P E R S P E C T I V E S

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

P E R S P E C T I V E S P E R S P E C T I V E S PHOENIX CENTER FOR ADVANCED LEGAL & ECONOMIC PUBLIC POLICY STUDIES Free Markets, Monopolies, and Copyright George S. Ford, PhD June 25, 2014 Critics of copyright law sometimes refer to it as In this PERSPECTIVE, I present a brief argument a grant of a “monopoly” right to the author, against both the use of the “monopoly” artist, or creator of a copyrighted work. In fact, terminology for copyright and the related claim the use of the term “monopoly” in the copyright that copyright is incompatible with laissez-faire context is a misnomer: While a copyright holder capitalism. To do so, I appeal to authority by retains the exclusive rights over his or her own looking at the writings of arguably the three particular work, the artist must compete in the most respected and vocal advocates for laissez- market with many close substitutes and thus faire economics—Ludwig von Mises (mentor of lacks the character of the “textbook” monopolist Friedrich Hayek), Milton Friedman, and and its associated market power (i.e., the ability philosopher Ayn Rand. Given the work of these to raise prices above competitive levels for three, and some modern documents on the issue extended periods of time). Indeed, the related to the “monopoly” lingo, I conclude that consensus today among experts is that the artist the arguments that copyright is inconsistent does not hold a “monopoly” in the usual with laissez-faire capitalism and constitutes a economic/antitrust sense of one actor having “monopoly” are exceedingly difficult positions control of an entire market; rather, the owner of to defend.4 As such, the keys to intellectual a copyright only has control over certain uses of debate surrounding copyright do not lie in such his or her particular work in the market. arguments, but rather rest in a detailed, rational analysis of the trade-offs inherent in specific Notwithstanding the above, those wishing to proposals. argue that copyright is antithetical to laissez- faire capitalism often seek to invoke the word What is Copyright? “monopoly” because of its pejorative nature.1 Since the concept of laissez-faire emerged in the The current legal regime of copyright in the U.S. 16th century as a counter to the widespread use is based on Article I, Section 8, Clause 8, of the of monopoly grants in the mercantilist model U.S. Constitution, which authorizes Congress: adopted by the European governments of that To promote the Progress of Science and useful era (including monopolies over printing), this Arts, by securing for limited Times to Authors link is not terribly surprising.2 Modern and Inventors the exclusive Right to their copyright law secures no such monopoly over respective Writings and Discoveries. printing (or any other mode of expression), but This clause empowers the legislature to secure by casting copyright in opposition to laissez- for authors and inventors the exclusive right to faire capitalism, some hope to sway their respective works and discoveries.5 “conservative” lawmakers to weaken copyright enforcement.3 Of course, the idea of copyright was not original in the U.S. Constitution, but dates back to PHOENIX CENTER PERSPECTIVES 14-04 P E R S P E C T I V E S ancient Jewish and Roman law.6 Yet, the real continues in use to this day, though it is plainly need for formal copyright began with the a misnomer. invention of the printing press in the 15th and 16th centuries. As they did with many In the formative years of the United States, the businesses at this time, the governments of need for copyright was well understood. Europe granted monopolies (in the true sense of However, the development of copyright law the word) in printing and document registration was somewhat ad hoc at first. Congress passed (e.g., the Stationers’ Company in England, the first formal law with the Copyright Law of which had exclusive control over essentially all 1790 (based heavily on the Statute of Anne), printing). Such monopolies were created by which granted a 14-year exclusive right for government so that it could both share in the books, maps and charts (extendable for another profits of such ventures and exercise censorship. 14 years if the author survived the first 14 year At the time, the government’s chosen actors term).7 Subsequent laws and treaties, typically controlled virtually all printing, and thus were extending the term of copyright and broadening very much like a monopolist as understood in its scope (e.g., to musical compositions, pictures, modern economics (i.e., a single seller protected sculptures, derivate works, and so forth), by entry barriers with no close substitutes). appeared in 1831, 1909, 1954, 1971, 1976, 1988, 1992, 1994, 1992, 1994, and 1998.8 Today, copyrights generally expire 70 years after the Given the work of [von Mises, author’s death, a term set in the Sonny Bono Friedman and Rand] … the Copyright Term Extension Act of 1998,9 a term arguments that copyright is proposed, interestingly enough, by John Locke in 1694.10 The Digital Millennium Copyright Act inconsistent with laissez-faire of 1988 is another significant law on copyright.11 capitalism and constitutes a Notably, none of the copyright laws in the U.S. “monopoly” are exceedingly awarded a monopoly right to control the difficult positions to defend. production or distribution of all creations. Since the ratification of the U.S. As with most monopoly privileges of the era, Constitution, the issue was not such exclusive rights began to be curtailed or whether or not to secure the eliminated during the Age of Enlightenment in exclusive right, since that much the late 17th century. The British Statute of Anne in 1710 laid the foundation for most modern seems required. Rather, the issue is copyright law. Rather than creating the form such rights take and the government-sanctioned printing monopolists, types of work the law encompasses. the Statute of Anne granted an exclusive right, limited in duration, directly to the author (and his or her chosen printer) of a particular work. Since authors and printers were numerous, the market Obviously, copyright law has evolved over time, for intellectual property was now competitive in both generally and in the United States. Since nature, and censorship was greatly curtailed. the ratification of the U.S. Constitution, the issue Unfortunately, even though modern copyright was not whether or not to secure the exclusive law does not grant a monopoly over “printing” right, since that much seems required. Rather, all materials, the “monopoly” language the issue is the form such rights take and the types of work the law encompasses. PHOENIX CENTER PERSPECTIVES 14-04 PAGE 2 P E R S P E C T I V E S Markets, Monopoly and Copyright “laissez faire”—an idea attributed to the 18th century group of economists known as the The copyright equals “monopoly” and is Physiocrats—became popular at a time when antithetical to laissez-faire capitalism positions government-granted monopolies (and other are made most directly in the retracted 2012 forms of regulation) were common, especially in Republican Study Committee (“RSC”) Report: France.14 Adam Smith was heavily influenced by the Physiocrats and their laissez-faire Copyright violates nearly every tenet of laissez- faire capitalism. Under the current system of philosophy, and his Wealth of Nations was copyright, producers of content are entitled to a largely a brief against such monopoly grants guaranteed, government instituted, government (and other forms of regulation, collectively subsidized content-monopoly.12 known as Mercantilism).15 While I do not and cannot ascribe this extreme position to all those calling for copyright reform, … U.S. copyright law does not the sentiments regarding “laissez-faire” and “monopoly” appear, to varying degrees, in other grant monopolies, but rather secures statements regarding copyright. rights to authors, artists, performers, designers and other Certainly, the use of the term “monopoly” can be found in legal scholarship, economic creators in their particular works. research, and case law. I suspect the use of Such artists must compete with “monopoly” terminology is largely attributable thousands of others for the to the practices in the distant past, when, in fact, attention of the consumer, so government-sanctioned monopolies in printing were granted. Again, U.S. copyright law does modern copyright is a far cry from not grant monopolies, but rather secures rights the actual practices centuries ago of to authors, artists, performers, designers and granting a monopoly. other creators in their particular works. Such artists must compete with thousands of others for the attention of the consumer, so modern copyright is a far cry from the actual practices I believe this view that copyright is incompatible centuries ago of granting a monopoly. Also, with laissez-faire capitalism and constitutes a government no longer plays a (meaningful) role monopoly is incorrect, but let’s not take my in what gets printed, sung, or painted in the word for it. Below, I will consider the opinions U.S., so censorship is not an issue. of three of history’s most recognized advocates of laissez-faire capitalism—Ludwig von Mises, Unfortunately, the “monopoly” terminology Milton Friedman and Ayn Rand. Among persists. As a consequence, analysts often economists, Ludwig von Mises (1881-1973) evaluate copyright using the simple economic makes one of the strongest cases for laissez-faire arguments against monopoly despite the fact capitalism. His views are described by the that monopoly is no longer a good fit for Ludwig von Mises Institute (located near my copyright. Monopoly is also most amenable to alma mater, Auburn University) as follows: the mathematical modeling of economists, and I Mises concluded that the only viable economic suspect this fact plays a large role in the use of policy for the human race was a policy of 13 the “monopoly” lingo in economic research.
Recommended publications
  • Consumers' Surplus 1506 26
    Consumers’ surplus when individuals lack integrated preferences: a development of some ideas from Dupuit Robert Sugden School of Economics, University of East Anglia Norwich NR4 7TJ, United Kingdom [email protected] 25 June 2015 Abstract: In modern economics, consumers’ surplus is understood as the sum of individuals’ compensating variations, defined by reference to well-behaved preferences. If individuals lack integrated preferences, as behavioural economics suggests they often do, consumers’ surplus cannot be defined. However, Dupuit – the earliest theorist of consumers’ surplus – did not assume integrated preferences. His concept of consumers’ surplus can be interpreted in terms of the maximum yield of discriminatory prices. In principle, this can be measured without making assumptions about preferences, but (contrary to what Dupuit apparently thought) is not in general equal to the area under the observed demand curve. Keywords : consumers’ surplus, price discrimination, integrated preferences, Dupuit Acknowledgements : This paper was presented at the conference of the European Society for History of Economic Thought, Lausanne, May 2014. I thank participants at this conference and three anonymous referees for their comments. My work was supported by the Economic and Social Research Council through the Network for Integrated Behavioural Science (grant reference ES/K002201/1). 1 ‘Hence the saying which we shall often repeat because it is often forgotten: the only real utility is that which people are willing to pay for’ (Jules Dupuit, 1844/ 1952, p. 262). Consumers’ surplus is one of the most important theoretical constructs in applied welfare economics. It plays an essential part in normative economic analyses of competition policy, of price regulation for natural monopolies, and of public provision of non-marketed goods such as road space, flood protection and free health care.
    [Show full text]
  • The Law and Economics of Price Discrimination in Modern Economies: Time for Reconciliation?
    Scholarship Repository University of Minnesota Law School Articles Faculty Scholarship 2010 The Law and Economics of Price Discrimination in Modern Economies: Time for Reconciliation? Daniel J. Gifford University of Minnesota Law School, [email protected] Robert T. Kudrle University of Minnesota Hubert Humphrey Institute of Public Affairs, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.umn.edu/faculty_articles Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Daniel J. Gifford and Robert T. Kudrle, The Law and Economics of Price Discrimination in Modern Economies: Time for Reconciliation?, 43 U.C. DAVIS L. REV. 1235 (2010), available at https://scholarship.law.umn.edu/faculty_articles/358. This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the University of Minnesota Law School. It has been accepted for inclusion in the Faculty Scholarship collection by an authorized administrator of the Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. The Law and Economics of Price Discrimination in Modern Economies: Time for Reconciliation? Daniel J. Gifford* Robert T. Kudrle** TABLE OF CONTENTS INTRODUCTION: LAWS TARGETING PRICE DISCRIMINATION .............. 1237 1. ECONOMIC CONCEPTIONS OF PRICE DISCRIMINATION: A BRIEF R EVIEW ..................................................................... 1239 A. Price Discrimination,Defined .......................................... 1239 B. Arbitrage,Market Power, and PriceDiscrimination ........ 1243 C. Price DiscriminationInvolving the Rates
    [Show full text]
  • Friedrich A. Von Hayek Papers, Date (Inclusive): 1906-2005 Collection Number: 86002 Creator: Hayek, Friedrich A
    http://oac.cdlib.org/findaid/ark:/13030/kt3v19n8zw No online items Register of the Friedrich A. von Hayek Papers Processed by Linda Bernard and David Jacobs Hoover Institution Archives Stanford University Stanford, California 94305-6010 Phone: (650) 723-3563 Fax: (650) 725-3445 Email: [email protected] © 1998, 2003, 2011 Hoover Institution Archives. All rights reserved. Register of the Friedrich A. von 86002 1 Hayek Papers Register of the Friedrich A. von Hayek Papers Hoover Institution Archives Stanford University Stanford, California Contact Information Hoover Institution Archives Stanford University Stanford, California 94305-6010 Phone: (650) 723-3563 Fax: (650) 725-3445 Email: [email protected] Processed by: Linda Bernard and David Jacobs Date Completed: 1998, 2000, 2011 Encoded by: James Lake, ByteManagers using OAC finding aid conversion service specifications, and Elizabeth Phillips © 2011 Hoover Institution Archives. All rights reserved. Descriptive Summary Title: Friedrich A. von Hayek papers, Date (inclusive): 1906-2005 Collection number: 86002 Creator: Hayek, Friedrich A. von (Friedrich August), 1899-1992. Extent: 139 manuscript boxes, 8 oversize boxes, 23 card file boxes, 5 envelopes, 2 audio tapes, 16 videotape cassettes, digital files(66 linear feet) Repository: Hoover Institution Archives Stanford, California 94305-6010 Abstract: Diaries, correspondence, speeches and writings, notes, conference papers, conference programs, printed matter, sound recordings, and photographs, relating to laissez-faire economics and associated concepts of liberty, and especially to activities of the Mont Pèlerin Society. Most of collection also available on microfilm (91 reels). Sound use copies of sound recordings available. Physical Location: Hoover Institution Archives Language: English and German. Access Collection is open for research.
    [Show full text]
  • Space, Railways, and Market Structures1
    Space, Railways, and Market Structures1 In Memory of Héctor Grupe By Manuel Fernández López Institute of Economic Research (University of Buenos Aires), CONICET, and National Academy of Economic Sciences 1. Introduction The market demand for a good descends when its price increases. This is a plain fact, observable in the real world. However the same fact may mean different things for the seller, according to the number of other competitors operating in the market. When the number is high, and thus small the part of total production under control of an individual business, any seller may change its own supply without altering the market price. If he supplies more, this doesn't cause the market price to be diminished. Any individual supplier, at the market price, may throw on the market at the same price all the units supplied, whatever the quantity. Selling one unit more accrues to him an additional gross revenue (i.e. “marginal revenue”) equal to the price (or unit revenue). His profit is increased whenever the selling of one unit more causes a cost-increase which is less than the increase of gross revenue: that is, when marginal cost is less than the market price. On the contrary, when the share of the individual seller in the market supply is significant, an increase of his individual supply is perceived by the market as a greater supply, and thus the market price decreases. All the more when the seller is just one (a monopoly) for the whole market. In such a case, the market demand is also the monopolist's unit or average revenue.
    [Show full text]
  • Jules Dupuit and the Railroads: What Is the Role of the State? Philippe Poinsot
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Archive Ouverte en Sciences de l'Information et de la Communication Jules Dupuit and the railroads: what is the role of the State? Philippe Poinsot To cite this version: Philippe Poinsot. Jules Dupuit and the railroads: what is the role of the State?. Journal of the History of Economic Thought, Informa UK (Taylor & Francis), 2016, 38 (2), 10.1017/S1053837216000080. hal-01383443 HAL Id: hal-01383443 https://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-01383443 Submitted on 22 Aug 2019 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. JULES DUPUIT AND THE RAILROADS: WHAT IS THE ROLE OF THE STATE? ABSTRACT The emergence of railroads in France in the nineteenth century gave rise to new debates on analytical issues. The focus of interest lay in the fact that they are natural monopolies. In this paper, I focus on Jules Dupuit’s work on the operations of the railroad sector. Curiously, he seemed to have defended two contrasting positions, opening the way for debate among com- mentators: on the one hand, he claimed that unlimited competition is the most efficient way to operate in the railroad sector; on the other, he stated that State management was the best way to run the railroads.
    [Show full text]
  • The Economics of E-Commerce and Technology
    The Economics of E-commerce and Technology Monetization: Prices and Advertising 1 10/13/2016 The Stages of Buying (The Marketing Funnel) Marketing Other Networks • Content • Broadcast of premium Funnel content on multiple • SEO, SEM, display, platforms Awareness email and word-of- mouth • Synchronized marketing campaigns Company X leverages its • Frequency of • Mass media Lower Familiarity user visits (pull) Broadcast relationships frequency (push) with content providers to • Rise of third-party reviews • Participation in target a community features • Comments / message high-value Opinion boards • Brand affiliation user • Content / brand Consideration affinity Consumer Value of Value Company X network is • Typically lose the user • Company X can comprised of and data at this juncture capitalize on and high-value Intent as users exit the network influence intent users with expressed • Company X can intent Shopping facilitate process Higher Purchase 2 10/13/2016 Basic Monopoly Pricing 3 10/13/2016 Monopoly Pricing: Recap Constant marginal cost, c. Firm chooses quantity to maximize profits (q) q(p(q) c) First-order condition MR(q) c Inverse elasticity rule p c 1 p dq where e p e q dp 4 10/13/2016 Multi-product monopolist Microsoft sells XBox and Halo If sell separately optimal prices pX=300, pH=50. But they sell both: how should they price them? Walmart sells Xbox and PS3 If sell separately optimal prices pX=300, pPS=400. But they sell both: how should they price? Economist sells print and online editions How should they price? 5 10/13/2016 Multi-product monopolist Firm chooses (q1,q2) to maximize (q1,q2 ) q1( p1(q1,q2 ) c1) q2 ( p2 (q1,q2 ) c2 ) Inverse elasticity rule for p1 p c 1 ( p c )q p dq 1 1 2 2 2 e where e 1 2 12 12 p1 e11 p1q1e11 q2 dp1 Substitutes: e12<0 Negative externality so increase p1.
    [Show full text]
  • Competitive Screening Under Heterogeneous Information
    Competitive Screening under Heterogeneous Information Daniel Garrett⇤ Renato Gomes† Lucas Maestri‡ First Version: November, 2013. This Version: April, 2016. Abstract We build a theory of second-degree price discrimination under imperfect competition that allows us to study the substitutive role of prices and qualities in increasing sales. A key feature of our model is that consumers are heterogeneously informed about the o↵ers available in the market, which leads to dispersion over price-quality menus in equilibrium. While firms are ex- ante identical, their menus are ordered so that more generous menus leave more surplus uniformly over consumer types. We generate empirical predictions by exploring the e↵ects of changes in market fundamentals on the distribution of surplus across types, and pricing across products. For instance, more competition may raise prices for low-quality goods; yet, consumers are better o↵, as the qualities they receive also increase. The predictions of our model illuminate empirical findings in many markets, such as those for cell phone plans, yellow-pages advertising, cable TV and air travel. JEL Classification: D82 Keywords: competition, screening, heterogeneous information, price discrimination, adverse selection ⇤Toulouse School of Economics, University of Toulouse Capitole, [email protected]. †Toulouse School of Economics, University of Toulouse Capitole (CNRS), [email protected]. ‡Getulio Vargas Foundation (EPGE), [email protected]. 1 Introduction Price discrimination through menus of products, exhibiting di↵erent combinations of quality and price, is a widespread practice across many industries. Examples include flight tickets with di↵erent terms and conditions, cell phone plans with increasing usage allowances, and television subscriptions in basic and premium versions.
    [Show full text]
  • Jules Dupuit and the Early Theory of Marginal Cost Pricing Author(S): R
    Jules Dupuit and the Early Theory of Marginal Cost Pricing Author(s): R. B. Ekelund, Jr. Source: Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 76, No. 3 (May - Jun., 1968), pp. 462-471 Published by: The University of Chicago Press Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1829307 . Accessed: 05/05/2014 19:39 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp . JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. The University of Chicago Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of Political Economy. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 128.97.27.21 on Mon, 5 May 2014 19:39:54 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Jules Dupuit and the Early Theory of Marginal Cost Pricing R. B. Ekelund,Jr.* Texas A and M University I. Introduction The name of JulesDupuit, the nineteenth-centuryFrench engineer, has been frequentlyinvoked in contemporaryeconomic literature concerned with marginalcost pricing(Hotelling, 1938, pp. 242-44; Nelson, 1964, pp. vii-viii) and cost-benefitanalysis (Prest and Turvey,1965, p. 683). Althoughhis contributionsin the area of utilitytheory (Stigler, 1950), consumers'surplus (Houghton,
    [Show full text]
  • Download PDF (1.1
    IMF Working Paper This is a Working Paper and the author(s) would welcome any comments on the present text. Citations should refer to a Working Paper ofthe International Monetary Fund. The © 1997 International Monetary Fund views expressed are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent those of the Fund. WP/97/59 INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND Research Department Social Security Tax Reform and Unemployment: A General Equilibrium Analysis for France Prepared by Caroline Van Rijckeghem Authorized for distribution by Peter Wickham May 1997 Abstract This paper develops and calibrates a simple general equilibrium model with two types of labor and capital for the French economy. The simulation results indicate that targeted reductions in employer social security taxes have six times as large an effect on employment as untargeted reductions for equal initial budgetary cost, while employee social security tax reductions have a negative effect on employment. They also point to the presence of "self-financing," whereby reductions in various tax rates lead to lower budget deficits in the long run, as a result of an expanding tax base and lower unemployment insurance outlays. 1 JEL Classification Numbers: E62, H21, J38, J68 Author's E-Mail Address: cvanrijckeghem@imforg Keywords: Tax policy, Unemployment, Laffer Curve, Wage Curve IThe author would like to thank Richard Agenor, Jean-Pierre Laffargue, Howell Zee, Jacques Artus, Max Watson, Joaquim Levy, Ousmane Dore, Karl Habermeier, and participants at a seminar at INSEE for insightful comments and discussions and is indebted to Habib F etini for the reference to the work of Ibn Khaldfin.
    [Show full text]
  • Marshallian Cross Diagrams and Their Uses Before Alfred Marshall: the Origins of Supply and Demand Geometry
    Marshallian Cross Diagrams and Their Uses before Alfred Marshall: The Origins of Supply and Demand Geometry ThonaasM. Humphrey And Karl Rau (184 l), Jules Dupuit (1844), Hans von Mangoldt (1863), and Fleeming Jenkin (1870) thor- Undoubtedly the simplest. and most frequently oughly developed it years before Marshall presented used tool of microeconomic analysis is the conven- it in his Pzm Theory of Domestic Vafues (1879) and tional partial equilibrium demand-and-supply-curve later in his Pnitciples of fionomics (1890). Far from diagram of the textbooks. Economics professors merely introducing the diagram, these writers applied and their students put the diagram to at least six it to derive many of the concepts and theories often main uses. They use it to depict the equilibrium or attributed to Marshall or his followers. The notions market-clearing price and quantity of any particular of price elasticity of demand and supply, of stability good or factor input. They employ it to show how of equilibrium, of the possibility of multiple equilibria, (Walrasian) price or (Marshallian) quantity adjust- of comparative statics analyses involving shifts in the ments ensure this equilibrium: the first by eliminating curves, of consumers’ and producers’ surplus, of con- excess supply and demand, the second by eradicating stant, increasing and decreasing costs, of pricing of disparities between supply price and demand price. joint and composite products, of potential benefits They use it to illustrate how parametric shifts in of price discrimination, of tax incidence analysis, of demand and supply curves induced by changes in deadweight-welfare-loss triangles and the allocative tastes, incomes, technology, factor prices, and prices inefficiency of monopoly: all find expression in of related goods operate to alter a good’s equilibrium early expositions of the diagram.
    [Show full text]
  • The Role of Entropy in the Development of Economics
    entropy Article The Role of Entropy in the Development of Economics Aleksander Jakimowicz Department of World Economy, Institute of Economics, Polish Academy of Sciences, Palace of Culture and Science, 1 Defilad Sq., 00-901 Warsaw, Poland; [email protected] Received: 25 February 2020; Accepted: 13 April 2020; Published: 16 April 2020 Abstract: The aim of this paper is to examine the role of thermodynamics, and in particular, entropy, for the development of economics within the last 150 years. The use of entropy has not only led to a significant increase in economic knowledge, but also to the emergence of such scientific disciplines as econophysics, complexity economics and quantum economics. Nowadays, an interesting phenomenon can be observed; namely, that rapid progress in economics is being made outside the mainstream. The first significant achievement was the emergence of entropy economics in the early 1970s, which introduced the second law of thermodynamics to considerations regarding production processes. In this way, not only was ecological economics born but also an entropy-based econometric approach developed. This paper shows that non-extensive cross-entropy econometrics is a valuable complement to traditional econometrics as it explains phenomena based on power-law probability distribution and enables econometric model estimation for non-ergodic ill-behaved (troublesome) inverse problems. Furthermore, the entropy economics has accelerated the emergence of modern econophysics and complexity economics. These new directions of research have led to many interesting discoveries that usually contradict the claims of conventional economics. Econophysics has questioned the efficient market hypothesis, while complexity economics has shown that markets and economies function best near the edge of chaos.
    [Show full text]
  • Situating Cost-Benefit Analysis for Environmental Justice
    SITUATING COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS FOR ENVIRONMENTAL JUSTICE Erik Michael Wohlmuth, B.A. Thesis Prepared for the Degree of MASTER OF ARTS UNIVERSITY OF NORTH TEXAS December 2010 APPROVED: Robert M. Figueroa, Major Professor David M. Kaplan, Committee Member Irene J. Klaver, Committee Member Patricia Glazebrook, Chair of the Department of Philosophy and Religion Studies James D. Meernik, Acting Dean of the Robert B. Toulouse School of Graduate Studies Wohlmuth, Erik Michael. Situating Cost-Benefit Analysis for Environmental Justice. Master of Arts (Philosophy), December 2010, 92 pp., 1 table, references, 46 titles. Cost-benefit analysis plays a significant role in the process of siting hazardous waste facilities throughout the United States. Controversy regarding definitively disparate, albeit unintentional, racist practices in reaching these siting decisions abounds, yet cost-benefit analysis stands incapable of commenting on normative topics. This thesis traces the developments of both cost-benefit analysis and its normative cousin utilitarianism by focusing on the impacts they have had on the contemporary environmental justice discourse and highlighting valid claims, misunderstandings, and sedimented ideas surrounding the popularity of cost-benefit analysis. This analysis ultimately leads to an alternative means of realizing environmental justice that both acknowledges the need for greater democratic interactions and attempts to work with, rather than against, the prevailing paradigm of reaching siting decisions. Copyright 2010 by Erik
    [Show full text]