acts according to a behavioral Bellman equation. The framework yields a behavioral version of some of the canonical models in macroeconomics and finance. In the life-cycle model, the agent initially does not pay much attention to retirement and undersaves; late in life, he progressively saves more, generating realistic dynamics. In the consumption-savings model, the consumer decides to pay little or no attention to the interest rate and more attention to his income. Ricardian equivalence and the Lucas critique partially fail because the consumer may not pay full attention to taxes and policy changes. In a Merton- style dynamic portfolio choice problem, the agent endogenously pays limited or no attention to the varying equity premium and hedging demand terms. Finally, in the neoclassical growth model, agents act on a simplified model of the macroeconomy; in equilibrium, fluctuations are larger and more persistent. ∗[email protected]. I thank David Laibson for a great many enlightening conversations about behavioral economics. For useful comments I also thank Adrien Auclert, Robert Barro, John Campbell, John Cochrane, Emmanuel Farhi, Peter Ganong, Mark Gertler, David Hirshleifer, Bentley MacLeod, Mat- teo Maggiori, Jonathan Parker, Michael Rockinger, Thomas Sargent, Josh Schwarzstein, Andrei Shleifer, Bruno Strulovici, Richard Thaler, Jessica Wachter, Michael Woodford, seminar participants at various sem- inars and conferences, and my discussants: Andrew Abel, Nick Barberis, Harrison Hong, Jennifer La'O, Ali Lazrak, Ricardo Reis, Alp Simsek, Alexis Toda.
    [Show full text]
  • A SPARSITY-BASED MODEL of BOUNDED RATIONALITY* Xavier Gabaix
    A SPARSITY-BASED MODEL OF BOUNDED RATIONALITY* Xavier Gabaix This article defines and analyzes a ‘‘sparse max’’ operator, which is a less than fully attentive and rational version of the traditional max operator. The agent builds (as economists do) a simplified model of the world which is sparse, considering only the variables of first-order importance. His stylized model and his resulting choices both derive from constrained optimization. Still, the sparse max remains tractable to compute. Moreover, the induced outcomes reflect basic Downloaded from psychological forces governing limited attention. The sparse max yields a behav- ioral version of basic chapters of the microeconomics textbook: consumer demand and competitive equilibrium. I obtain a behavioral version of Marshallian and Hicksian demand, Arrow-Debreu competitive equilibrium, the Slutsky matrix, the Edgeworth box, Roy’s identity, and so on. The Slutsky matrix is no longer symmetric: nonsalient prices are associated with anomalously small demand elas- http://qje.oxfordjournals.org/ ticities. Because the consumer exhibits nominal illusion, in the Edgeworth box, the offer curve is a two-dimensional surface rather than a one-dimensional curve. As a result, different aggregate price levels correspond to materially distinct competitive equilibria, in a similar spirit to a Phillips curve. The Arrow-Debreu welfare theorems typically do not hold. This framework provides a way to assess which parts of basic microeconomics are robust, and which are not, to the as- sumption of perfect maximization. JEL Codes: D01, D03, D11, D51. I. Introduction at New York University on January 17, 2015 This article proposes a tractable model of some dimensions of bounded rationality (BR).
    [Show full text]
  • Shrouded Attributes, Consumer Myopia, and Information Suppression in Competitive Markets*
    SHROUDED ATTRIBUTES, CONSUMER MYOPIA, AND INFORMATION SUPPRESSION IN COMPETITIVE MARKETS* XAVIER GABAIX AND DAVID LAIBSON Bayesian consumers infer that hidden add-on prices (e.g., the cost of ink for a printer) are likely to be high prices. If consumers are Bayesian, firms will not shroud information in equilibrium. However, shrouding may occur in an economy with some myopic (or unaware) consumers. Such shrouding creates an ineffi- ciency, which firms may have an incentive to eliminate by educating their com- petitors’ customers. However, if add-ons have close substitutes, a “curse of debi- asing” arises, and firms will not be able to profitably debias consumers by un- shrouding add-ons. In equilibrium, two kinds of exploitation coexist. Optimizing firms exploit myopic consumers through marketing schemes that shroud high- priced add-ons. In turn, sophisticated consumers exploit these marketing schemes. It is not possible to profitably drive away the business of sophisticates. It is also not possible to profitably lure either myopes or sophisticates to nonex- ploitative firms. We show that informational shrouding flourishes even in highly competitive markets, even in markets with costless advertising, and even when the shrouding generates allocational inefficiencies. I. INTRODUCTION When consumers make mistakes, firms will try to exploit those mistakes.1 In some markets, competitive pressure may * For useful suggestions we thank our editor and referees, Daron Acemoglu, Simon Anderson, Mark Armstrong, Ian Ayres, Robert Barro, Douglas Bernheim, Andrew
    [Show full text]
  • The Age of Reason: Financial Decisions Over the Life Cycle and Implications for Regulation
    11941-03_Agarwal_rev2.qxd 1/26/10 11:30 AM Page 51 SUMIT AGARWAL XAVIER GABAIX Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago New York University JOHN C. DRISCOLL DAVID LAIBSON Board of Governors Harvard University of the Federal Reserve System The Age of Reason: Financial Decisions over the Life Cycle and Implications for Regulation ABSTRACT Many consumers make poor financial choices, and older adults are particularly vulnerable to such errors. About half of the population between ages 80 and 89 have a medical diagnosis of substantial cognitive impairment. We study life-cycle patterns in financial mistakes using a proprietary database with information on 10 types of credit transactions. Financial mistakes include sub- optimal use of credit card balance transfer offers and excess interest rate and fee payments. In a cross section of prime borrowers, middle-aged adults made fewer financial mistakes than either younger or older adults. We conclude that finan- cial mistakes follow a U-shaped pattern, with the cost-minimizing performance occurring around age 53. We analyze nine regulatory strategies that may help individuals avoid financial mistakes. We discuss laissez-faire, disclosure, nudges, financial “driver’s licenses,” advance directives, fiduciaries, asset safe harbors, and ex post and ex ante regulatory oversight. Finally, we pose seven questions for future research on cognitive limitations and associated policy responses. ost households in the United States have accumulated a substantial Mpool of wealth by the time they retire. Among households with a head aged 65–74, median net worth—including net home equity but excluding public and private defined-benefit claims—was $239,400 in 2007, accord- ing to the 2007 Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF).1 Moreover, household 1.
    [Show full text]